scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Book ChapterDOI

2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand and distribution in neo-Kaleckian and neo-Goodwinian models

31 Jul 2020-Research Papers in Economics (Edward Elgar Publishing)-
About: This article is published in Research Papers in Economics.The article was published on 2020-07-31 and is currently open access. It has received None citations till now.

Summary (2 min read)

INTRODUCTION

  • The neo-Kaleckian branch of post-Keynesian economics emphasizes the multi-faceted relationships between the functional distribution of income and various indicators of macroeconomic performance, such as the rates of capital accumulation, capacity utilization, and economic growth (Hein 2014; Lavoie 2014).
  • This chapter will argue that there is a logically coherent explanation for the paradox that an increased profit share has failed to bring about improved macro performance at medium-term horizons (across a few decades) in economies that have profit-led demand in the short run (that is, at business-cycle frequencies).
  • I apply the wage-led versus profit-led distinction only to the slope of the aggregate demand relationship in the short run; I do not use it to characterize the behavior of the overall economic system or longer-term outcomes.

THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

  • Two stable cases that have (if the reader will pardon the pun) attracted much attention in the literature are the ones depicted in Figure 1.
  • But as the raw data show – and the econometric estimates of Kiefer and Rada (2015) confirm – the equilibria in these figures have drifted in a southwesterly direction, that is, toward lower equilibrium levels of both utilization rates (measured by output gaps) and the wage share, in most of the advanced economies over the past few decades.
  • With the AD curve sloping upward, a downward shift of the DC curve would naturally have led to reductions in the equilibrium levels of both the wage share and the utilization (or growth) rate, as shown by the shift of DC to DC′ in panel (a) of Figure 2.
  • The cases depicted in the two panels of Figure 2 represent only two extreme possibilities, in which only one curve (AD or DC) shifts in the medium run; hence, either of these scenarios seems quite unlikely.

REEVALUATING THE EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

  • Kiefer and Rada (2015) modified the neo-Goodwinian model of Barbosa-Filho and Taylor (2006) to allow for long-term shifts in the equilibrium values of capacity utilization (measured by the output gap) and the wage share.
  • In contrast, Stockhammer and Wildauer (2016) studied the drivers of aggregate demand for a panel of 18 OECD countries using a structural model with separate equations for consumption, investment, exports, and imports.
  • Stockhammer (2013) found that decreasing wage shares in a panel of 71 countries (including both advanced and developing nations) were principally explained by variables representing financialization, globalization, and retrenchment of welfare states.
  • The stricter are the inflation targeting policies (for example, the lower is the policy objective for inflation and the higher is the estimated “natural rate of unemployment”), the more aggregate demand will be chronically depressed, with negative effects on the wage share if the DC relationship exhibits a profit-squeeze.
  • Indeed, the post-Keynesian literature often emphasizes the distributional impact of monetary policy, but mainly in relation to the distribution of capital income between rentiers and firms (see Rochon and Setterfield 2012).

CONCLUSIONS

  • The findings of profit-led demand and neo-Goodwinian cyclical dynamics in some empirical studies have led to widespread skepticism of how such behavior could be compatible with the observed medium-term declines in both macro performance (utilization or growth rates) and wage shares in various countries.
  • But since those findings pertain only to short-run, cyclical behavior, they are not necessarily inconsistent with the observed medium-term trends.
  • This chapter has shown that profit-led demand and neo-Goodwinian cycles can potentially be reconciled with those trends, but only if there is a profit-squeeze in distribution and the shifts in the aggregate demand relationship dominate the shifts in the distributive relationship.
  • It should be emphasized that this is only a logical possibility, and much more theoretical and empirical work is required to tease out the channels through which various kinds of structural forces and policy shifts have affected both income distribution and aggregate demand in the long term.
  • Also, if Lavoie is correct that cyclical movements in the wage share are largely driven by endogenous fluctuations in labor productivity rather than by the behavior of the real wage, as the empirical results in Cauvel (2018) suggest, then all models that assume that the wage share is an adequate measure of distributional forces would have to be re-thought.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Long-term shifts in demand and distribution in neo-Kaleckian
and neo-Goodwinian models
Robert A. Blecker*
November 2017 [revised, June 2018]
Draft chapter for Hassan Bougrine and Louis-Philippe Rochon (eds), Money and Crises in Post-
Keynesian Economics: Essays in Honour of Marc Lavoie and Mario Seccareccia (Edward Elgar,
forthcoming). [6026 words total]
*Professor of Economics, American University, Washington, DC, USA, blecker@american.edu.
The author would like to thank participants at conferences and seminars in New York (Eastern
Economic Association), Brasilia (Brazilian Keynesian Association), and Buenos Aires
(Universidad Nacional de San Martín) for comments on earlier versions of material in this
chapter.
American University Working Paper Series
https://doi.org/10.17606/c8vj-q531

