scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Book ChapterDOI

2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand and distribution in neo-Kaleckian and neo-Goodwinian models

31 Jul 2020-Research Papers in Economics (Edward Elgar Publishing)-
About: This article is published in Research Papers in Economics.The article was published on 2020-07-31 and is currently open access. It has received None citations till now.

Summary (2 min read)

INTRODUCTION

  • The neo-Kaleckian branch of post-Keynesian economics emphasizes the multi-faceted relationships between the functional distribution of income and various indicators of macroeconomic performance, such as the rates of capital accumulation, capacity utilization, and economic growth (Hein 2014; Lavoie 2014).
  • This chapter will argue that there is a logically coherent explanation for the paradox that an increased profit share has failed to bring about improved macro performance at medium-term horizons (across a few decades) in economies that have profit-led demand in the short run (that is, at business-cycle frequencies).
  • I apply the wage-led versus profit-led distinction only to the slope of the aggregate demand relationship in the short run; I do not use it to characterize the behavior of the overall economic system or longer-term outcomes.

THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

  • Two stable cases that have (if the reader will pardon the pun) attracted much attention in the literature are the ones depicted in Figure 1.
  • But as the raw data show – and the econometric estimates of Kiefer and Rada (2015) confirm – the equilibria in these figures have drifted in a southwesterly direction, that is, toward lower equilibrium levels of both utilization rates (measured by output gaps) and the wage share, in most of the advanced economies over the past few decades.
  • With the AD curve sloping upward, a downward shift of the DC curve would naturally have led to reductions in the equilibrium levels of both the wage share and the utilization (or growth) rate, as shown by the shift of DC to DC′ in panel (a) of Figure 2.
  • The cases depicted in the two panels of Figure 2 represent only two extreme possibilities, in which only one curve (AD or DC) shifts in the medium run; hence, either of these scenarios seems quite unlikely.

REEVALUATING THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

  • Kiefer and Rada (2015) modified the neo-Goodwinian model of Barbosa-Filho and Taylor (2006) to allow for long-term shifts in the equilibrium values of capacity utilization (measured by the output gap) and the wage share.
  • In contrast, Stockhammer and Wildauer (2016) studied the drivers of aggregate demand for a panel of 18 OECD countries using a structural model with separate equations for consumption, investment, exports, and imports.
  • Stockhammer (2013) found that decreasing wage shares in a panel of 71 countries (including both advanced and developing nations) were principally explained by variables representing financialization, globalization, and retrenchment of welfare states.
  • The stricter are the inflation targeting policies (for example, the lower is the policy objective for inflation and the higher is the estimated “natural rate of unemployment”), the more aggregate demand will be chronically depressed, with negative effects on the wage share if the DC relationship exhibits a profit-squeeze.
  • Indeed, the post-Keynesian literature often emphasizes the distributional impact of monetary policy, but mainly in relation to the distribution of capital income between rentiers and firms (see Rochon and Setterfield 2012).

CONCLUSIONS

  • The findings of profit-led demand and neo-Goodwinian cyclical dynamics in some empirical studies have led to widespread skepticism of how such behavior could be compatible with the observed medium-term declines in both macro performance (utilization or growth rates) and wage shares in various countries.
  • But since those findings pertain only to short-run, cyclical behavior, they are not necessarily inconsistent with the observed medium-term trends.
  • This chapter has shown that profit-led demand and neo-Goodwinian cycles can potentially be reconciled with those trends, but only if there is a profit-squeeze in distribution and the shifts in the aggregate demand relationship dominate the shifts in the distributive relationship.
  • It should be emphasized that this is only a logical possibility, and much more theoretical and empirical work is required to tease out the channels through which various kinds of structural forces and policy shifts have affected both income distribution and aggregate demand in the long term.
  • Also, if Lavoie is correct that cyclical movements in the wage share are largely driven by endogenous fluctuations in labor productivity rather than by the behavior of the real wage, as the empirical results in Cauvel (2018) suggest, then all models that assume that the wage share is an adequate measure of distributional forces would have to be re-thought.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Long-term shifts in demand and distribution in neo-Kaleckian
and neo-Goodwinian models
Robert A. Blecker*
November 2017 [revised, June 2018]
Draft chapter for Hassan Bougrine and Louis-Philippe Rochon (eds), Money and Crises in Post-
Keynesian Economics: Essays in Honour of Marc Lavoie and Mario Seccareccia (Edward Elgar,
forthcoming). [6026 words total]
*Professor of Economics, American University, Washington, DC, USA, blecker@american.edu.
The author would like to thank participants at conferences and seminars in New York (Eastern
Economic Association), Brasilia (Brazilian Keynesian Association), and Buenos Aires
(Universidad Nacional de San Martín) for comments on earlier versions of material in this
chapter.
American University Working Paper Series
https://doi.org/10.17606/c8vj-q531

