scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

A Class of Singular Control Problems and the Smooth Fit Principle

01 Nov 2008-Siam Journal on Control and Optimization (Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics)-Vol. 47, Iss: 6, pp 3076-3099
TL;DR: In particular, the authors analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions are not necessarily smooth and provides necessary and sufficient conditions for the well-known smooth fit principle, along with the regularity of the value functions.
Abstract: This paper analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions are not necessarily smooth. Necessary and sufficient conditions for the well-known smooth fit principle, along with the regularity of the value functions, are given. Explicit solutions for the optimal policy and for the value functions are provided. In particular, when payoff functions satisfy the usual Inada conditions, the boundaries between action and continuation regions are smooth and strictly monotonic, as postulated and exploited in the existing literature (see [A. K. Dixit and R. S. Pindyck, Investment under Uncertainty, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 1994]; [M. H. A. Davis et al., Adv. in Appl. Probab., 19 (1987), pp. 156-176]; [T. O. Kobila, Stochastics Stochastics Rep., 43 (1993), pp. 29-63]; [A. B. Abel and J. C. Eberly, J. Econom. Dynam. Control, 21 (1997), pp. 831-852]; [A. Oksendal, Finance Stoch., 4 (2000), pp. 223-250]; [J. A. Scheinkman and T. Zariphopoulou, J. Econom. Theory, 96 (2001), pp. 180-207]; [A. Merhi and M. Zervos, SIAM J. Control Optim., 46 (2007), pp. 839-876]; and [L. H. Alvarez, A General Theory of Optimal Capacity Accumulation under Price Uncertainty and Costly Reversibility, Working Paper, Helsinki Center of Economic Research, Helsinski, Finland, 2006]). Illustrative examples for both smooth and nonsmooth cases are discussed to emphasize the pitfall of solving singular control problems with a priori smoothness assumptions.

Summary (2 min read)

1 Introduction

  • Consider the following problem in reversible investment/capacity planning that arises naturally in resource extraction and power generation.
  • Facing the risk of market uncertainty, companies extract resources (such as oil or gas) and choose the capacity level in response to the random fluctuation of market price for the resources, subject to some capacity constraints, as well as the associated costs for capacity expansion and contraction.
  • Both necessary and sufficient conditions on the differentiability of the value function and on the smooth fit principle are established.
  • In fact, when the payoff function is not smooth, this paper is the first to rigorously characterize the action and no-action regions, and to explicitly construct both the optimal policy and the value function.

2.1 Problem

  • This is a continuous time formulation of the aforementioned risk management problem.
  • The goal of the company is to maximize its long-term profit with a payoff function that depends on both the resource extraction rate and the market price, with a form of H(Y )Xλ.
  • And the control problem can be reduced to an equivalent yet simpler singular control problem .
  • In fact, this equivalent control problem is more standard in the existing literature for both singular control and (ir)reversible investment.

3 Derivation of the Solution

  • The derivation goes as follows: first, a collection of corresponding optimal switching problems is established and solved; then, the consistency of the optimal switching controls is proved; finally, the existence of the corresponding integrable optimal singular control (ξ̂+, ξ̂−) ∈.
  • A′y is established and the corresponding value function are derived.
  • This method is built on the general correspondence between singular controls and switching controls outlined in Guo and Tomecek (2007).

3.1.2 Solution of the Optimal Switching Problems

  • The derivation of the value function proceeds analogously to the derivation for the case of h(z) >.
  • Moreover, these equations depend on z only through ν(z) and κ(z), implying that there exist unique constants κ, ν such that κ(z) ≡ κ and ν(z) ≡ ν for all z.

3.2 Derivation of the Optimal Switching Controls

  • The authors then define a collection of these switching controls and prove that this collection satisfies the consistency property from Guo and Tomecek (2007), which implies that it corresponds to an admissible singular control.
  • Note that since the regime values κ̂n are alternating, it suffices to define the switching times τ̂n.

3.2.2 Consistency of the Switching Controls

  • The collection of switching controls (α̂(x, z))z∈(a,b) is consistent.
  • Then the consistency follows from the following lemmas.
  • For simplicity, the authors omit the dependence on x from the notation.
  • Note that after the first switch, each subsequent switch requires that Xx move from (0, F (z)] to [G(z),∞) or vice versa.
  • In particular, this quantity is independent of z. Since log(Xx) is a Brownian motion with drift, its sample paths are almost surely uniformly continuous on [0, t].

