scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

A Road Map for Efficiently Taxing Heterogeneous Agents

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
The authors characterizes optimal labor-income taxes that depend on age, household assets, and filing status (one or two earners) within a life-cycle model with heterogeneous, two-member households and endogenous human capital.
Abstract
This paper characterizes optimal labor-income taxes that depend on age, household assets, and filing status (one or two earners) within a life-cycle model with heterogeneous, two-member households and endogenous human capital. The key innovation is a labor supply elasticity that varies endogenously among households. I find that tax distortions should be hump shaped in age, decrease in household assets, and be lower for joint relative to single filers. Age and assets act as complements within the optimal tax policy. In contrast, filing status neither complements nor crowds out the age and asset tag. Overall, a tax system using all three tags can increase consumption up to 6.4 percent and welfare up to 1.5 percent.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Online Appendix for “A Road Map for Efficiently Taxing
Heterogeneous Agents”
Marios Karabarbounis
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
August 5, 2015
A Alternative models: Aggregate Effects
This section reports the aggregate effects of the optimal labor-income policy in the “Ex-
ogenous Human Capital” model and the “Constant Elasticity Model.”
Table 1 reports the effects and welfare gains for the model with exogenous human capital.
Overall, the aggregate effects are in the same range. In addition, the presence of endogenous
human capital seems to add 0.1% to our welfare gains. Table 2 compares the effects of the
the age- and assets- dependent tax reform for both models. Changes in macro variables and
welfare gains are close to the ones found in the benchmark economy. Table 2 also reports the
effects in macro aggregates and welfare gains for different values of labor supply elasticity.
1
A larger value of labor supply elasticity can increase labor supply (and capital) by a larger
amount. However, welfare gains seem robust across specifications.
1
In the benchmark model the (heterogeneity in) labor supply elasticity depends mostly on the distribution
of reservation wages and not on the value θ (see Hansen (1985), Rogerson (1988), and Chang and Kim (2006)).
In contrast, varying parameter θ
c
in the CEM will affect uniformly all agents.
1

Table 1: Aggregate Effects of Tax Reform: Benchmark and Exogenous Human Capital
Model Benchmark Exogenous Human Capital
K +19.7% +20.3%
L +2.7% +2.8%
C +6.4% +6.0%
w +5.6% +5.7%
r -1.0% -1.0%
Cons. Gini -0.2% -0.5%
CEV +1.5% +1.4%
Note: The Table reports the percentage change in aggregates due to the tax reform. The tax reform includes age, household
assets, and filing status as tax tags. Results are presented for the benchmark case and two alternative specifications. A model
with exogenous human capital accumulation and a model with constant elasticity of labor supply.
Table 2: Aggregate Effects of Tax Reform: Benchmark and CEM
Model Benchmark CEM
θ
c
= 0.4 θ
c
= 0.73 θ
c
= 1.5
K +17.7% +18.9% +18.4% +22.2%
L +0.6% +0.6% +0.9% +1.7%
C +3.7% +3.0% +3.1% +4.2%
w +5.8% +6.1% +5.9% +6.8%
r -1.1% -0.3% -0.3% -0.4%
Cons. Gini +0.3% +0.2% +0.2% +0.2%
CEV +1.0% +1.1% +1.1% +1.0%
Note: The Table reports the percentage change in aggregates due to the tax reform. The tax reform includes age and household
assets as tax tags. Results are presented for the benchmark case and a model with constant elasticity of labor supply. For the
latter case, I present the effects of the optimal tax system for a variety of labor supply elasticities: θ
c
= 0.4,θ
c
= 0.73, θ
c
= 1.5.
B Simpler Policies
In this section, I restrict the age-dependent tax system to simpler forms. In particular, I
analyze a linear form, τ
00
+ τ
01
j, a second-degree polynomial, τ
00
+ τ
01
j + τ
02
j
2
, and compare
them to our benchmark specification: τ
00
+ τ
01
j + τ
02
j
2
+ τ
03
j
3
. The aggregate effects and
2

