scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

A retrospective on friedman's theory of permanent income*

01 Jun 2004-The Economic Journal (Institute for Fiscal Studies)-Vol. 114, Iss: 496, pp 293-306
TL;DR: Friedman's Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIF) is one of the great works of economics as mentioned in this paper, and it has been used extensively in modern economics and discusses some relevant empirical results and the way they relate to the original approach.
Abstract: Friedman’s book on the “Consumption Function” is one of the great works of Economics demonstrating how the interplay between theoretical ideas and data analysis could lead to major policy implications. We present a short review of Friedman’s Permanent Income Hypothesis, the origins of the idea and its theoretical foundations. We give a brief overview of its influence in modern economics and discuss some relevant empirical results and the way they relate to the original approach taken by Friedman.

Summary (2 min read)

Introduction

  • The theory of the Consumption function played an important role in explaining why traditional Keynesian demand management, through transitory tax policy or other transitory income boosting measures can have little or no effect on real consumption and on the desired policy outcomes.
  • The apparently simple ideas in this excellent book have been so insightful and powerful that they have given rise to a huge amount of research, both theoretical and empirical, which continues to this date.
  • Particularly that which has been based on microeconomic data, and I demonstrate the relevance of these ideas for their current way of thinking about consumption, savings and income processes.

A statement of the Hypothesis

  • Milton Friedman’s PI hypothesis originates from the basic intuition that individuals would wish to smooth consumption and not let it fluctuate with short run fluctuations in income.
  • The basic hypothesis posited is that individuals consume a fraction of this permanent income in each period and thus the average propensity to consume would equal the marginal propensity to consume.
  • He brings together empirical results and statistical theory, and develops new results by combining these with his economic ideas.
  • By comparing averages over time or across different groups of individuals, Friedman is implicitly using Instrumental variables, now a well recognised technique for dealing with classical measurement error in linear models.
  • Wald (1940) suggested comparing group averages to overcome measurement error, although the way he approached grouping was not quite right.

The notions of Permanent Income

  • The PIH provides a flexible framework for the study of consumption and savings.
  • Much of the subsequent research has filled in those elements necessary for explaining aspects of the data, thus defining the agenda for research on consumption and savings.
  • The basic hypothesis requires a rolling horizon, which allows some degree of smoothing of consumption.
  • The flexibility of the hypothesis comes at a price, since it is hard to define the theoretical underpinnings of the model, and consequently it is hard to make more detailed statements about policy.
  • Friedman points this out in the Consumption function book when he states that that permanent income is best defined “… to be whatever seems to correspond to consumer behaviour.”.

The theoretical foundations of the PIH

  • There have been other attempts to explain consumption behaviour.
  • The key implication of this model ttt E R cU λ β =)(' is that the marginal utility of consumption in each period is equal to the expected marginal utility of wealth multiplied by a factor depending on the interest rate and the rate of time preference.
  • Whether this will be detectable in the data will depend on the proportion of individuals who are thus constrained.
  • This is not too say that this is not important, but to lay the ground for arguing that a more general version of the PIH, with similar foundations is in fact consistent with the data, although the version of the PIH developed here is probably too restrictive.

Risk aversion, and the PIH

  • Given that markets are never found to be complete (e.g. Cochrane, 1991) and Attanasio and Davis, 1996) and given aggregate uninsurable shocks this must be a central issue.
  • While these ideas were not formalised at the time they turn out to be key elements in demonstrating that some generalised version of the PIH does in fact fit the data very well and can explain observed consumption patterns.
  • It may for example be reasonable to think that more consumption is shifted towards the household when it consists of more members.
  • Heckman (1974) pointed out that if consumption is not additively separable from hours of work and this is ignored, the resulting consumption choices over time will look as if they track income, in a way that would reject the basic premise of the permanent income hypothesis.
  • The study of income processes has been motivated in part by the study of consumption and savings because it has become apparent that knowing the time series properties of income may be informative about consumption behaviour.

Conclusions

  • Most important discoveries and insights are simple, economical, have important implications for a broad range of issues and withstand the test of time.
  • Moreover, they generate large amounts of research, verifying it and refining it.
  • This is exactly the case with Friedman’s PIH.
  • At the end of all this, the original idea has not only survived, but has formed the basis for developing a coherent analysis of consumption and savings.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

A RETROSPECTIVE ON FRIEDMANS
THEORY OF PERMANENT INCOME
Costas Meghir
THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES
WP04/01

A Retrospective on Friedman’s Theory of Permanent Income
Costas Meghir
1
University College London and Institute for Fiscal Studies
November 2002
This Version January 2004
Abstract
Friedman’s book on the “Consumption Function” is one of the great works of Economics
demonstrating how the interplay between theoretical ideas and data analysis could lead to
major policy implications. We present a short review of Friedman’s Permanent Income
Hypothesis, the origins of the idea and its theoretical foundations. We give a brief
overview of its influence in modern economics and discuss some relevant empirical
results and the way they relate to the original approach taken by Friedman.
1
Acknowledgements: This article was prepared for a conference in honour of Milton Friedman at the
University of Chicago in November 2002, on the occasion of his 90
th
Birthday. I thank the organisers for
the invitation. I also thank Orazio Attanasio, Richard Blundell, Martin Browning, Jim Heckman, Hide
Ichimura, an anonymous referee and colleagues at IFS and UCL for useful discussions that helped me
organise this presentation. I am of course responsible for all errors and interpretations.