1
INTRODUCTION
The neo-Kaleckian branch of post-Keynesian economics emphasizes the multi-faceted
relationships between the functional distribution of income and various indicators of
macroeconomic performance, such as the rates of capital accumulation, capacity utilization, and
economic growth (Hein 2014; Lavoie 2014). Empirical studies in this tradition have, however,
reached diametrically opposed conclusions about whether aggregate demand is normally wage-
led or profit-led in the short run. As surveyed by Blecker (2016) and Stockhammer (2017),
1
studies using a “structural” (multi-equation) approach have (with some exceptions) tended to
find that most countries have wage-led demand, except for very small or highly open economies,
while studies using an “aggregative” approach have typically found that demand is profit-led
(often for the same countries or similar panels of countries). The latter studies have frequently
relied upon the so-called “Goodwin cycle” variant of the neo-Kaleckian model pioneered by
Barbosa-Filho and Taylor (2006), in which it is also found that there is a “profit squeeze” (that
is, higher utilization leads to an increased wage share or reduced profit share).
2
Following
Stockhammer (2017), this variant will be referred to as the “neo-Goodwinian” approach.
In spite of these varied empirical findings, one thing is clear: over the past few decades,
most advanced capitalist countries (and some emerging market nations as well) have suffered
from slower growth along with rising inequality. In particular, wage shares – which in the past
usually exhibited the “stylized fact” of mostly cyclical fluctuations around roughly constant
trends – have fallen notably in many countries since roughly the 1980s or 1990s, depending on
the country (Storm and Naastepad 2012; Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014; Kiefer and Rada
2015; Wolff 2015; Stockhammer and Wildauer 2016). The wage-led demand view suggests a

2
ready-made explanation for this coincidence of increasing inequality and worsening
performance: various structural changes and policy shifts (globalization, financialization,
deregulation, deunionization, and neo-liberal policies generally) have combined to weaken labor
relative to capital; the resulting redistribution of income toward profits inevitably causes
aggregate demand to be depressed and growth to falter in economies where demand is wage-led.
It is less apparent how the coincidence of greater inequality and slower growth in the
longer term can be explained by a model in which demand is profit-led. As two skeptics of the
profit-led view have written,
despite the fact that in almost all OECD countries real wage growth was
significantly restrained after 1980, allowing profitability to recover to its golden-
age level, post-1980 macroeconomic performance is in general characterized by
lower output growth, lower rates of investment, and higher rates of
unemployment than witnessed during the period from 1960 to 1980.... The
disappointing performance raises the question of why the redistribution of income
from wages to profits in a supposedly profit-led demand regime has so far failed
to bring about a more adequate long-run economic performance. (Storm and
Naastepad 2012, p. 113)
This chapter will argue that there is a logically coherent explanation for the paradox that
an increased profit share has failed to bring about improved macro performance at medium-term
horizons (across a few decades) in economies that have profit-led demand in the short run (that
is, at business-cycle frequencies). The key to this explanation lies in the other finding of the neo-
Goodwinian literature: that the distributive relationship slopes upward in utilization-wage share
space, or in other words, the economy exhibits a “profit-squeeze” in distribution. If the
distributive relationship slopes upward while the aggregate demand relationship slopes
downward, then any medium-run shifts in a southwesterly direction (toward lower
utilization/growth rates and a lower wage share) should be driven primarily by downward shifts
in the aggregate demand relationship. Thus, any factors that tend to depress aggregate demand
will also move the economy toward lower points on the distributive relationship – lower

3
combinations of the wage share and utilization rate (or some other measure of output or demand)
– provided that this relationship is characterized by profit-squeeze behavior.
Essentially, chronically depressed aggregate demand relieves the profit-squeeze on
capital by holding down output and employment, thereby preventing workers from reaping wage
gains both during cyclical upturns and over longer periods. Thus, this explanation reverses the
causality in the standard long-run story: in this alternative view, it is chronically depressed
aggregate demand that prevents workers from winning wage gains in line with their productivity
growth, rather than the falling wage share being an exogenous cause of depressed demand.
Before proceeding further, several qualifications are in order. First, many economists
have rejected the entire idea of characterizing economic systems as uniquely either wage-led or
profit-led (for example, Nikiforos and Foley 2012; Dos Santos 2015; Palley 2017; Skott 2017). I
am sympathetic with that critique, especially since my own previous work has emphasized that
the impact of a redistribution of income between wages and profits on aggregate demand varies
according to the source of the shift in distribution in an open economy (Blecker 1989, 2011). In
this chapter, I apply the wage-led versus profit-led distinction only to the slope of the aggregate
demand relationship in the short run; I do not use it to characterize the behavior of the overall
economic system or longer-term outcomes.
Second, some economists have argued that the findings of profit-led demand are likely to
be biased by factors that are not controlled for in the neo-Goodwinian empirical studies. Lavoie
(2014, 2017) argues that those findings could be driven by the procyclical behavior of labor
productivity in the presence of overhead labor. Assuming that firms do not layoff overhead labor
in proportion to the decline in output during a cyclical downturn, labor productivity will fall in a
recession and rise in the recovery, and since the wage share equals the ratio of the real wage to