3.3 Derivation of the Optimal Singular Control

  • Clearly, the following proposition holds, from Merhi and Zervos (2007).
  • Therefore, after verifying the Standing Assumptions A1, A2 and A3, one can invoke Guo and Tomecek (2007, Proposition 2.13, Theorem 3.13, Theorem 3.10) and conclude that there exists a corresponding integrable singular control (ξ̂+, ξ̂−) ∈.
  • To prove Theorem 2.5, the authors first establish some Lemmas.
  • (The second one follows by a similar argument, and the last one is immediate from the definition of C and the first two.).

4 Regularity, Smooth Fit and Region Characterization

  • The authors shall establish necessary and sufficient conditions for the smooth fit principle by exploiting both the structure of the payoff function and the explicit solution of the value function.
  • This analysis leads to the proof of Theorem 2.6 on region characterization.

4.1 Regularity and Smooth Fit

  • Therefore, d(x, ·) has only countably many discontinuities.
  • This theorem follows naturally from the following Lemma and the Proposition.
  • Thus fx must have at least two positive roots.

5 Examples and Discussions

  • By now, it is clear from their analysis that without sufficient smoothness of the payoff function, the value function may be non-differentiable and the boundaries may be non-smooth or not strictly monotonic.
  • Moreover, when the payoff function H is not continuously differentiable, the interior of C may not be simply connected.
  • Note, however, the regions S0, S1 and C are mutually disjoint and simply connected by the monotonicity of F and G.
  • The authors elaborate on these points with some concrete examples.

5.2 Discussion

  • The above examples demonstrate how the regularity assumptions typically assumed by the traditional HJB approach may fail.
  • Furthermore, Example 5.3 shows that in general, one may not have the smoothness of the boundary, as the boundaries F and G are not necessarily continuous or not even strictly increasing.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

UC Berkeley
Coleman Fung Risk Management Research Center Working
Papers 2006-2013
Title
A Class of Singular Control Problems and the Smooth Fit Principle
Permalink
https://escholarship.org/uc/item/8w46j0td
Authors
Guo, Xin
Tomecek, Pascal
Publication Date
2007-10-07
eScholarship.org Powered by the California Digital Library
University of California

University of California
Berkeley
Working Paper # 2007 -05
A Class of Singular Control Problems
and the Smooth Fit Principle
Xin Guo, UC Berkeley and Cornell University
Pascal Tomecek, Cornell University
October 7,2007

A Class of Singular Control Problems and the Smo oth Fit
Principle
Xin Guo
UC Berkeley and Cornell
Pascal Tomecek
Cornell University
October 7, 2007
Abstract
This paper analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions
are not necessarily smooth. Necessary and sufficient conditions for the well-known
smooth fit principle, along with the regularity of the value functions, are given. Explicit
solutions for the optimal policy and for the value functions are provided. In particular,
when payoff functions satisfy the usual Inada conditions, the boundaries between action
and no-action regions are smooth and strictly monotonic as postulated and exploited in
the existing literature (Dixit and Pindyck (1994); Davis, Dempster, Sethi, and Vermes
(1987); Kobila (1993); Abel and Eberly (1997); Øksendal (2000); Scheinkman and
Zariphopoulou (2001); Merhi and Zervos (2007); Alvarez (2006)). Illustrative examples
for both smooth and non-smooth cases are discussed, to highlight the pitfall of solving
singular control problems with a priori smoothness assumptions.
This research is generously supported by grants from OpenLink Fund at the Coleman Fung Risk Man-
agement Research Center at UC Berkeley
Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research, UC Berkeley, CA 94720-1777, USA,
Phone (510) 642 3615, email: xinguo@ieor.berkeley.edu.
Scho ol of Operations Research and Industrial Engineering, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853-3801,
USA, Phone (607) 255 1270, Fax (607) 255 9129, email: pascal@orie.cornell.edu.
1

