scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Institution

Copenhagen Business School

EducationCopenhagen, Hovedstaden, Denmark
About: Copenhagen Business School is a education organization based out in Copenhagen, Hovedstaden, Denmark. It is known for research contribution in the topics: Corporate governance & Context (language use). The organization has 2194 authors who have published 9649 publications receiving 341898 citations.


Papers
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors argue that knowledge mapping may provide a fruitful avenue for intellectual capital management in academic environments such as university departments, and they make a number of suggestions as to the rationale and conduct of knowledge mapping in academe.
Abstract: This paper argues that knowledge mapping may provide a fruitful avenue for intellectual capital management in academic environments such as university departments. However, while some research has been conducted on knowledge mapping and intellectual capital management in the public sector, the university has so far not been directly considered for this type of management. The paper initially reviews the functions and techniques of knowledge mapping and assesses these in the light of academic demands. Second, the result of a focus group study is presented, where academic leaders were asked to reflect of the uses of knowledge mapping at their departments and institutes. Finally a number of suggestions are made as to the rationale and conduct of knowledge mapping in academe.

189 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A theory for a general class of discrete-time stochastic control problems that, in various ways, are time-inconsistent in the sense that they do not admit a Bellman optimality principle is developed.
Abstract: We develop a theory for a general class of discrete-time stochastic control problems that, in various ways, are time-inconsistent in the sense that they do not admit a Bellman optimality principle. We attack these problems by viewing them within a game theoretic framework, and we look for subgame perfect Nash equilibrium points. For a general controlled Markov process and a fairly general objective functional, we derive an extension of the standard Bellman equation, in the form of a system of nonlinear equations, for the determination of the equilibrium strategy as well as the equilibrium value function. Most known examples of time-inconsistent stochastic control problems in the literature are easily seen to be special cases of the present theory. We also prove that for every time-inconsistent problem, there exists an associated time-consistent problem such that the optimal control and the optimal value function for the consistent problem coincide with the equilibrium control and value function, respectively for the time-inconsistent problem. To exemplify the theory, we study some concrete examples, such as hyperbolic discounting and mean–variance control.

188 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors explore what the specific driving forces are that increase the degree of sustainable innovation within a firm's innovation activities and find that firms need to invest in internal absorptive capacities and to draw both broadly and deeply from external sources for innovation.
Abstract: Over the past decade, sustainable innovation has occupied a top-ranking position on the agenda of many firms. Sustainable innovation can be broadly defined as an innovation that has to consider environmental and social issues as well as the needs of future generations. Although sustainable innovation provides considerable new opportunities for companies it goes along with an increased complexity. This in turn requires certain organizational routines and capabilities to deal with the upcoming challenges. We explore what the specific driving forces are that increase the degree of sustainable innovation within a firm's innovation activities. We test them empirically for more than 1,100 firms in Germany and find that firms need to invest in internal absorptive capacities and to draw both broadly and deeply from external sources for innovation. In that sense, investments in employee training turn out to be more important than technological R&D expenditures.

187 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A formal definition of supply chain robustness is developed to build a framework that captures the dimensions, antecedents and moderators of the construct as discussed in the literature.
Abstract: Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to provide groundwork for an emerging theory of supply chain robustness – which has been conceptualized as a dimension of supply chain resilience – through reviewing and synthesizing related yet disconnected studies. The paper develops a formal definition of supply chain robustness to build a framework that captures the dimensions, antecedents and moderators of the construct as discussed in the literature. Design/methodology/approach – The authors apply a systematic literature review approach. In order to reduce researcher bias, they involve a team of academics, librarians and managers. Findings – The paper first, provides a formal definition of supply chain robustness; second, builds a theoretical framework of supply chain robustness that augments both causal and descriptive knowledge; third,shows how findings in this review support practice; and fourth,reveals methodological insights on the use of journal rankings in reviews. Research limitations/implications – At ...

186 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Green default rules may well be a more effective tool for altering outcomes than large economic incentives as discussed by the authors, and that may be more effective than, the standard tools of economic incentives, mandates, and bans.
Abstract: Careful attention to choice architecture promises to open up new possibilities for environmental protection – possibilities that go well beyond, and that may be more effective than, the standard tools of economic incentives, mandates, and bans. How, for example, do consumers choose between environmentally-friendly products or services and alternatives that are potentially damaging to the environment but less expensive? The answer may well depend on the default rule. Indeed, green default rules may well be a more effective tool for altering outcomes than large economic incentives. The underlying reasons include the power of suggestion; inertia and procrastination; and loss aversion. If well-chosen, green defaults are likely to have large effects in reducing the economic and environmental harms associated with various products and activities. Such defaults may or may not be more expensive to consumers. In deciding whether to establish green defaults, choice architects should consider both consumer welfare and a wide range of other costs and benefits. Sometimes that assessment will argue strongly in favor of green defaults, particularly when both economic and environmental considerations point in their direction. But when choice architects lack relevant information, when interest-group maneuvering is a potential problem, and when externalities are not likely to be significant, active choosing, perhaps accompanied by various influences (including provision of relevant information), will usually be preferable to a green default.

186 citations


Authors

Showing all 2280 results

NameH-indexPapersCitations
Cass R. Sunstein11778757639
John Campbell107115056067
Nicolai J. Foss9145431803
Stewart Clegg7051723021
Robert J. Kauffman6943715762
James R. Markusen6721626362
Timo Teräsvirta6222420403
John D. Sterman6217127982
Björn Johansson6263716030
Richard L. Baskerville6128418796
Torben Pedersen6124114499
Peter Christoffersen5920815208
Saul Estrin5835916448
Ram Mudambi5623613562
Xin Li5621411450
Network Information
Related Institutions (5)
Stockholm School of Economics
4.8K papers, 285.5K citations

93% related

Bocconi University
8.9K papers, 344.1K citations

90% related

Athens University of Economics and Business
6.9K papers, 177.8K citations

89% related

University of Mannheim
12.9K papers, 446.5K citations

88% related

HEC Montréal
5.7K papers, 196.8K citations

88% related

Performance
Metrics
No. of papers from the Institution in previous years
YearPapers
202329
2022144
2021584
2020534
2019453
2018452