scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question

Showing papers by "Donald B. Rubin published in 1999"


Book
28 Dec 1999
TL;DR: In this paper, the basic concepts of focused procedures and focused procedures for two groups are discussed. But they do not consider contrast analysis in factorial designs and contrast analysis for repeated measures.
Abstract: 1. Basic concepts of focused procedures 2. Basic procedures for two groups 3. One-way contrast analysis 4. Contrasts in factorial designs 5. Contrasts in repeated measures 6. Multiple contrasts.

869 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors derived an adjusted repeated-imputation degree of freedom, ν m, with the following properties: for fixed m and estimated fraction of missing information, the adjusted degree increases in ν com.
Abstract: An appealing feature of multiple imputation is the simplicity of the rules for combining the multiple complete-data inferences into a final inference, the repeated-imputation inference (Rubin, 1987). This inference is based on a t distribution and is derived from a Bayesian paradigm under the assumption that the complete-data degrees of freedom, ν com , are infinite, but the number of imputations, m, is finite. When ν com is small and there is only a modest proportion of missing data, the calculated repeated-imputation degrees of freedom, ν m , for the t reference distribution can be much larger than ν com , which is clearly inappropriate. Following the Bayesian paradigm, we derive an adjusted degrees of freedom, ν m , with the following three properties: for fixed m and estimated fraction of missing information, ν m monotonically increases in ν com ; ν m is always less than or equal to ν com ; and ν m equals ν m when ν com is infinite. A small simulation study demonstrates the superior frequentist performance when using ν m rather than ν m .

684 citations



Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the combined impact of all-or-none compliance and subsequent missing outcomes can have on the estimation of the intention-to-treat effect of assignment in randomised studies.
Abstract: SUMMARY We study the combined impact that all-or-none compliance and subsequent missing outcomes can have on the estimation of the intention-to-treat effect of assignment in randomised studies. In this setting, a standard analysis, which drops subjects with missing outcomes and ignores compliance information, can be biased for the intention-to-treat effect. To address all-or-none compliance that is followed by missing outcomes, we construct a new estimation procedure for the intention-to-treat effect that maintains good randomisation-based properties under more plausible, nonignorable noncompliance and nonignorable missing-outcome conditions: the 'compound exclusion restriction' on the effect of assignment and the 'latent ignorability' of the missing data mechanism. We present both theoretical results and a simulation study. Moreover, we show how the two key concepts of compound exclusion and latent ignorability are relevant in more complicated settings, such as right censoring of a time-to-event outcome.

392 citations



Posted Content
TL;DR: This article conducted a survey of people who played the lottery in the mid-eighties and estimated the effect of lottery winnings on their subsequent earnings, labor supply, consumption, and savings.
Abstract: Knowledge of the effect of unearned income on economic behavior of individuals in general, and on labor supply in particular, is of great importance to policy makers. Estimation of income effects, however, is a difficult problem because income is not randomly assigned and exogenous changes in income are difficult to identify. Here we exploit the randomized assignment of large amounts of money over long periods of time through lotteries. We carried out a survey of people who played the lottery in the mid-eighties and estimate the effect of lottery winnings on their subsequent earnings, labor supply, consumption, and savings. We find that winning a modest prize ($15,000 per year for twenty years) does not affect labor supply or earnings substantially. Winning such a prize does not considerably reduce savings. Winning a much larger prize ($80,000 rather than $15,000 per year) reduces labor supply as measured by hours, as well as participation and social security earnings; elasticities for hours and earnings are around -0.20 and for participation around -0.14. Winning a large versus modest amount also leads to increased expenditures on cars and larger home values, although mortgages values appear to increase by approximately the same amount. Winning $80,000 increases overall savings, although savings in retirement accounts are not significantly affected. The results do not vary much by gender, age, or prior employment status. There is some evidence that for those with zero earnings prior to winning the lottery there is a positive effect of winning a small prize on subsequent labor market participation.

54 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A mixture model is presented in which the ordinary and degraded states are described by distinct ANOVA structures, each with its own task, subject and interaction effects, with transitions between them occurring at random times.

24 citations


Proceedings ArticleDOI
27 Mar 1999
TL;DR: In this article, the authors describe the commissioning of the first three accelerating modules of a superconducting RF system consisting of four single-cell cavity modules, which is an important part of the CESR Luminosity Upgrade.
Abstract: The new superconducting RF system consisting of four single-cell cavity modules is an important part of the CESR Luminosity Upgrade. We describe the commissioning of the first three accelerating modules. This includes in situ testing and conditioning, pulsed power and beam processing of RF windows, commissioning of various cryogenic feedback loops, measuring cavity spacing and phasing with beam, and high-current operation.

16 citations





Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper provided sufficient conditions for estimating from longitudinal data the causal effect of a time-dependent exposure or treatment on the marginal probability of response for a dichotomous outcome and showed how one can estimate this effect under these conditions using the g-computation algorithm of Robins.
Abstract: We provide sufficient conditions for estimating from longitudinal data the causal effect of a time-dependent exposure or treatment on the marginal probability of response for a dichotomous outcome. We then show how one can estimate this effect under these conditions using the g-computation algorithm of Robins. We also derive the conditions under which some current approaches to the analysis of longitudinal data, such as the generalized estimating equations (GEE) approach of Zeger and Liang, the feedback model techniques of Liang and Zeger, and within-subject conditional methods, can provide valid tests and estimates of causal effects. We use out methods to estimate the causal effect of maternal stress on the marginal probability of a child's illness from the Mothers' Stress and Children's Morbidity data and compare out results with those previously obtained by Zeger and Liang using a GEE approach.



Posted Content
TL;DR: This paper conducted a survey of people who played the lottery in the mid-eighties and estimated the effect of lottery winnings on their subsequent earnings, labor supply, consumption, and savings.
Abstract: Knowledge of the effect of unearned income on economic behavior of individuals in general, and on labor supply in particular, is of great importance to policy makers. Estimation of income effects, however, is a difficult problem because income is not randomly assigned and exogenous changes in income are difficult to identify. Here we exploit the randomized assignment of large amounts of money over long periods of time through lotteries. We carried out a survey of people who played the lottery in the mid-eighties and estimate the effect of lottery winnings on their subsequent earnings, labor supply, consumption, and savings. We find that winning a modest prize ($15,000 per year for twenty years) does not affect labor supply or earnings substantially. Winning such a prize does not considerably reduce savings. Winning a much larger prize ($80,000 rather than $15,000 per year) reduces labor supply as measured by hours, as well as participation and social security earnings; elasticities for hours and earnings are around -0.20 and for participation around -0.14. Winning a large versus modest amount also leads to increased expenditures on cars and larger home values, although mortgages values appear to increase by approximately the same amount. Winning $80,000 increases overall savings, although savings in retirement accounts are not significantly affected. The results do not vary much by gender, age, or prior employment status. There is some evidence that for those with zero earnings prior to winning the lottery there is a positive effect of winning a small prize on subsequent labor market participation.