scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Author

Bart Hobijn

Bio: Bart Hobijn is an academic researcher from Arizona State University. The author has contributed to research in topics: Unemployment & Inflation. The author has an hindex of 41, co-authored 161 publications receiving 7046 citations. Previous affiliations of Bart Hobijn include Federal Reserve Bank of New York & Erasmus University Rotterdam.
Topics: Unemployment, Inflation, Recession, Wage, Productivity


Papers
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
01 Sep 2013
TL;DR: In this article, a detailed examination of the magnitude, determinants, and implications of the U.S. labor share decline is presented, concluding that about a third of the published labor share appears to be an artifact of statistical procedures used to impute the labor income of the self-employed that underlies the headline measure.
Abstract: Over the past quarter century, labor’s share of income in the United States has trended downward, reaching its lowest level in the postwar period after the Great Recession. A detailed examination of the magnitude, determinants, and implications of this decline delivers five conclusions. First, about a third of the decline in the published labor share appears to be an artifact of statistical procedures used to impute the labor income of the self-employed that underlies the headline measure. Second, movements in labor’s share are not solely a feature of recent U.S. history: The relative stability of the aggregate labor share prior to the 1980s in fact veiled substantial, though offsetting, movements in labor shares within industries. By contrast, the recent decline has been dominated by the trade and manufacturing sectors. Third, U.S. data provide limited support for neoclassical explanations based on the substitution of capital for (unskilled) labor to exploit technical change embodied in new capital goods. Fourth, prima facie evidence for institutional explanations based on the decline in unionization is inconclusive. Finally, our analysis identifies offshoring of the labor-intensive component of the U.S. supply chain as a leading potential explanation of the decline in the U.S. labor share over the past 25 years.

619 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors conclude that the problems facing the U.S. labor market are unlikely to be as severe as the European unemployment problem of the 1980s and suggest that the extension of Emergency Unemployment Compensation may have led to a modest increase in unemployment.
Abstract: From the perspective of a wide range of labor market outcomes, the recession that began in 2007 represents the deepest downturn in the postwar era. Early on, the nature of labor market adjustment displayed a notable resemblance to that observed in past severe downturns. During the latter half of 2009, however, the path of adjustment exhibited important departures from that seen during and after prior deep recessions. Recent data point to two warning signs going forward. First, the record rise in long-term unemployment may yield a persistent residue of long-term unemployed workers with weak search effectiveness. Second, conventional estimates suggest that the extension of Emergency Unemployment Compensation may have led to a modest increase in unemployment. Despite these forces, we conclude that the problems facing the U.S. labor market are unlikely to be as severe as the European unemployment problem of the 1980s.

588 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors developed and estimated a model where technology diffusion depends on the level of productivity embodied in capital and where this is, in turn, determined by two key mechanisms: the rate at which the quality embodied in new technology vintages increases (embodiment) and the gains from varieties induced by the introduction of new Vintages (variety).
Abstract: We develop and estimate a model where technology diffusion depends on the level of productivity embodied in capital and where this is, in turn, determined by two key mechanisms: the rate at which the quality embodied in new technology vintages increases (embodiment) and the gains from varieties induced by the introduction of new vintages (variety). In our model, these two effects are related to technology adoption decisions taken at two different levels. The capital goods suppliers%u2019 decisions of when to adopt a given vintage determines the embodiment margin. The workers%u2019 decisions of which of the adopted vintages to use in production determines the variety margin.Estimation of our model for a sample of 19 technologies, 21 countries, and the period 1870-1998 reveals that embodied productivity growth is large for many of the technologies in our sample. On average, increases in the variety of vintages available is a more important source of growth than the increases in the embodiment margin. There is, however, substantial heterogeneity across technologies. Where adoption lags matter, they are largely determined by lack of educational attainment and lack of trade openness.

360 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper examined the diffusion of more than 20 technologies across 23 of the world's leading industrial economies and found that the most important determinants of the speed at which a country adopts technologies are the country's human capital endowment, type of government, degree of openness to trade, and adoption of predecessor technologies.

341 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors provide comparable estimates for the rates of in-ow to and out-of-work from unemployment for fourteen OECD economies using publicly available data and devise a method to decompose changes in unemployment into contributions accounted for by changes in in −ow and out −ow rates for cases where unemployment deviates from its steady state, as it does in many countries.
Abstract: We provide a set of comparable estimates for the rates of in‡ow to and out‡ow from unemployment for fourteen OECD economies using publicly available data. We then devise a method to decompose changes in unemployment into contributions accounted for by changes in in‡ow and out‡ow rates for cases where unemployment deviates from its ‡ow steady state, as it does in many countries. Our decomposition reveals that ‡uctuations in both in‡ow and out‡ow rates contribute substantially to unemployment variation within countries. For Anglo-Saxon economies we …nd approximately a 20:80 in‡ow/out‡ow split to unemployment variation, while for Continental European and Nordic countries, we observe much closer to a 50:50 split. Using the estimated ‡ow rates we compute gross worker ‡ows into and out of unemployment. In all economies we observe that increases in in‡ows lead increases in unemployment, whereas out‡ows lag a ramp up in unemployment.

287 citations


Cited by
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors show that the frequency of price change is highly seasonal: it is highest in the first quarter and then declines, and that price increases covaries strongly with inflation, whereas price decreases and the size of price increases and decreases do not.
Abstract: are price decreases. (3) The frequency of price increases covaries strongly with inflation, whereas the frequency of price decreases and the size of price increases and price decreases do not. (4) The frequency of price change is highly seasonal: it is highest in the first quarter and then declines. (5) We find no evidence of upwardsloping hazard functions of price changes for individual products. We show that the first, second, and third facts are consistent with a benchmark menu-cost model, whereas the fourth and fifth facts are not.

1,588 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors use the highly unequal geographic distribution of wealth losses across the United States to estimate a large elasticity of consumption with respect to housing net worth of 0.6 to 0.8, which soundly rejects the hypothesis of full consumption risk sharing.
Abstract: lapse using the highly unequal geographic distribution of wealth losses across the United States. We estimate a large elasticity of consumption with respect to housing net worth of 0.6 to 0.8, which soundly rejects the hypothesis of full consumption risk-sharing. The average marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of housing wealth is 5–7 cents with substantial heterogeneity across ZIP codes. ZIP codes with poorer and more levered households have a significantly higher MPC out of housing wealth. In line with the MPC result, ZIP codes experiencing larger wealth losses, particularly those with poorer and more levered households, experience a larger reduction in credit limits, refinancing likelihood, and credit scores. Our findings highlight the role of debt and the geographic distribution of wealth shocks in explaining the large and unequal decline in consumption from 2006 to 2009. JEL Codes: E21, E32, E44, E60.

1,245 citations

01 Feb 1951
TL;DR: The Board of Governors' Semiannual Agenda of Regulations for the period August 1, 1980 through February 1, 1981 as discussed by the authors provides information on those regulatory matters that the Board now has under consideration or anticipates considering over the next six months.
Abstract: Enclosed is a copy of the Board of Governors’ Semiannual Agenda of Regulations for the period August 1, 1980 through February 1, 1981. The Semiannual Agenda provides you with information on those regulatory matters that the Board now has under consideration or anticipates considering over the next six months, and is divided into three parts: (1) regulatory matters that the Board had considered during the previous six months on which final action has been taken; (2) regulatory matters that have been proposed for public comment and that require further Board consideration; and (3) regulatory matters that the Board may consider over the next six months.

1,236 citations