Introduction
Friedman’s book on the “Consumption Function” is one of the great works of Economics
demonstrating how the interplay between theoretical ideas and data analysis could lead to
major policy implications. The theory of the Consumption function played an important
role in explaining why traditional Keynesian demand management, through transitory tax
policy or other transitory income boosting measures can have little or no effect on real
consumption and on the desired policy outcomes. The apparently simple ideas in this
excellent book have been so insightful and powerful that they have given rise to a huge
amount of research, both theoretical and empirical, which continues to this date. In this
short article I trace out some of the research relating to the Permanent Income Hypothesis
(PIH), particularly that which has been based on microeconomic data, and I demonstrate
the relevance of these ideas for our current way of thinking about consumption, savings
and income processes.
Friedman and Kuznets (1954) “Incomes from Independent Professional Practice” which
was actually written in the early 1940s but delayed in publication, first formulated many
of the ideas of the PIH, including the permanent/transitory decomposition of income in
the volume. The core of these ideas, together with further tests, was brought together in
Friedman’s “Consumption function”. In my review of the PIH I draw mainly from this
latter work.

The Permanent Income Hypothesis
A statement of the Hypothesis
Milton Friedman’s PI hypothesis originates from the basic intuition that individuals
would wish to smooth consumption and not let it fluctuate with short run fluctuations in
income. In fact the model was developed to explain important empirical facts in a unified
framework. For example, why is income more volatile than consumption and why is the
long run marginal propensity to consume out of income higher than the short run one. To
answer these questions Friedman hypothesized that individuals base their consumption on
a longer term view of an income measure, perhaps a notion of lifetime wealth or a notion
of wealth over a reasonably long horizon. The basic hypothesis posited is that individuals
consume a fraction of this permanent income in each period and thus the average
propensity to consume would equal the marginal propensity to consume. The propensity
itself could vary with a number of factors, including the interest rate and taste shifter
variables, or could reflect uncertainty – we will return to these important insights below.
Friedman set himself the task of testing his hypothesis against an increasing set of
empirical facts from time series data and budget studies. The standard least squares
regression of consumption on income would always point to a marginal propensity to
consume below the average propensity. Conditioning on extra regressors seems to make
things worse. It is at this point that Friedman’s ingenuity, brought together the literature

on budget studies by Margaret Reid, Morgan and others
2
, as well as time series analyses
with Econometric ideas on measurement error to devise estimation techniques, that not
only allowed the testing of the basic hypothesis, but led to the estimation of underlying
parameters that directly characterised the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). As far as
the role of measurement error is concerned the works of great economists and
statisticians of the time, namely Harold Hotelling
3
and James Durbin, influenced
Friedman. He brings together empirical results and statistical theory, and develops new
results by combining these with his economic ideas.
The ingredients of Friedman’s model are permanent consumption (
p
c
), permanent
income (
p
y ), transitory consumption (
t
c ), transitory income (
t
y ). Measured income is
the sum of
permanent and transitory income (
t
y
) and measured consumption is the sum
of
permanent and transitory consumption (
t
c
), i.e.
tp
ccc +=
and
tp
yyy +=
Permanent consumption is determined by the equation
pp
yzrkc ),(=
where
),( zrk is the average (or marginal) propensity to consume out of permanent
income which depends on the rate of interest and on taste shifter variables z. The
2
See Reid (1952) and Morgan (1951).
3
See Hotelling (1933) and Friedman (1992) on the regression fallacy.

