scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

A Class of Singular Control Problems and the Smooth Fit Principle

01 Nov 2008-Siam Journal on Control and Optimization (Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics)-Vol. 47, Iss: 6, pp 3076-3099
TL;DR: In particular, the authors analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions are not necessarily smooth and provides necessary and sufficient conditions for the well-known smooth fit principle, along with the regularity of the value functions.
Abstract: This paper analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions are not necessarily smooth. Necessary and sufficient conditions for the well-known smooth fit principle, along with the regularity of the value functions, are given. Explicit solutions for the optimal policy and for the value functions are provided. In particular, when payoff functions satisfy the usual Inada conditions, the boundaries between action and continuation regions are smooth and strictly monotonic, as postulated and exploited in the existing literature (see [A. K. Dixit and R. S. Pindyck, Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 1994]; [M. H. A. Davis et al., Adv. in Appl. Probab., 19 (1987), pp. 156-176]; [T. O. Kobila, Stochastics Stochastics Rep., 43 (1993), pp. 29-63]; [A. B. Abel and J. C. Eberly, J. Econom. Dynam. Control, 21 (1997), pp. 831-852]; [A. Oksendal, Finance Stoch., 4 (2000), pp. 223-250]; [J. A. Scheinkman and T. Zariphopoulou, J. Econom. Theory, 96 (2001), pp. 180-207]; [A. Merhi and M. Zervos, SIAM J. Control Optim., 46 (2007), pp. 839-876]; and [L. H. Alvarez, A General Theory of Optimal Capacity Accumulation under Price Uncertainty and Costly Reversibility, Working Paper, Helsinki Center of Economic Research, Helsinski, Finland, 2006]). Illustrative examples for both smooth and nonsmooth cases are discussed to emphasize the pitfall of solving singular control problems with a priori smoothness assumptions.

Summary (2 min read)

1 Introduction

  • Consider the following problem in reversible investment/capacity planning that arises naturally in resource extraction and power generation.
  • Facing the risk of market uncertainty, companies extract resources (such as oil or gas) and choose the capacity level in response to the random fluctuation of market price for the resources, subject to some capacity constraints, as well as the associated costs for capacity expansion and contraction.
  • Both necessary and sufficient conditions on the differentiability of the value function and on the smooth fit principle are established.
  • In fact, when the payoff function is not smooth, this paper is the first to rigorously characterize the action and no-action regions, and to explicitly construct both the optimal policy and the value function.

2.1 Problem

  • This is a continuous time formulation of the aforementioned risk management problem.
  • The goal of the company is to maximize its long-term profit with a payoff function that depends on both the resource extraction rate and the market price, with a form of H(Y )Xλ.
  • And the control problem can be reduced to an equivalent yet simpler singular control problem .
  • In fact, this equivalent control problem is more standard in the existing literature for both singular control and (ir)reversible investment.

3 Derivation of the Solution

  • The derivation goes as follows: first, a collection of corresponding optimal switching problems is established and solved; then, the consistency of the optimal switching controls is proved; finally, the existence of the corresponding integrable optimal singular control (ξ̂+, ξ̂−) ∈.
  • A′y is established and the corresponding value function are derived.
  • This method is built on the general correspondence between singular controls and switching controls outlined in Guo and Tomecek (2007).

3.1.2 Solution of the Optimal Switching Problems

  • The derivation of the value function proceeds analogously to the derivation for the case of h(z) >.
  • Moreover, these equations depend on z only through ν(z) and κ(z), implying that there exist unique constants κ, ν such that κ(z) ≡ κ and ν(z) ≡ ν for all z.

3.2 Derivation of the Optimal Switching Controls

  • The authors then define a collection of these switching controls and prove that this collection satisfies the consistency property from Guo and Tomecek (2007), which implies that it corresponds to an admissible singular control.
  • Note that since the regime values κ̂n are alternating, it suffices to define the switching times τ̂n.

3.2.2 Consistency of the Switching Controls

  • The collection of switching controls (α̂(x, z))z∈(a,b) is consistent.
  • Then the consistency follows from the following lemmas.
  • For simplicity, the authors omit the dependence on x from the notation.
  • Note that after the first switch, each subsequent switch requires that Xx move from (0, F (z)] to [G(z),∞) or vice versa.
  • In particular, this quantity is independent of z. Since log(Xx) is a Brownian motion with drift, its sample paths are almost surely uniformly continuous on [0, t].

