scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Author

George D. Farmer

Bio: George D. Farmer is an academic researcher from University of Manchester. The author has contributed to research in topics: Preference & Human multitasking. The author has an hindex of 7, co-authored 17 publications receiving 158 citations. Previous affiliations of George D. Farmer include University College London & Manchester Academic Health Science Centre.

Papers
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Findings highlight the need for sustained follow-up after GDM through screening, and interventions to reduce modifiable risk factors, as well as estimate development of type 2 diabetes in women with previous gestational diabetes and investigate characteristics associated with higher diagnoses.

50 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Examining adult participants’ choices between pairs of consumer products that were presented with a third, less desirable “decoy” option indicated that their choices were more consistent and conventionally rational than those of control participants.
Abstract: People with autism spectrum conditions (ASC) show reduced sensitivity to contextual stimuli in many perceptual and cognitive tasks. We investigated whether this also applies to decision making by examining adult participants’ choices between pairs of consumer products that were presented with a third, less desirable “decoy” option. Participants’ preferences between the items in a given pair frequently switched when the third item in the set was changed, but this tendency was reduced among individuals with ASC, which indicated that their choices were more consistent and conventionally rational than those of control participants. A comparison of people who were drawn from the general population and who varied in their levels of autistic traits revealed a weaker version of the same effect. The reduced context sensitivity was not due to differences in noisy responding, and although the ASC group took longer to make their decisions, this did not account for the enhanced consistency of their choices. The result...

47 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: It is demonstrated that if a person is only able to make noisy calculations of expected value and noisy observations of the ordinal relations among option features, then the expected value maximizing choice is influenced by the addition of new options and does give rise to apparent preference reversals.
Abstract: Contextual preference reversals occur when a preference for one option over another is reversed by the addition of further options. It has been argued that the occurrence of preference reversals in human behavior shows that people violate the axioms of rational choice and that people are not, therefore, expected value maximizers. In contrast, we demonstrate that if a person is only able to make noisy calculations of expected value and noisy observations of the ordinal relations among option features, then the expected value maximizing choice is influenced by the addition of new options and does give rise to apparent preference reversals. We explore the implications of expected value maximizing choice, conditioned on noisy observations, for a range of contextual preference reversal types-including attraction, compromise, similarity, and phantom effects. These preference reversal types have played a key role in the development of models of human choice. We conclude that experiments demonstrating contextual preference reversals are not evidence for irrationality. They are, however, a consequence of expected value maximization given noisy observations. (PsycINFO Database Record

44 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This result is used to clarify the implications of the attraction effect, arguing that although it robustly violates the assumptions of value‐maximising models, it does not eliminate the possibility that human decision making is optimal.
Abstract: The attraction effect shows that adding a third alternative to a choice set can alter preference between the original two options. For over 30 years, this simple demonstration of context dependence has been taken as strong evidence against a class of parsimonious value-maximising models that evaluate alternatives independently from one another. Significantly, however, in previous demonstrations of the attraction effect alternatives are approximately equally valuable, so there was little consequence to the decision maker irrespective of which alternative was selected. Here we vary the difference in expected value between alternatives and provide the first demonstration that, although extinguished with large differences, this theoretically important effect persists when choice between alternatives has a consequence. We use this result to clarify the implications of the attraction effect, arguing that although it robustly violates the assumptions of value-maximising models, it does not eliminate the possibility that human decision making is optimal.