Citations
More filters
01 Jan 2019
TL;DR: In this paper, the Inverse hyperbolic sine (IHS) function is introduced as an alternative to the logarithm for zero values, allowing for the creation of descriptive statistics that take into account periods of unemployment and changes in employment status.
Abstract: Female earnings are underrepresented in the earnings and earnings dynamics literature. This underrepresentation is largely a result of the di erences in participation rates between male and female workers. Female workers tend to have more frequent changes in employment status, and more periods of unemployment than their male counterparts. These periods of unemployment result in observations with zero earnings, and common transformations such as the logarithm are not de ned for zero values. This means that any analysis of the logarithm of earnings is forced to exclude periods where an individual does not work, and cannot take into account the e ect of moving into or out of employment. The higher rate of unemployment in female workers also increases the risk of sample selection bias. If selection into employment is non-random, then estimating earnings equations based on only workers will result in biased estimates. This thesis takes a novel approach by focusing on the annual earnings of females, and in doing so introduces two methods for addressing the issues associated with zero earnings observations. First, the Inverse Hyperbolic Sine (IHS) function is introduced as an alternative to the logarithm. The IHS is de ned for zero values, allowing for the creation of descriptive statistics that take into account periods of unemployment and changes in employment status. While the IHS has many properties that are useful when working with annual earnings, this thesis also highlights a number of estimation issues that can arise when using the function that have not previously been mentioned in the literature. Second, a new correction for sample selection bias that has been proposed by Semykina and Wooldridge (2013) is used to model the annual earnings of female workers. Both the sample selection bias correction and the IHS are applied to data on prime aged females from the Survey of Families, Income, and Employment (SoFIE) data set.

4 citations


Cites background from "A retrospective on friedman's theor..."

  • ...First, in Friedman’s permanent income hypothesis, individuals react differently to permanent versus transitory shocks to earnings, with differing effects on individual decision making and the level of consumption (Baker and Solon, 1999; Meghir, 2004)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper , the authors investigate empirically the channels through which Islamic and/or conventional banking can spur economic growth in MENA region using a range of developed econometric approaches, including panel cointegration technique, panel Granger causality test and a panel-based vector error correction model (VECM).
Abstract: Purpose The purpose of this paper is to investigate empirically the channels through which Islamic and/or conventional banking can spur economic growth in MENA region. Design/methodology/approach The study uses a range of developed econometric approaches, including panel cointegration technique, panel Granger causality test and a panel-based vector error correction model (VECM), to analyze explicitly all the causal relationships among Islamic banking, conventional banking development and economic growth in a unified framework. Findings The empirical results show that Islamic banking in MENA countries not only leads to economic growth but also affects positively and significantly conventional banking development. Thus, Islamic banking has an active role and could be classified as “supply-following” since its development only leads to economic growth, whereas conventional banking, with passive role, could be classified as “demand-following” since it only reacts to economic growth in long run. Research limitations/implications The study has two principal limitations. It is conducted within a relatively limited time period and sample of countries. Also, the used models did not take into account the impact of others financial and macroeconomic variables like stock market development, interest rate, inflation and financial crisis. Practical implications The results have two main implications. First, in MENA countries, well-functioning Islamic banking sector could not only promote economic growth but also can be served as a development factor for their conventional one. Second, unlike conventional banks, the customer of Islamic banks seems not to be motivated by interest and profits. Rather religious factors are recommended as the main motive for investing and saving in Islamic banks. Originality/value The study tries to perceive whether there exists a substitution or complementarity effect between Islamic and conventional banking in promoting economic growth for MENA countries. This situation is neither revealed nor clarified in the relevant literature.

4 citations

01 Jan 2012
TL;DR: In this article, the authors describe the development of population health and disability insurance in Sweden, summarized as follows: "Disability Insurance, Population Health, and Employment in Sweden".
Abstract: This thesis consists of five papers, summarized as follows. "Disability Insurance, Population Health, and Employment in Sweden"This paper describes the development of population health and disabili ...

4 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors apply Friedman's (1957) permanent income hypothesis by distinguishing between temporary and permanent effects of income changes, which allows them to account for intertemporal spillovers of income compensations.
Abstract: Unemployment causes significant losses in the quality of life. In addition to reducing individual income, it also creates non-pecuniary, psychological costs. We quantify these non-pecuniary losses by using the life satisfaction approach. In contrast to previous studies, we apply Friedman's (1957) permanent income hypothesis by distinguishing between temporary and permanent effects of income changes. This allows us to account for intertemporal spillovers of income compensations. Our results show that, without this distinction, the non-pecuniary costs of unemployment are overestimated by roughly one-third. Nevertheless, the non-pecuniary costs of unemployment with this modified quantification method still amount to 2.3 (1.5) times the pure pecuniary costs of unemployment for men (women). This confirms the high value of work for life satisfaction.

4 citations


Cites background from "A retrospective on friedman's theor..."