3.3 Derivation of the Optimal Singular Control

  • Clearly, the following proposition holds, from Merhi and Zervos (2007).
  • Therefore, after verifying the Standing Assumptions A1, A2 and A3, one can invoke Guo and Tomecek (2007, Proposition 2.13, Theorem 3.13, Theorem 3.10) and conclude that there exists a corresponding integrable singular control (ξ̂+, ξ̂−) ∈.
  • To prove Theorem 2.5, the authors first establish some Lemmas.
  • (The second one follows by a similar argument, and the last one is immediate from the definition of C and the first two.).

4 Regularity, Smooth Fit and Region Characterization

  • The authors shall establish necessary and sufficient conditions for the smooth fit principle by exploiting both the structure of the payoff function and the explicit solution of the value function.
  • This analysis leads to the proof of Theorem 2.6 on region characterization.

4.1 Regularity and Smooth Fit

  • Therefore, d(x, ·) has only countably many discontinuities.
  • This theorem follows naturally from the following Lemma and the Proposition.
  • Thus fx must have at least two positive roots.

5 Examples and Discussions

  • By now, it is clear from their analysis that without sufficient smoothness of the payoff function, the value function may be non-differentiable and the boundaries may be non-smooth or not strictly monotonic.
  • Moreover, when the payoff function H is not continuously differentiable, the interior of C may not be simply connected.
  • Note, however, the regions S0, S1 and C are mutually disjoint and simply connected by the monotonicity of F and G.
  • The authors elaborate on these points with some concrete examples.

5.2 Discussion

  • The above examples demonstrate how the regularity assumptions typically assumed by the traditional HJB approach may fail.
  • Furthermore, Example 5.3 shows that in general, one may not have the smoothness of the boundary, as the boundaries F and G are not necessarily continuous or not even strictly increasing.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

UC Berkeley
Coleman Fung Risk Management Research Center Working
Papers 2006-2013
Title
A Class of Singular Control Problems and the Smooth Fit Principle
Permalink
https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8w46j0td
Authors
Guo, Xin
Tomecek, Pascal
Publication Date
2007-10-07
eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library
University of California

University of California
Berkeley
Working Paper # 2007 -05
A Class of Singular Control Problems
and the Smooth Fit Principle
Xin Guo, UC Berkeley and Cornell University
Pascal Tomecek, Cornell University
October 7,2007

A Class of Singular Control Problems and the Smo oth Fit
Principle
Xin Guo
UC Berkeley and Cornell
Pascal Tomecek
Cornell University
October 7, 2007
Abstract
This paper analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions
are not necessarily smooth. Necessary and sufficient conditions for the well-known
smooth fit principle, along with the regularity of the value functions, are given. Explicit
solutions for the optimal policy and for the value functions are provided. In particular,
when payoff functions satisfy the usual Inada conditions, the boundaries between action
and no-action regions are smooth and strictly monotonic as postulated and exploited in
the existing literature (Dixit and Pindyck (1994); Davis, Dempster, Sethi, and Vermes
(1987); Kobila (1993); Abel and Eberly (1997); Øksendal (2000); Scheinkman and
Zariphopoulou (2001); Merhi and Zervos (2007); Alvarez (2006)). Illustrative examples
for both smooth and non-smooth cases are discussed, to highlight the pitfall of solving
singular control problems with a priori smoothness assumptions.
This research is generously supported by grants from OpenLink Fund at the Coleman Fung Risk Man-
agement Research Center at UC Berkeley
Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research, UC Berkeley, CA 94720-1777, USA,
Phone (510) 642 3615, email: xinguo@ieor.berkeley.edu.
Scho ol of Operations Research and Industrial Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853-3801,
USA, Phone (607) 255 1270, Fax (607) 255 9129, email: pascal@orie.cornell.edu.
1