1
INTRODUCTION
The neo-Kaleckian branch of post-Keynesian economics emphasizes the multi-faceted
relationships between the functional distribution of income and various indicators of
macroeconomic performance, such as the rates of capital accumulation, capacity utilization, and
economic growth (Hein 2014; Lavoie 2014). Empirical studies in this tradition have, however,
reached diametrically opposed conclusions about whether aggregate demand is normally wage-
led or profit-led in the short run. As surveyed by Blecker (2016) and Stockhammer (2017),
1
studies using a “structural” (multi-equation) approach have (with some exceptions) tended to
find that most countries have wage-led demand, except for very small or highly open economies,
while studies using an “aggregative” approach have typically found that demand is profit-led
(often for the same countries or similar panels of countries). The latter studies have frequently
relied upon the so-called “Goodwin cycle” variant of the neo-Kaleckian model pioneered by
Barbosa-Filho and Taylor (2006), in which it is also found that there is a “profit squeeze” (that
is, higher utilization leads to an increased wage share or reduced profit share).
2
Following
Stockhammer (2017), this variant will be referred to as the “neo-Goodwinian” approach.
In spite of these varied empirical findings, one thing is clear: over the past few decades,
most advanced capitalist countries (and some emerging market nations as well) have suffered
from slower growth along with rising inequality. In particular, wage shares – which in the past
usually exhibited the “stylized fact” of mostly cyclical fluctuations around roughly constant
trends – have fallen notably in many countries since roughly the 1980s or 1990s, depending on
the country (Storm and Naastepad 2012; Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014; Kiefer and Rada
2015; Wolff 2015; Stockhammer and Wildauer 2016). The wage-led demand view suggests a

2
ready-made explanation for this coincidence of increasing inequality and worsening
performance: various structural changes and policy shifts (globalization, financialization,
deregulation, deunionization, and neo-liberal policies generally) have combined to weaken labor
relative to capital; the resulting redistribution of income toward profits inevitably causes
aggregate demand to be depressed and growth to falter in economies where demand is wage-led.
It is less apparent how the coincidence of greater inequality and slower growth in the
longer term can be explained by a model in which demand is profit-led. As two skeptics of the
profit-led view have written,
despite the fact that in almost all OECD countries real wage growth was
significantly restrained after 1980, allowing profitability to recover to its golden-
age level, post-1980 macroeconomic performance is in general characterized by
lower output growth, lower rates of investment, and higher rates of
unemployment than witnessed during the period from 1960 to 1980.... The
disappointing performance raises the question of why the redistribution of income
from wages to profits in a supposedly profit-led demand regime has so far failed
to bring about a more adequate long-run economic performance. (Storm and
Naastepad 2012, p. 113)
This chapter will argue that there is a logically coherent explanation for the paradox that
an increased profit share has failed to bring about improved macro performance at medium-term
horizons (across a few decades) in economies that have profit-led demand in the short run (that
is, at business-cycle frequencies). The key to this explanation lies in the other finding of the neo-
Goodwinian literature: that the distributive relationship slopes upward in utilization-wage share
space, or in other words, the economy exhibits a “profit-squeeze” in distribution. If the
distributive relationship slopes upward while the aggregate demand relationship slopes
downward, then any medium-run shifts in a southwesterly direction (toward lower
utilization/growth rates and a lower wage share) should be driven primarily by downward shifts
in the aggregate demand relationship. Thus, any factors that tend to depress aggregate demand
will also move the economy toward lower points on the distributive relationship – lower