1 Introduction
Consider the following problem in reversible investment/capacity planning that arises nat-
urally in resource extraction and power generation. Facing the risk of market uncertainty,
companies extract resources (such as oil or gas) and choose the capacity level in response
to the random fluctuation of market price for the resources, subject to some capacity con-
straints, as well as the associated costs for capacity expansion and contraction. The goal of
the company is to maximize its long-term profit, subject to these constraints and the rate
of resource extraction.
This kind of capacity planning with price uncertainty and partial (or no) reversibility
originated from the economics literature and has since attracted the interest of the ap-
plied mathematics community. (See Dixit and Pindyck (1994); Brekke and Øksendal (1994);
Davis, Dempster, Sethi, and Vermes (1987); Kobila (1993); Abel and Eberly (1997); Baldurs-
son and Karatzas (1997); Øksendal (2000); Scheinkman and Zariphopoulou (2001); Wang
(2003); Chiarolla and Haussmann (2005); Guo and Pham (2005) and the references therein.)
Mathematical analysis of such control problems has evolved considerably from the initial
heuristics to the more sophisticated and standard stochastic control approach, and from
the very special case study to general payoff functions. (See Harrison and Taksar (1983);
Karatzas (1985); Karatzas and Shreve (1985); El Karoui and Karatzas (1988, 1989); Ma
(1992); Davis and Zervos (1994, 1998); Boetius and Kohlmann (1998); Alvarez (2000, 2001 );
Bank (2005); Boetius (2005)). Most recently, Merhi and Zervos (2007) analyzed this problem
in great generality and provided explicit solutions for the special case where the payoff is of
Cobb-Douglas type. Their method is to directly solve the HJB equations, assuming certain
regularity conditions for both the value function and the boundaries between the action and
no-action regions. Guo and Tomecek (2007) later established sufficient conditions for the
smoothness of the value function by connecting the singular control problem with a collection
of optimal switching problems.
However, for many singular control problems in reversible investment and in areas such
as queuing and wireless communications (Martins, Shreve, and Soner (1996); Assaf (1997);
Harrison and Van Mieghem (1997); Ata, Harrison, and Shepp (2005)), there is no regularity
for either the value function or the boundaries. Therefore, two important mathematical issues
remain: 1) necessary conditions for regularity properties; and 2) characterization for the
value function and for the action and no-action regions when these regularity conditions fail.
Understanding these issues is especially important in cases where only numerical solutions
are available, and for which the assumption on the degree of the smoothness is wrong (see
also discussions in Section 5.2).
This paper addresses these two issues via the study of a class of singular control problems.
Both necessary and sufficient conditions on the differentiability of the value function and on
the smooth fit principle are established. Moreover, these conditions lead to a derivative-
based characterization of the investment, disinvestment and continuation regions even for
non-smooth value functions. In fact, when the payoff function is not smooth, this paper is the
2

first to rigorously characterize the action and no-action regions, and to explicitly construct
both the optimal policy and the value function. To be consistent with the literature in
(ir)reversible investment, the running payoff function in this paper depends on the resource
extraction rate and the market price in the form of H(Y )X
λ
. It is worth noting that H(·)
is any concave function of the capacity, and may be neither monotonic nor differentiable.
This includes the special cases investigated by Guo and Pham (2005); Merhi and Zervos
(2007); Guo and Tomecek (2007). In particular, when H satisifies the well-known Inada
conditions (i.e., continuously differentiable, strictly increasing, strictly concave, with H(0) =
0, H
0
(0
+
) = , H
0
() = 0), our results show that the boundaries between regions are
indeed continuous and strictly increasing as postulated and exploited in previous works:
Dixit and Pindyck (1994); Davis, Dempster, Sethi, and Vermes (1987); Kobila (1993); Abel
and Eberly (1997); Øksendal (2000); Scheinkman and Zariphopoulou (2001); Merhi and
Zervos (2007); Alvarez (2006). Also note that our method can be applied to more general
(diffusion) processes for the price dynamics, other than the geometric Brownian motion
assumed for explicitness in this paper. Finally, the construction between the functional form
of the boundaries and the payoff function itself is also novel, as the value function and the
boundaries may be neither smooth nor strictly monotonic as in the existing literature.
The most relevant and recent work to this paper is Alvarez (2006), which provides a
great deal of economic insight into the problem. However, Alvarez (2006) only handles
payoff functions satisfying the Inada conditions. In contrast, our solution is independent of
the regularity of the payoff and value functions.
Outline. The control problem is formally stated, with its value function and optimal p olicy
described in Section 2; details of the derivation are in Section 3. The main result of this
paper regarding the regularity of the value function is in Section 4. Examples are provided
in Section 5, including cases for which the value function is not differentiable, the optimal
controlled process not continuous, the boundaries of the action regions not smooth, and the
interior of the continuation region not simply connected.
2 Mathematical Problem and Solution
2.1 Problem
Let (Ω, F, F, P) be a filtered probability space and assume a given bounded interval [a, b]
(−∞, ). Consider the following problem:
Problem A.
V
H
(x, y) := sup
(ξ
+
)∈A
00
y
J
H
(x, y; ξ
+
, ξ
),
3

Citations
More filters
08 Jun 2023
TL;DR: In this article , the authors consider a class of zero-sum stopper vs. singular controller games, where the controller can only act on a subset of the coordinates of a controlled diffusion.
Abstract: We consider a class of zero-sum stopper vs.\ singular-controller games in which the controller can only act on a subset $d_0