1 Introduction
Consider the following problem in reversible investment/capacity planning that arises nat-
urally in resource extraction and power generation. Facing the risk of market uncertainty,
companies extract resources (such as oil or gas) and choose the capacity level in response
to the random fluctuation of market price for the resources, subject to some capacity con-
straints, as well as the associated costs for capacity expansion and contraction. The goal of
the company is to maximize its long-term profit, subject to these constraints and the rate
of resource extraction.
This kind of capacity planning with price uncertainty and partial (or no) reversibility
originated from the economics literature and has since attracted the interest of the ap-
plied mathematics community. (See Dixit and Pindyck (1994); Brekke and Øksendal (1994);
Davis, Dempster, Sethi, and Vermes (1987); Kobila (1993); Abel and Eberly (1997); Baldurs-
son and Karatzas (1997); Øksendal (2000); Scheinkman and Zariphopoulou (2001); Wang
(2003); Chiarolla and Haussmann (2005); Guo and Pham (2005) and the references therein.)
Mathematical analysis of such control problems has evolved considerably from the initial
heuristics to the more sophisticated and standard stochastic control approach, and from
the very special case study to general payoff functions. (See Harrison and Taksar (1983);
Karatzas (1985); Karatzas and Shreve (1985); El Karoui and Karatzas (1988, 1989); Ma
(1992); Davis and Zervos (1994, 1998); Boetius and Kohlmann (1998); Alvarez (2000, 2001 );
Bank (2005); Boetius (2005)). Most recently, Merhi and Zervos (2007) analyzed this problem
in great generality and provided explicit solutions for the special case where the payoff is of
Cobb-Douglas type. Their method is to directly solve the HJB equations, assuming certain
regularity conditions for both the value function and the boundaries between the action and
no-action regions. Guo and Tomecek (2007) later established sufficient conditions for the
smoothness of the value function by connecting the singular control problem with a collection
of optimal switching problems.
However, for many singular control problems in reversible investment and in areas such
as queuing and wireless communications (Martins, Shreve, and Soner (1996); Assaf (1997);
Harrison and Van Mieghem (1997); Ata, Harrison, and Shepp (2005)), there is no regularity
for either the value function or the boundaries. Therefore, two important mathematical issues
remain: 1) necessary conditions for regularity properties; and 2) characterization for the
value function and for the action and no-action regions when these regularity conditions fail.
Understanding these issues is especially important in cases where only numerical solutions
are available, and for which the assumption on the degree of the smoothness is wrong (see
also discussions in Section 5.2).
This paper addresses these two issues via the study of a class of singular control problems.
Both necessary and sufficient conditions on the differentiability of the value function and on
the smooth fit principle are established. Moreover, these conditions lead to a derivative-
based characterization of the investment, disinvestment and continuation regions even for
non-smooth value functions. In fact, when the payoff function is not smooth, this paper is the
2

first to rigorously characterize the action and no-action regions, and to explicitly construct
both the optimal policy and the value function. To be consistent with the literature in
(ir)reversible investment, the running payoff function in this paper depends on the resource
extraction rate and the market price in the form of H(Y )X
λ
. It is worth noting that H(·)
is any concave function of the capacity, and may be neither monotonic nor differentiable.
This includes the special cases investigated by Guo and Pham (2005); Merhi and Zervos
(2007); Guo and Tomecek (2007). In particular, when H satisifies the well-known Inada
conditions (i.e., continuously differentiable, strictly increasing, strictly concave, with H(0) =
0, H
0
(0
+
) = , H
0
() = 0), our results show that the boundaries between regions are
indeed continuous and strictly increasing as postulated and exploited in previous works:
Dixit and Pindyck (1994); Davis, Dempster, Sethi, and Vermes (1987); Kobila (1993); Abel
and Eberly (1997); Øksendal (2000); Scheinkman and Zariphopoulou (2001); Merhi and
Zervos (2007); Alvarez (2006). Also note that our method can be applied to more general
(diffusion) processes for the price dynamics, other than the geometric Brownian motion
assumed for explicitness in this paper. Finally, the construction between the functional form
of the boundaries and the payoff function itself is also novel, as the value function and the
boundaries may be neither smooth nor strictly monotonic as in the existing literature.
The most relevant and recent work to this paper is Alvarez (2006), which provides a
great deal of economic insight into the problem. However, Alvarez (2006) only handles
payoff functions satisfying the Inada conditions. In contrast, our solution is independent of
the regularity of the payoff and value functions.
Outline. The control problem is formally stated, with its value function and optimal p olicy
described in Section 2; details of the derivation are in Section 3. The main result of this
paper regarding the regularity of the value function is in Section 4. Examples are provided
in Section 5, including cases for which the value function is not differentiable, the optimal
controlled process not continuous, the boundaries of the action regions not smooth, and the
interior of the continuation region not simply connected.
2 Mathematical Problem and Solution
2.1 Problem
Let (Ω, F, F, P) be a filtered probability space and assume a given bounded interval [a, b]
(−∞, ). Consider the following problem:
Problem A.
V
H
(x, y) := sup
(ξ
+
)∈A
00
y
J
H
(x, y; ξ
+
, ξ
),
3

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, a singular control problem whose value function is governed by a time-dependent HJB equation with gradient constraints is considered, and the authors transform a two-dimensional parabolic variational inequality with gradient constraint into a double obstacle problem with parameter involving two free boundaries that correspond to the investment and disinvestment policies.