3
combinations of the wage share and utilization rate (or some other measure of output or demand)
– provided that this relationship is characterized by profit-squeeze behavior.
Essentially, chronically depressed aggregate demand relieves the profit-squeeze on
capital by holding down output and employment, thereby preventing workers from reaping wage
gains both during cyclical upturns and over longer periods. Thus, this explanation reverses the
causality in the standard long-run story: in this alternative view, it is chronically depressed
aggregate demand that prevents workers from winning wage gains in line with their productivity
growth, rather than the falling wage share being an exogenous cause of depressed demand.
Before proceeding further, several qualifications are in order. First, many economists
have rejected the entire idea of characterizing economic systems as uniquely either wage-led or
profit-led (for example, Nikiforos and Foley 2012; Dos Santos 2015; Palley 2017; Skott 2017). I
am sympathetic with that critique, especially since my own previous work has emphasized that
the impact of a redistribution of income between wages and profits on aggregate demand varies
according to the source of the shift in distribution in an open economy (Blecker 1989, 2011). In
this chapter, I apply the wage-led versus profit-led distinction only to the slope of the aggregate
demand relationship in the short run; I do not use it to characterize the behavior of the overall
economic system or longer-term outcomes.
Second, some economists have argued that the findings of profit-led demand are likely to
be biased by factors that are not controlled for in the neo-Goodwinian empirical studies. Lavoie
(2014, 2017) argues that those findings could be driven by the procyclical behavior of labor
productivity in the presence of overhead labor. Assuming that firms do not layoff overhead labor
in proportion to the decline in output during a cyclical downturn, labor productivity will fall in a
recession and rise in the recovery, and since the wage share equals the ratio of the real wage to

4
labor productivity, the wage share will naturally move in the opposite direction. This endogenous
movement of the wage share could create a misleading impression that demand is profit-led,
since the profit share would be falling as utilization falls and conversely. Also, Stockhammer and
Michell (2017) demonstrate theoretically that a debt-driven “Minsky cycle” can mimic a profit-
driven Goodwin cycle even when aggregate demand is not truly profit-led.
3
Third, and most importantly, the argument in this chapter is intended only to establish a
logical possibility, not to claim that it is the only or exclusive explanation for the coincidence of
worsened economic performance and higher profit shares. It is clear that the massive structural
changes brought about by the globalization of production and finance and shifts toward neo-
liberal policies have directly weakened labor’s bargaining position and inhibited workers from
winning wage increases commensurate with their rising productivity, and the resulting fall in
wage shares (especially for production workers) certainly could contribute to depressed
economic activity in the long term. Indeed, I have argued elsewhere that the impact of
distribution on demand and growth is likely to vary over different time horizons (Blecker 2016):
the positive effects of profitability on investment and negative effects of unit labor costs on net
exports are likely to dominate in the short run, implying profit-led demand at business-cycle
frequencies, whereas the positive effects of high wages on consumption are likely to dominate in
the longer term, implying wage-led demand over longer time horizons.
4
But what this chapter
emphasizes is not the demand relationship per se, but rather how it interacts with the
distributional relationship in such a way that depressed demand and growth could be as much
causes of a more unequal distribution of income as they are consequences of the latter.

References
More filters
Book ChapterDOI
21 Jan 2013
TL;DR: In the last quarter century dramatic changes in income distribution have taken place as discussed by the authors, with the very top income groups increasing their income shares substantially in the Anglo-Saxon countries, in particular in the United States.
Abstract: In the last quarter century dramatic changes in income distribution have taken place This refers to the personal distribution of income as well as to the functional distribution of income Distribution has become more polarized in most OECD countries (OECD 2008, 2011), with the very top income groups increasing their income shares substantially in the Anglo-Saxon countries, in particular in the United States (Atkinson et al 2011) Wage shares have fallen in virtually all OECD countries, with decreases typically being more pronounced in continental European countries (and Japan) than in the Anglo-Saxon countries In the advanced economies1 the (adjusted) wage share has, on average, fallen from 734 in 1980 to 640 per cent in 2007 (Figure 21) The data for Germany are very similar (722 to 618); the decline is somewhat stronger in Japan (772 to 622) and a little weaker in the United States (700 to 649) Overall, real wage growth has clearly lagged behind productivity growth since around 1980 This constitutes a major historical change as wage shares had been stable or increasing in the post-war era

176 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Stockhammer (2013) found that decreasing wage shares in a panel of 71 countries (including both advanced and developing nations) were principally explained by variables representing financialization, globalization, and retrenchment of welfare states....