  • ...For comprehensive surveys of the literature on empirical tests of the PIH, see Deaton (1992), Browning and Lusardi (1996), Browning and Crossley (2001), and Meghir (2004)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper , the authors investigate the multidisciplinary theoretical context of financial capability and provide a critical examination of 14 relevant theoretical frameworks, including financial literacy and psychological financial capability, where the former represents automatic and controlled mental processes.
Abstract: This paper investigates the multidisciplinary theoretical context of financial capability and provides a critical examination of 14 relevant theoretical frameworks. To this end, the paper defines financial capability and develops a new theoretical framework of financial capability termed the personal financial management system. Financial capability is defined as the capacity of consumers to undertake comprehensive financial activities and thereby achieve personal financial well-being. The exploration of financial capability includes the concepts of financial literacy and psychological financial capability, where the latter represents automatic and controlled mental processes. Recent advances in behavioural science have profoundly changed the realm of personal finances, and it is, therefore, essential to acknowledge the importance of the intuitive reasoning that shapes our financial decision making. As part of the financial management system's throughput, together with individual motivation and opportunity within the personal financial management system, financial capability forms financial behaviour. The framework identifies three groups of relevant antecedents of financial capability including sociodemographic factors, cognitive and affective factors and personality and values. By constructing a comprehensive theoretical model, this paper contributes to the literature by providing greater consistency in the definitions of capability and its related terms, encouraging academic discussion and affirming the much-needed directions for future research.

4 citations

References
More filters
Book
01 Jan 1936
TL;DR: In this article, a general theory of the rate of interest was proposed, and the subjective and objective factors of the propensity to consume and the multiplier were considered, as well as the psychological and business incentives to invest.
Abstract: Part I. Introduction: 1. The general theory 2. The postulates of the classical economics 3. The principle of effective demand Part II. Definitions and Ideas: 4. The choice of units 5. Expectation as determining output and employment 6. The definition of income, saving and investment 7. The meaning of saving and investment further considered Part III. The Propensity to Consume: 8. The propensity to consume - i. The objective factors 9. The propensity to consume - ii. The subjective factors 10. The marginal propensity to consume and the multiplier Part IV. The Inducement to Invest: 11. The marginal efficiency of capital 12. The state of long-term expectation 13. The general theory of the rate of interest 14. The classical theory of the rate of interest 15. The psychological and business incentives to liquidity 16. Sundry observations on the nature of capital 17. The essential properties of interest and money 18. The general theory of employment re-stated Part V. Money-wages and Prices: 19. Changes in money-wages 20. The employment function 21. The theory of prices Part VI. Short Notes Suggested by the General Theory: 22. Notes on the trade cycle 23. Notes on mercantilism, the usury laws, stamped money and theories of under-consumption 24. Concluding notes on the social philosophy towards which the general theory might lead.

15,146 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the theory of interest was restated and the output of capital goods and of consumption was analyzed in terms of uncertainty and fluctuations of investment, and demand and supply for output as a whole.
Abstract: I. Comments on the four discussions in the previous issue of points in the General Theory, 209. — II. Certain definite points on which the writer diverges from previous theories, 212. — The theory of interest restated, 215. — Uncertainties and fluctuations of investment, 217. — III. Demand and Supply for output as a whole, 219. — The output of capital goods and of consumption, 221.

5,476 citations

Journal ArticleDOI

5,379 citations


"A retrospective on friedman's theor..." refers methods in this paper

  • ...…of the Euler equation approach for the study of savings and consumption, the introduction of Rational expectations in economic modelling and the Lucas (1976) critique, provided both the motivation and the means by which to develop tests of the PIH that did not involve measuring PI, at least…...

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: JSTOR transmission may be copied, downloaded,stored, further transmitted, transferred, distributed, altered, or otherwise used, in any form or by any means, except: (1) one stored electronic and one paper copy of any article solely for personal, non-commercial use, or (2) with prior written permission of JSTOR and the publisher of the article or other text.
Abstract: Youruse of the JSTOR database indicates your acceptance of JSTOR’s Termsand Conditions of Use. A copy of JSTOR’s Terms and Conditions of Useis available at http://www.jstor.ac.uk/about/terms.html, by contacting JSTORatjstor@midas.ac.uk, or by calling JSTOR at 0161 275 7919 or (FAX) 0161 275 6040. Nopart ofaSTOR transmission may be copied, downloaded,stored, further transmitted, transferred, distributed, altered, or otherwise used, in any form or by any means, except: (1) one stored electronic and one paper copy ofanyarticle solely for your personal, non-commercial use, or (2) with prior written permission of JSTOR andthe publisher of the article or other text.

5,069 citations


"A retrospective on friedman's theor..." refers background in this paper

  • ...…appeal, it is a special case of an intertemporal optimisation model of consumer behaviour, which is the most coherent and logically consistent model we have at present.3 This model has its roots in the works of Fisher (1907) and Ramsey (1928) and has since been developed in many directions....

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "A retrospective on friedman’s theory of permanent income" ?

The authors present a short review of Friedman ’ s Permanent Income Hypothesis, the origins of the idea and its theoretical foundations. The authors give a brief overview of its influence in modern economics and discuss some relevant empirical results and the way they relate to the original approach taken by Friedman. This article was prepared for a conference in honour of Milton Friedman at the University of Chicago in November 2002, on the occasion of his 90 Birthday.