14 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors provide a complete theoretical analysis of a two-dimensional degenerate non-convex singular stochastic control problem, motivated by a storage-consumption model in an electricity market.
Abstract: In this paper we provide a complete theoretical analysis of a two-dimensional degenerate non convex singular stochastic control problem. The optimisation is motivated by a storage-consumption model in an electricity market, and features a stochastic real-valued spot price modelled by Brownian motion. We find analytical expressions for the value function, the optimal control and the boundaries of the action and inaction regions. The optimal policy is characterised in terms of two monotone and discontinuous repelling free boundaries, although part of one boundary is constant and and the smooth fit condition holds there.

11 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this article, the authors provide a complete theoretical analysis of a two-dimensional degenerate non-convex singular stochastic control problem, motivated by a storage-consumption model in an electricity market.
Abstract: In this paper we provide a complete theoretical analysis of a two-dimensional degenerate non convex singular stochastic control problem. The optimisation is motivated by a storage-consumption model in an electricity market, and features a stochastic real-valued spot price modelled by Brownian motion. We find analytical expressions for the value function, the optimal control and the boundaries of the action and inaction regions. The optimal policy is characterised in terms of two monotone and discontinuous repelling free boundaries, although part of one boundary is constant and the smooth fit condition holds there.

8 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors derive a stochastic control model to optimize banks' dividend and recapitalization policies in this situation and calibrate that to a sample of U.S. banks.
Abstract: Banks' assets are opaque, and therefore, we model their true accounting asset values as partially observed variables. We derive a stochastic control model to optimize banks' dividend and recapitalization policies in this situation, and calibrate that to a sample of U.S. banks. By the calibrated model, the noise in reported accounting asset values hides about one-third of the true asset return volatility and raises the banks' market equity value by 7.8% because the noise hides the banks' solvency risk from banking regulators. Particularly, those banks with a high level of loan loss provisions, nonperforming assets, and real estate loans, and with a low volatility of reported total assets have noisy accounting asset values. Because of the substantial shock on the true asset values, the banks' assets were more opaque during the recent financial crisis.