4
labor productivity, the wage share will naturally move in the opposite direction. This endogenous
movement of the wage share could create a misleading impression that demand is profit-led,
since the profit share would be falling as utilization falls and conversely. Also, Stockhammer and
Michell (2017) demonstrate theoretically that a debt-driven “Minsky cycle” can mimic a profit-
driven Goodwin cycle even when aggregate demand is not truly profit-led.
3
Third, and most importantly, the argument in this chapter is intended only to establish a
logical possibility, not to claim that it is the only or exclusive explanation for the coincidence of
worsened economic performance and higher profit shares. It is clear that the massive structural
changes brought about by the globalization of production and finance and shifts toward neo-
liberal policies have directly weakened labor’s bargaining position and inhibited workers from
winning wage increases commensurate with their rising productivity, and the resulting fall in
wage shares (especially for production workers) certainly could contribute to depressed
economic activity in the long term. Indeed, I have argued elsewhere that the impact of
distribution on demand and growth is likely to vary over different time horizons (Blecker 2016):
the positive effects of profitability on investment and negative effects of unit labor costs on net
exports are likely to dominate in the short run, implying profit-led demand at business-cycle
frequencies, whereas the positive effects of high wages on consumption are likely to dominate in
the longer term, implying wage-led demand over longer time horizons.
4
But what this chapter
emphasizes is not the demand relationship per se, but rather how it interacts with the
distributional relationship in such a way that depressed demand and growth could be as much
causes of a more unequal distribution of income as they are consequences of the latter.

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors showed that the global labor share has signicantly declined since the early 1980s, with the decline occurring within the large majority of countries and industries, and that the decrease in the relative price of investment goods, often attributed to advances in information technology and the computer age, induced rms.
Abstract: The stability of the labor share of income is a key foundation in macroeconomic models. We document, however, that the global labor share has signicantly declined since the early 1980s, with the decline occurring within the large majority of countries and industries. We show that the decrease in the relative price of investment goods, often attributed to advances in information technology and the computer age, induced rms

1,578 citations

Book ChapterDOI
01 Jan 1982
TL;DR: In this paper, a starkly schematised and hence quite unrealistic model of cycles in growth rates is presented, which seems to me to have better prospects than the more usual treatment of growth theory or of cycle theory separately or in combination.
Abstract: Presented here is a starkly schematised and hence quite unrealistic model of cycles in growth rates. This type of formulation now seems to me to have better prospects than the more usual treatment of growth theory or of cycle theory, separately or in combination. Many of the bits of reasoning are common to both, but in the present paper they are put together in a different way.

987 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers result in this paper

  • ...All of these models differ from the original model of Goodwin (1967), which was a neo-Marxian model that generated limit cycles in the wage share and employment rate, but did not consider variable capacity utilization....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors explored the relationship between financialization in the U.S economy and real investment at the firm level and found a negative relationship between real investment and financialization, which may have crowded out real investment by changing the incentives of firm managers and directing funds away from real investment.
Abstract: Recent research has explored the growing ‘financialization’ process in the U.S. and other advanced economies. The term is a catch-all phrase used to denote important changes in the structure of non-financial corporations’ balance sheets, including the growth of income from financial subsidiaries and investment as well as growth in the transfer of earnings to financial markets in the forms of interest payments, dividend payments and stock buybacks. This paper seeks to empirically explore the relationship between financialization in the U.S economy and real investment at the firm level. Using data from a sample of non-financial corporations from 1973 to 2003, I find a negative relationship between real investment and financialization. First, increased financial investment and increased financial profit opportunities may have crowded out real investment by changing the incentives of firm managers and directing funds away from real investment. Second, increased payments to the financial markets may have impeded real investment by decreasing available internal funds, shortening the planning horizons of the firm management, and increasing uncertainty. These two channels can help explain the negative relationship I find between investment and financialization.