    [...]

  • ...…of the wage-led literature: AD slopes upward in u×ψ space, while DC slopes downward – the latter reflecting the negative effect of GDP growth on the wage share found by Stockhammer (2013).5 Following Kiefer and Rada (2015), we will call the downward-sloping DC curve the case of a “wage squeeze.”...

    [...]

  • ...These underlying forces include globalization, financialization, deunionization, and other transformations generally associated with the “neoliberal” policy paradigm (Stockhammer 2013)....

    [...]

  • ...1 For earlier surveys of the empirical literature, see Onaran and Galanis (2012) and Lavoie and Stockhammer (2013)....

    [...]

  • ...Starting with the wage-led view, the explanation is relatively straightforward and indeed is implicit in a large number of studies (for example, Lavoie and Stockhammer 2013)....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the effects of a change in the wage share on growth in the G20 countries using a post-Keynesian/post-Kaleckian model were analyzed.
Abstract: This paper estimates the effects of a change in the wage share on growth in the G20 countries using a post-Keynesian/post-Kaleckian model, analyses the interactions among different economies, and calculates the global multiplier effects of a simultaneous decline in the wage share. At the national level, a decrease in the wage share leads to lower growth in the euro area, Germany, France, Italy, UK, US, Japan, Turkey, and Korea, i.e. these economies are wage-led, whereas it stimulates growth in Canada, Australia, Argentina, Mexico, China, India, and South Africa; thus the latter group of countries are profit-led. However, a simultaneous decline in the wage share in all these countries leads to a decline in global growth. Furthermore, Canada, Argentina, Mexico, and India also contract when they decrease their wage-share along with their trading partners. Thus the global economy in aggregate is wage-led. The policy conclusions of the paper shed light on the limits of strategies of international competitiveness based on wage competition in a highly integrated global economy, and point at the possibilities to correct global imbalances via coordinated macroeconomic and wage policy, where domestic demand plays an important role. There is room for a wage-led recovery in the global economy based on a simultaneous increase in the wage shares, where global GDP as well as all individual countries can grow.

165 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers background or methods in this paper

  • ...methodology to individual countries (for example, Hein and Vogel 2008; Onaran and Galanis 2012), Stockhammer and Wildauer find that most countries – especially the larger and relatively...

    [...]

  • ...As in previous studies applying a similar methodology to individual countries (for example, Hein and Vogel 2008; Onaran and Galanis 2012), Stockhammer and Wildauer find that most countries – especially the larger and relatively more closed ones – have wage-led demand overall, while some of the…...

    [...]

  • ...1 For earlier surveys of the empirical literature, see Onaran and Galanis (2012) and Lavoie and Stockhammer (2013)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, a theoretical and empirical investigation of how changes in the size distribution of income can aect aggregate demand and the demand regime of an economy is presented, and conditions under which a reduction of income inequality among workers turns demand more wage-led.
Abstract: This paper presents a theoretical and empirical investigation of how changes in the size distribution of income can aect aggregate demand and the demand regime of an economy. After presenting empirical evidence for the US economy that the propensity to save increases signicantly from the bottom to the top quintile of wage earners, we demonstrate that more equal distributions always lead to higher output in the traditional neo-Kaleckian macroeconomic model. We also present conditions under which a reduction of income inequality among workers turns demand more wage-led. This view is supported by the results of an econometric study for the United States (1967-2010) which show that the rise after 1980 in income inequality has made the US economy more prot-led.

137 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...2 See also Kiefer and Rada (2015) and Carvalho and Rezai (2016)....