7 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Asmussen et al. as mentioned in this paper presented a multivariate random walk with regularly varying step sizes to solve high-dimensional singular control problems in finance and insurance, and the results showed that the approach can be used to solve problems in both finance and actuarial mathematics.
Abstract: The workshop brought together leading experts from all over the world to exchange and discuss the latest developments in mathematical finance and actuarial mathematics. Researchers from the industry had the opportunity to circulate their problems among mathematicians. The participants gained from a fruitful interaction between mathematical methods and practitioner’s problems as well as from the interaction between finance and actuarial mathematics. Mathematics Subject Classification (2000): 91Bxx, 60Gxx. Introduction by the Organisers The workshop Recent Developments in Financial and Insurance Mathematics and the Interplay with the Industry, organised by Søren Asmussen (Aarhus), Nicole Bäuerle (Karlsruhe) and Ralf Korn (Kaiserslautern) was held February 18th– February 24th, 2006. The participants came from all over the world, including Hong Kong and the US. The workshop was attended by 25 mathematicians, most of them were leading experts in mathematical finance and actuarial mathematics and a few researchers from the industry. In total, there were 21 talks distributed over five days with a long lunch break between 12:30 and 16:00 which made it possible to discuss the latest results and open problems posed in the morning sessions. The major themes of the talks had been • Optimization problems in finance and insurance • Multidimensional modeling in finance and insurance • Valuation of insurance products, credit risk and electricity markets • Risk measures and distributions with heavy tails. 550 Oberwolfach Report 10/2007 We proceed with a brief overview of the four subjects above and a summary of the principal results of those areas that were reported on in the workshop: Optimization problems in finance and insurance: Quite a large number of the talks investigated stochastic dynamic portfolio problems in finance as well as in insurance. Tomas Björk who gave the first talk considered a general investment problem where the local rate of return is unobservable. Using non-linear filtering techniques and the martingale method he derived fairly explicit results. Thaleia Zariphopoulou introduced a new way to quantify performance measurement in asset allocation. Motivated by the martingale optimality principle she showed how optimal portfolios in this setup can be obtained by solving a fast diffusion equation posed inversely in time. Ralf Korn gave a review on old and new results for worstcase portfolio problems. He reported that he now found a HJB-system linking the indifference approach to classical stochastic control theory. Martin Schweizer’s talk was on utility indifference valuation of contingent claims H in an incomplete market driven by two Brownian motions where the traded and non-traded assets are stochastically correlated. He showed explicit formulas for the indifference value of H in case of exponential utility. Xin Guo established a new theoretical connection between singular control of finite variation and optimal switching problems. This approach provides a novel method for solving explicitly high-dimensional singular control problems. Jostein Paulsen considered two optimal dividend problems with and without reinvestment (which could prevent from ruin) and where dividend payments and reinvestment are subject to fixed and proportional cost. He gave an explicit solution in case the expected discounted payout minus reinvestment has to be maximized. Finally Mogens Steffensen studied optimal consumption and insurance payment streams in a multistate Markovian framework seen from the individuals’s perspective. He derived a general solution in case of power utility maximization. Multidimensional modeling in finance and insurance: It is obvious from the workshop that multidimensional (correlated) stochastic processes have become a very important topic recently. In particular as far as Lévy processes are concerned.In his talk, Filip Lindskog extended (under some conditions) the classical CramérWold results on projections and convergence of probability measures to measures with a singularity. This result can also be applied to Lévy processes. Thomas Mikosch showed how to combine functional regular variation with heavy-tailed large deviations for partial sums. As an application he derived asymptotic results for ruin probabilities of a multivariate random walk with regularly varying step sizes. Claudia Klüppelberg presented a multivariate model for operational risk processes. She discussed in particular the influence of the Lévy copula on the Value-at-risk of the summed process. Finally, Nicole Bäuerle showed how to characterize dependence properties and comparison results for Lévy processes with the help of the Lévy measure and the Lévy copula. Some applications in insurance and finance were reported. Recent Developments in Financial and Insurance Mathematics 551 Valuation of insurance products, credit risk and electricity markets: Several talks demonstrated that the mixture between financial and actuarial aspects of problems still is increasing. Thomas Møller told the audience that a new market for so-called mortality derivatives is now appearing due to the systematic risk in life insurance portfolios. He showed how insurers can reduce their risk by trading e.g. survivor swaps. Andrew Cairns discussed some new stochastic models for mortality, in particular the Olivier-Smith model which borrows ideas from interest rate modeling. Hailiang Yang investigated the valuation of insurance liabilities of equity-indexed annuities and participating life insurance policies where the equity price process is given by a Markov regime switching model. Alfred Müller reported on challenges in modeling electricity price processes and introduced a three-factor model for the spot market price which captures seasonal effects. Uwe Schmock presented a one-period model for dependent risks which generalizes both the standard collective risk model and CreditRisk and where the portfolio loss distribution can be computed with a numerically stable algorithm. Holger Kraft introduced a unified framework for modeling credit risks with bankruptcy and contagion and showed how to compute prices of derivatives in the setup. Risk measures and distributions with heavy tails: It is clear from the workshop that heavy tails still are an important topic as far as applications are concerned. Christian Hipp explained in his talk how third order asymptotic expansions for the tail probability of n-fold convolutions of claim sizes with regular varying tails can be computed. He ended with some conjectures about Weibull type and Lognormal type claim sizes. Jens Perch Nielsen talked about new approaches to regression which can determine the full distribution and where errors can have heavy tails. Hansjörg Furrer presented the evolution of the regulatory framework from Solvency 0 to Solvency II and posed some open questions concerning the risk measurement in a multi-period framework. Dirk Tasche investigated in his talk how kernel estimation can be combined with importance sampling to obtain efficient estimations of Value-at-risk contributions. In addition to the excellent scientific program, there were two scheduled social activities: Due to the splendid weather, the traditional hike to St. Roman on Wednesday afternoon was a true pleasure despite the muddy short-cut at the beginning. On Thursday night there was a piano concert given by Mogens Steffensen with a lot of entertaining Elton John songs. For some of the participants this was their first trip to Oberwolfach and they were very impressed by this experience. We, the organizers, would like to thank the ”Mathematisches Forschungsinstitut Oberwolfach” for providing such an excellent environment and for the technical support. The participants encouraged the idea of organizing a similar workshop in about three years. Søren Asmussen Nicole Bäuerle Ralf Korn Recent Developments in Financial and Insurance Mathematics 553 Recent Developments in Financial and Insurance Mathematics and the Interplay with the Industry