1 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper , the problem of optimal dividend payout strategies from a surplus process governed by Brownian motion with drift under a drawdown constraint was addressed, i.e., the dividend rate can never decrease below a given fraction of its historical maximum.
Abstract: Abstract In this paper, we address the problem of optimal dividend payout strategies from a surplus process governed by Brownian motion with drift under a drawdown constraint, i.e., the dividend rate can never decrease below a given fraction $a$ a of its historical maximum. We solve the resulting two-dimensional optimal control problem and identify the value function as the unique viscosity solution of the corresponding Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation. We then derive sufficient conditions under which a two-curve strategy is optimal, and we show how to determine its concrete form using calculus of variations. We establish a smooth-pasting principle and show how it can be used to prove the optimality of two-curve strategies for sufficiently large initial and maximum dividend rates. We also give a number of numerical illustrations in which the optimality of the two-curve strategy can be established for instances with smaller values of the maximum dividend rate and the concrete form of the curves can be determined. One observes that the resulting drawdown strategies nicely interpolate between the solution for the classical unconstrained dividend problem and that for a ratcheting constraint as recently studied in Albrecher et al. (SIAM J. Financial Math. 13:657–701, 2022). When the maximum allowed dividend rate tends to infinity, we show a surprisingly simple and somewhat intriguing limit result in terms of the parameter $a$ a for the surplus level above which, for a sufficiently large current dividend rate, a take-the-money-and-run strategy is optimal in the presence of the drawdown constraint.

1 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a degenerate singular stochastic control problem is considered, where the objective is to minimize an expected functional involving the time-integral of a running cost and the proportional costs of adjusting the drift.
Abstract: We consider a standard Brownian motion whose drift can be increased or decreased in a possibly singular manner. The objective is to minimize an expected functional involving the time-integral of a running cost and the proportional costs of adjusting the drift. The resulting two-dimensional degenerate singular stochastic control problem has interconnected dynamics and it is solved by combining techniques of viscosity theory and free boundary problems. We provide a detailed description of the problem’s value function and of the geometry of the state space, which is split into three regions by two monotone curves. Our main result shows that those curves are continuously differentiable with locally Lipschitz derivative and solve a system of nonlinear ordinary differential equations.

1 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors proved the existence and uniqueness of the solution to this Dynkin game through an associated variational inequality problem involving Dirichlet form and showed that the properties of the value function of this game imply the smoothness of the stochastic singular control problem.
Abstract: The traditional difficulty about stochastic singular control is to characterize the regularities of the value function and the optimal control policy. In this paper, a multi-dimensional singular control problem is considered. We found the optimal value function and the optimal control policy of this problem via Dynkin game, whose solution is given by the saddle point of the cost function. The existence and uniqueness of the solution to this Dynkin game are proved through an associated variational inequality problem involving Dirichlet form. As a consequence, the properties of the value function of this Dynkin game implies the smoothness of the value function of the stochastic singular control problem. In this way, we are able to show the existence of a classical solution to this multi-dimensional singular control problem, which was traditionally solved in the sense of viscosity solutions, and this enables the application of the verification theorem to prove optimality.

1 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, a stochastic control model to optimize banks' dividend and recapitalization policies and calibrate that to a sample of U.S. banks in the situation where they model banks' true accounting asset values as partially observed variables due to the opaqueness in banks' assets.
Abstract: This thesis mainly focuses on two problems in capital structure and individual's life-cycle portfolio choice. In the first problem, we derive a stochastic control model to optimize banks' dividend and recapitalization policies and calibrate that to a sample of U.S. banks in the situation where we model banks' true accounting asset values as partially observed variables due to the opaqueness in banks' assets. By the calibrated model, the noise in reported accounting asset values hides about one-third of the true asset return volatility and raises the banks' market equity value by 7.8\% because the noise hides the banks' solvency risk from banking regulators. Particularly, those banks with a high level of loan loss provisions, nonperforming assets, and real estate loans, and with a low volatility of reported total assets have noisy accounting asset values. Because of the substantial shock on the true asset values, the banks' assets were more opaque during the recent financial crisis. In the second problem, we present an optimal portfolio selection model with voluntary retirement option in an economic situation, where an investor is facing borrowing and short sale constraints, as well as the cointegration between the stock and labor markets. Our model reinterprets the non-participation puzzle in stock investment and early retirement in market booms. Investor's willingness to retire earlier becomes stronger as risk aversion increases or as wages decline in the long term. Consistent with the empirical evidence, we find that retirement flexibility makes the optimal portfolio invest less in the stock market. We also find that our model-generated portfolio share rises in wealth.