641 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Orhangazi (2008) found that corporate payouts (the sum of interest expense, cash dividends, and stock buybacks) have a negative and significant effect on investment by US nonfinancial corporations, while financial profits (the sum of interest income and equity in net earnings) have a negative and…...

    [...]

  • ...Orhangazi (2008) found that corporate payouts (the sum of interest expense, cash dividends, and stock buybacks) have a negative and significant effect on investment by US nonfinancial corporations, while financial profits (the sum...

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
01 Sep 2013
TL;DR: In this article, a detailed examination of the magnitude, determinants, and implications of the U.S. labor share decline is presented, concluding that about a third of the published labor share appears to be an artifact of statistical procedures used to impute the labor income of the self-employed that underlies the headline measure.
Abstract: Over the past quarter century, labor’s share of income in the United States has trended downward, reaching its lowest level in the postwar period after the Great Recession. A detailed examination of the magnitude, determinants, and implications of this decline delivers five conclusions. First, about a third of the decline in the published labor share appears to be an artifact of statistical procedures used to impute the labor income of the self-employed that underlies the headline measure. Second, movements in labor’s share are not solely a feature of recent U.S. history: The relative stability of the aggregate labor share prior to the 1980s in fact veiled substantial, though offsetting, movements in labor shares within industries. By contrast, the recent decline has been dominated by the trade and manufacturing sectors. Third, U.S. data provide limited support for neoclassical explanations based on the substitution of capital for (unskilled) labor to exploit technical change embodied in new capital goods. Fourth, prima facie evidence for institutional explanations based on the decline in unionization is inconclusive. Finally, our analysis identifies offshoring of the labor-intensive component of the U.S. supply chain as a leading potential explanation of the decline in the U.S. labor share over the past 25 years.

619 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...According to the estimates of Elsby et al. (2013), falling wage shares in US industries are mainly driven by increasing import penetration and offshoring of labor-intensive activities, especially in manufacturing....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors analyzed micro panel data from the U.S. Economic Census since 1982 and international sources and document empirical patterns to assess a new interpretation of the fall in the labor share based on the rise of "superstar firms."
Abstract: The fall of labor's share of GDP in the United States and many other countries in recent decades is well documented but its causes remain uncertain. Existing empirical assessments of trends in labor's share typically have relied on industry or macro data, obscuring heterogeneity among firms. In this paper, we analyze micro panel data from the U.S. Economic Census since 1982 and international sources and document empirical patterns to assess a new interpretation of the fall in the labor share based on the rise of "superstar firms." If globalization or technological changes advantage the most productive firms in each industry, product market concentration will rise as industries become increasingly dominated by superstar firms with high profits and a low share of labor in firm value-added and sales. As the importance of superstar firms increases, the aggregate labor share will tend to fall. Our hypothesis offers several testable predictions: industry sales will increasingly concentrate in a small number of firms; industries where concentration rises most will have the largest declines in the labor share; the fall in the labor share will be driven largely by between-firm reallocation rather than (primarily) a fall in the unweighted mean labor share within firms; the between-firm reallocation component of the fall in the labor share will be greatest in the sectors with the largest increases in market concentration; and finally, such patterns will be observed not only in U.S. firms, but also internationally. We find support for all of these predictions.

587 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Autor et al. (2017) found that the falling US labor share is...

    [...]

  • ...Autor et al. (2017) found that the falling US labor share is driven by increasing industrial concentration, as the firms that are increasing their market shares also have the highest profit shares so that weighted-average, industry-level profit shares are increasing.11 Furceri and Loungani (2018)…...

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (2)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Long-term shifts in demand and distribution in neo-kaleckian and neo-goodwinian models" ?

This paper argue that there is a logically coherent explanation for the paradox that an increased profit share has failed to bring about improved macro-term horizons ( across a few decades ) in economies that have profit-led demand in the short run ( that is, at business-cycle frequencies ). 

However, it should be emphasized that this is only a logical possibility, and much more theoretical and empirical work is required to tease out the channels through which various kinds of structural forces and policy shifts have affected both income distribution and aggregate demand in the long term. Thus, it is important for future research to focus on better understanding what determines the relative shares of wages and profits and analyzing the multidirectional causality between demand, distribution, and other factors over both short-run cycles and longer time horizons. Also, if Lavoie is correct that cyclical movements in the wage share are largely driven by endogenous fluctuations in labor productivity rather than by the behavior of the real wage, as the empirical results in Cauvel ( 2018 ) suggest, then all models that assume that the wage share is an adequate measure of distributional forces would have to be re-thought.