7 citations

References
More filters
Book
01 Jan 1994
TL;DR: In this article, Dixit and Pindyck provide the first detailed exposition of a new theoretical approach to the capital investment decisions of firms, stressing the irreversibility of most investment decisions, and the ongoing uncertainty of the economic environment in which these decisions are made.
Abstract: How should firms decide whether and when to invest in new capital equipment, additions to their workforce, or the development of new products? Why have traditional economic models of investment failed to explain the behavior of investment spending in the United States and other countries? In this book, Avinash Dixit and Robert Pindyck provide the first detailed exposition of a new theoretical approach to the capital investment decisions of firms, stressing the irreversibility of most investment decisions, and the ongoing uncertainty of the economic environment in which these decisions are made. In so doing, they answer important questions about investment decisions and the behavior of investment spending.This new approach to investment recognizes the option value of waiting for better (but never complete) information. It exploits an analogy with the theory of options in financial markets, which permits a much richer dynamic framework than was possible with the traditional theory of investment. The authors present the new theory in a clear and systematic way, and consolidate, synthesize, and extend the various strands of research that have come out of the theory. Their book shows the importance of the theory for understanding investment behavior of firms; develops the implications of this theory for industry dynamics and for government policy concerning investment; and shows how the theory can be applied to specific industries and to a wide variety of business problems.

10,879 citations

Book
01 Jan 1990
TL;DR: In this article, the authors propose a method for general stochastic integration and local times, which they call Stochastic Differential Equations (SDEs), and expand the expansion of Filtrations.
Abstract: I Preliminaries.- II Semimartingales and Stochastic Integrals.- III Semimartingales and Decomposable Processes.- IV General Stochastic Integration and Local Times.- V Stochastic Differential Equations.- VI Expansion of Filtrations.- References.

5,254 citations

Book
Rick Durrett1
01 Jan 1990
TL;DR: In this paper, a comprehensive introduction to probability theory covering laws of large numbers, central limit theorem, random walks, martingales, Markov chains, ergodic theorems, and Brownian motion is presented.
Abstract: This book is an introduction to probability theory covering laws of large numbers, central limit theorems, random walks, martingales, Markov chains, ergodic theorems, and Brownian motion. It is a comprehensive treatment concentrating on the results that are the most useful for applications. Its philosophy is that the best way to learn probability is to see it in action, so there are 200 examples and 450 problems.

5,168 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The optimality of a particular control limit policy is proved directly, with heavy reliance on the change of variable formula for semimartingales, to minimize the expected discounted sum of holding costs and control costs over an infinite planning horizon.
Abstract: A controller continuously monitors a storage system, such as an inventory or bank account, whose content Z = {Zt,t≥0} fluctuates as a (μ, σ2) Brownian motion in the absence of control. Holding costs are incurred continuously at rate h(Zt). At any time, the controller may instantaneously increase the content of the system, incurring a proportional cost of r times the size of the increase, or decrease the content at a cost of l times the size of the decrease. We consider the case where h is convex on a finite interval [α, β] and h = ∞ outside this interval. The objective is to minimize the expected discounted sum of holding costs and control costs over an infinite planning horizon. It is shown that there exists an optimal control limit policy, characterized by two parameters a and b (α ≤ a < b ≤ β). Roughly speaking, this policy exerts the minimum amounts of control sufficient to keep Zt ∈ [a, b] for all t ≥ 0. Put another way, the optimal control limit policy imposes on Z a lower reflecting barrier at a an...

273 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the problem of finding the optimal sequence of starting and stopping times of a multi-activity production process, given the costs of opening, running, and closing the activities and assuming that the economic system is a stochastic process, is formulated as an extended impulse control problem and solved using stochochastic calculus.
Abstract: This paper considers the problem of finding the optimal sequence of opening (starting) and closing (stopping) times of a multi- activity production process, given the costs of opening, running, and closing the activities and assuming that the state of the economic system is a stochastic process. The problem is formulated as an extended impulse control problem and solved using stochastic calculus. As an application, the optimal starting and stopping strategy are explicitly found for a resource extraction when the price of the resource is following a geometric Brownian motion.

227 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What are the contributions in "A class of singular control problems and the smooth fit principle" ?

This paper analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions are not necessarily smooth. Explicit solutions for the optimal policy and for the value functions are provided. Illustrative examples for both smooth and non-smooth cases are discussed, to highlight the pitfall of solving singular control problems with a priori smoothness assumptions. ∗This research is generously supported by grants from OpenLink Fund at the Coleman Fung Risk Management Research Center at UC Berkeley †Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research, UC Berkeley, CA 94720-1777, USA, Phone ( 510 ) 642 3615, email: xinguo @ ieor.