    [...]

Book
02 Jan 2012
TL;DR: In this article, Storm and Naastepad make a strong case that this concept is flawed: that a stable non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), independent of macroeconomic policy, does not exist.
Abstract: Economists and the governments they advise have based their macroeconomic policies on the idea of a natural rate of unemployment. Government policy that pushes the rate below this point--about 6 percent--is apt to trigger an accelerating rate of inflation that is hard to reverse, or so the argument goes. In this book, Storm and Naastepad make a strong case that this concept is flawed: that a stable non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), independent of macroeconomic policy, does not exist. Consequently, government decisions based on the NAIRU are not only misguided but have huge and avoidable social costs, namely, high unemployment and sustained inequality. Skillfully merging theoretical and empirical analysis, Storm and Naastepad show how the NAIRU's neglect of labor's impact on technological change and productivity growth eclipses the many positive contributions that labor and its regulation make to economic performance. When these positive effects are taken into account, the authors contend, a more humane policy becomes feasible, one that would enhance productivity and technological progress while maintaining profits, thus creating conditions for low unemployment and wider equality.

135 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This article argued that demand is more likely to be profit-driven than weakly wage-driven in the short run and more strongly wage-biased in the long run, because the positive effects of higher profits (lower labor costs) on investment and net exports are strongest in short-term and the negative effects of a higher wage share on consumption are if anything stronger in long-term.
Abstract: Empirical studies have found mixed results regarding whether various countries have wage-led or profit-led demand regimes based on a variety of econometric methodologies. However, most of the previous literature has paid too little attention to the time dimension of this distinction. This paper argues that demand is more likely to be profit led (or, at least, more weakly wage led) in the short run and more likely to be wage led (or more strongly wage led) in the long run, because the positive effects of higher profits (lower labor costs) on investment and net exports are likely to be strongest in the short run, while the positive effects of a higher wage share on consumption are if anything likely to be stronger in the long run. In fact, most of the studies that have found profit-led results (especially for the US) have used methodologies that (either intentionally or unintentionally) emphasize short-run cyclical relationships. An examination of correlations in the raw data for the US economy over different time horizons illustrates the plausibility of output and growth being profit led in the short run and wage led in the long run.

122 citations


"2018-06 Long-term shifts in demand ..." refers background or result in this paper

  • ...As surveyed by Blecker (2016) and Stockhammer (2017),1 studies using a “structural” (multi-equation) approach have (with some exceptions) tended to find that most countries have wage-led demand, except for very small or highly open economies, while studies using an “aggregative” approach have…...

    [...]

  • ...Indeed, I have argued elsewhere that the impact of distribution on demand and growth is likely to vary over different time horizons (Blecker 2016): the positive effects of profitability on investment and negative effects of unit labor costs on net exports are likely to dominate in the short run, implying profit-led demand at business-cycle...

    [...]

  • ...Indeed, I have argued elsewhere that the impact of distribution on demand and growth is likely to vary over different time horizons (Blecker 2016): the positive effects of profitability on investment and negative effects of unit labor costs on net exports are likely to dominate in the short run,…...

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (2)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Long-term shifts in demand and distribution in neo-kaleckian and neo-goodwinian models" ?

This paper argue that there is a logically coherent explanation for the paradox that an increased profit share has failed to bring about improved macro-term horizons ( across a few decades ) in economies that have profit-led demand in the short run ( that is, at business-cycle frequencies ). 

However, it should be emphasized that this is only a logical possibility, and much more theoretical and empirical work is required to tease out the channels through which various kinds of structural forces and policy shifts have affected both income distribution and aggregate demand in the long term. Thus, it is important for future research to focus on better understanding what determines the relative shares of wages and profits and analyzing the multidirectional causality between demand, distribution, and other factors over both short-run cycles and longer time horizons. Also, if Lavoie is correct that cyclical movements in the wage share are largely driven by endogenous fluctuations in labor productivity rather than by the behavior of the real wage, as the empirical results in Cauvel ( 2018 ) suggest, then all models that assume that the wage share is an adequate measure of distributional forces would have to be re-thought.