23 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The recommendations address the high-level needs of patients and their non-specialist clinicians when receiving genetic test results and provide at-a-glance comprehension of what the test results mean for the patient; suggested next steps; and details of further information and support.
Abstract: Patients and non-specialist healthcare professionals are increasingly expected to understand and interpret the results of genetic or genomic testing. These results are currently reported using a variety of templates, containing different amounts, levels, and layouts of information. We set out to establish a set of recommendations for communicating genetic test results to non-expert readers. We employed a qualitative-descriptive study design with user-centred design principles, including a mixture of in-person semi-structured interviews and online questionnaires with patients, healthcare professionals and the general public. The resulting recommendations and example template include providing at-a-glance comprehension of what the test results mean for the patient; suggested next steps; and details of further information and support. Separation and inclusion of technical methodological details enhances non-specialists’ understanding, while retaining important information for specialists and the patients’ records. The recommendations address the high-level needs of patients and their non-specialist clinicians when receiving genetic test results. These recommendations provide a solid foundation for the major content and structure of reports, and we recommend further engagement with patients and clinicians to tailor reports to specific types of test and results.

22 citations


Cited by
More filters
01 Jan 2016

1,538 citations

Book Chapter
29 Jan 2018
TL;DR: A brief overview of the origins of this prominent and sometimes controversial theory, including its origins and key tenets, the later developments of the theory in neuroscientific and hormone research, and the critical response to the theory can be found in this article.
Abstract: This encyclopedia entry gives the reader a brief overview of the origins of this prominent and sometimes controversial theory, including its origins and key tenets, the later developments of the theory in neuroscientific and hormone research, and the critical response to the theory.

263 citations

29 Mar 2016
TL;DR: CPT's parameters seem to pick up stable individual differences that need to be considered when predicting risky choice, and are correlated across time, in particular when using a simple implementation of CPT.
Abstract: In the behavioral sciences, a popular approach to describe and predict behavior is cognitive modeling with adjustable parameters (i.e., which can be fitted to data). Modeling with adjustable parameters allows, among other things, measuring differences between people. At the same time, parameter estimation also bears the risk of overfitting. Are individual differences as measured by model parameters stable enough to improve the ability to predict behavior as compared to modeling without adjustable parameters? We examined this issue in cumulative prospect theory (CPT), arguably the most widely used framework to model decisions under risk. Specifically, we examined (a) the temporal stability of CPT's parameters; and (b) how well different implementations of CPT, varying in the number of adjustable parameters, predict individual choice relative to models with no adjustable parameters (such as CPT with fixed parameters, expected value theory, and various heuristics). We presented participants with risky choice problems and fitted CPT to each individual's choices in two separate sessions (which were 1 week apart). All parameters were correlated across time, in particular when using a simple implementation of CPT. CPT allowing for individual variability in parameter values predicted individual choice better than CPT with fixed parameters, expected value theory, and the heuristics. CPT's parameters thus seem to pick up stable individual differences that need to be considered when predicting risky choice.

127 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This work reviews here the complex decision mechanisms necessary to account for context effects found with multi-attribute, multi-alternative choices and review linkages between these more complex processes and their neural substrates to develop a comprehensive and biologically plausible account of human value-based decision making.

122 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
30 Dec 2018
TL;DR: A systematic review of the literature shows little evidence that the alleged biases are potentially costly in terms of less health, wealth, or happiness as discussed by the authors. But the bias bias has been shown to be persistent and costly in real life.
Abstract: Behavioral economics began with the intention of eliminating the psychological blind spot in rational choice theory and ended up portraying psychology as the study of irrationality. In its portrayal, people have systematic cognitive biases that are not only as persistent as visual illusions but also costly in real life—meaning that governmental paternalism is called upon to steer people with the help of “nudges.” These biases have since attained the status of truisms. In contrast, I show that such a view of human nature is tainted by a “bias bias,” the tendency to spot biases even when there are none. This may occur by failing to notice when small sample statistics differ from large sample statistics, mistaking people’s random error for systematic error, or confusing intelligent inferences with logical errors. Unknown to most economists, much of psychological research reveals a different portrayal, where people appear to have largely fine-tuned intuitions about chance, frequency, and framing. A systematic review of the literature shows little evidence that the alleged biases are potentially costly in terms of less health, wealth, or happiness. Getting rid of the bias bias is a precondition for psychology to play a positive role in economics.

73 citations