1 citations

References
More filters
Book
01 Jan 1994
TL;DR: In this article, Dixit and Pindyck provide the first detailed exposition of a new theoretical approach to the capital investment decisions of firms, stressing the irreversibility of most investment decisions, and the ongoing uncertainty of the economic environment in which these decisions are made.
Abstract: How should firms decide whether and when to invest in new capital equipment, additions to their workforce, or the development of new products? Why have traditional economic models of investment failed to explain the behavior of investment spending in the United States and other countries? In this book, Avinash Dixit and Robert Pindyck provide the first detailed exposition of a new theoretical approach to the capital investment decisions of firms, stressing the irreversibility of most investment decisions, and the ongoing uncertainty of the economic environment in which these decisions are made. In so doing, they answer important questions about investment decisions and the behavior of investment spending.This new approach to investment recognizes the option value of waiting for better (but never complete) information. It exploits an analogy with the theory of options in financial markets, which permits a much richer dynamic framework than was possible with the traditional theory of investment. The authors present the new theory in a clear and systematic way, and consolidate, synthesize, and extend the various strands of research that have come out of the theory. Their book shows the importance of the theory for understanding investment behavior of firms; develops the implications of this theory for industry dynamics and for government policy concerning investment; and shows how the theory can be applied to specific industries and to a wide variety of business problems.

10,879 citations

Book
01 Jan 1990
TL;DR: In this article, the authors propose a method for general stochastic integration and local times, which they call Stochastic Differential Equations (SDEs), and expand the expansion of Filtrations.
Abstract: I Preliminaries.- II Semimartingales and Stochastic Integrals.- III Semimartingales and Decomposable Processes.- IV General Stochastic Integration and Local Times.- V Stochastic Differential Equations.- VI Expansion of Filtrations.- References.

5,254 citations

Book
Rick Durrett1
01 Jan 1990
TL;DR: In this paper, a comprehensive introduction to probability theory covering laws of large numbers, central limit theorem, random walks, martingales, Markov chains, ergodic theorems, and Brownian motion is presented.
Abstract: This book is an introduction to probability theory covering laws of large numbers, central limit theorems, random walks, martingales, Markov chains, ergodic theorems, and Brownian motion. It is a comprehensive treatment concentrating on the results that are the most useful for applications. Its philosophy is that the best way to learn probability is to see it in action, so there are 200 examples and 450 problems.

5,168 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The optimality of a particular control limit policy is proved directly, with heavy reliance on the change of variable formula for semimartingales, to minimize the expected discounted sum of holding costs and control costs over an infinite planning horizon.
Abstract: A controller continuously monitors a storage system, such as an inventory or bank account, whose content Z = {Zt,t≥0} fluctuates as a (μ, σ2) Brownian motion in the absence of control. Holding costs are incurred continuously at rate h(Zt). At any time, the controller may instantaneously increase the content of the system, incurring a proportional cost of r times the size of the increase, or decrease the content at a cost of l times the size of the decrease. We consider the case where h is convex on a finite interval [α, β] and h = ∞ outside this interval. The objective is to minimize the expected discounted sum of holding costs and control costs over an infinite planning horizon. It is shown that there exists an optimal control limit policy, characterized by two parameters a and b (α ≤ a < b ≤ β). Roughly speaking, this policy exerts the minimum amounts of control sufficient to keep Zt ∈ [a, b] for all t ≥ 0. Put another way, the optimal control limit policy imposes on Z a lower reflecting barrier at a an...

273 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the problem of finding the optimal sequence of starting and stopping times of a multi-activity production process, given the costs of opening, running, and closing the activities and assuming that the economic system is a stochastic process, is formulated as an extended impulse control problem and solved using stochochastic calculus.
Abstract: This paper considers the problem of finding the optimal sequence of opening (starting) and closing (stopping) times of a multi- activity production process, given the costs of opening, running, and closing the activities and assuming that the state of the economic system is a stochastic process. The problem is formulated as an extended impulse control problem and solved using stochastic calculus. As an application, the optimal starting and stopping strategy are explicitly found for a resource extraction when the price of the resource is following a geometric Brownian motion.

227 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What are the contributions in "A class of singular control problems and the smooth fit principle" ?

This paper analyzes a class of singular control problems for which value functions are not necessarily smooth. Explicit solutions for the optimal policy and for the value functions are provided. Illustrative examples for both smooth and non-smooth cases are discussed, to highlight the pitfall of solving singular control problems with a priori smoothness assumptions. ∗This research is generously supported by grants from OpenLink Fund at the Coleman Fung Risk Management Research Center at UC Berkeley †Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research, UC Berkeley, CA 94720-1777, USA, Phone ( 510 ) 642 3615, email: xinguo @ ieor.