optimal tax properties are shown in Table 3 and Figure 1, respectively.
Table 3: Age-dependent Taxes: Simpler Functional Forms
Linear Second-Degree Benchmark
Functional Form τ
00
+ τ
01
j τ
00
+ τ
01
j + τ
02
j
2
τ
00
+ τ
01
j + τ
02
j
2
+ τ
03
j
3
K +5.3% +5.0% +9.5%
L -1.0% -0.7% +0.8%
C +0.1% +0.4% +0.9%
w +2.2% +2.0% +4.1%
r -0.4% -0.4% +0.6%
Cons. Gini -1.1% -1.3% -1.7%
CEV +0.2% +0.3% +0.4%
Note: The table reports the percentage change in aggregates due to an age-dependent tax reform. Results are presented for a
linear tax function, a second-degree polynomial and the benchmark specification.
Figure 1: Optimal Age-dependent Taxes: Simpler Functional Forms
20 30 40 50 60 70
−0.08
−0.03
0.02
0.07
0.12
0.17
0.22
0.27
0.32
τ
0
Age
Optimal Tax by Age
Current U.S.
Linear
Second Degree
Benchmark
Note: The figure plots the properties of optimal age-dependent taxes for different functional forms: linear, second-degree
polynomial and benchmark case (third-degree polynomial).
A linear increasing function increases capital by a smaller amount compared to the bench-
mark. Moreover, labor supply decreases as the tax distortion induces older households to
retire earlier. If the tax function is a second-degree polynomial then the tax distortion also
increases but a smaller rate for older households. This makes the employment reduction small-
3

er. Using the benchmark specification (third-degree polynomial), we can increase capital by a
larger amount but also increase employment. The flexibility allows to increase tax distortions
steeply up to age 50 and decrease taxes after that age. Although relatively small, welfare
gains double compared to a linear tax function.
C Household’s Problem: Value Functions
In this section, I write the value function for a household employing the female worker
V
{NE,E}
and a household whose members are not employed V
{NE,N E}
. The value function
for a household employing the female worker is:
V
{NE,E}
zj
(a, x, κ, E
1
) = max
c,a
0
,h
f
(
log(c) + ψ
m
j
(1 h
m
)
1θ
1 θ
+ ψ
f
j
(1 h
f
)
1θ
1 θ
ζ(E
f
1
)
+βs
j+1
X
x
m
0
X
x
f
0
Γ
x
m
x
0
m
Γ
x
f
x
0
f
[
(1 λ
m
)
1 p
X
s={2,3}
p
s
V
1
z(j+1)
(a
0
, x
0
, κ
s
, E) +
λ
m
1 p
X
s={2,3}
p
s
V
{NE,N E}
z(j+1)
(a
0
, x
0
, κ
s
, E)]
(1)
s.t. h
f
= 0 (2)
(1+τ
c
)c +a
0
= (1τ
ss
)W T
L
(W ; S)+(1+r(1τ
k
))(a +T r) (3)
E = {u, e} (4)
The value function for a household with no earners is:
4

V
{NE,N E}
zj
(a, x, κ, E
1
) = max
c,a
0
(
log(c) + ψ
m
j
(1 h
m
)
1θ
1 θ
+ ψ
f
j
(1 h
f
)
1θ
1 θ
+βs
j+1
X
x
m
0
X
x
f
0
Γ
x
m
x
0
m
Γ
x
f
x
0
f
V
2
z(j+1)
(a
0
, x
0
, κ
0
, E)]
(5)
s.t. h
m
= 0, h
f
= 0 (6)
(1+τ
c
)c+a
0
= (1+r(1τ
k
))(a+T r) (7)
E = {u, u} (8)
References
Chang, Y., and Kim, S.-B. (2006). “From individual to aggregate labor supply: a quantitative
analysis based on a heterogeneous agent macroeconomy”. International Economic Review,
47 (1), 1-27.
Hansen, G. D. (1985). “Indivisible labor and the business cycle”. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 16 (3), 309-327.
Rogerson, R. (1988). “Indivisible labor, lotteries and equilibrium”. Journal of Monetary
Economics, 21 (1), 3-16.
5
Citations
More filters
Book ChapterDOI

Macroeconomics and Household Heterogeneity

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigate how households in different segments of the wealth distribution were affected by income declines, and how they changed their expenditures differentially during the aggregate downturn and find that wealth inequality can significantly amplify the impact of an aggregate shock, and it does so if the distribution features a sufficiently large fraction of households with very little net worth that sharply increase their saving (i.e., they are not hand-to-mouth) as the recession hits.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Young, the Old, and the Government: Demographics and Fiscal Multipliers

TL;DR: In this article, the authors used a parsimonious life-cycle open-economy New Keynesian model with credit market imperfections to study the relationship between local fiscal multipliers and demographics.
Journal ArticleDOI

Health, health insurance, and retirement: a survey

TL;DR: The mechanisms through which health affects retirement are described and how these mechanisms interact with public pensions and public health insurance are discussed.
Journal ArticleDOI

The effects of collecting income taxes on Social Security benefits

TL;DR: In this paper, a detailed life-cycle model of labor supply, saving, and Social Security claiming is presented to assess the impact of Social Security benefits subject to income taxation, a provision that can significantly increase the marginal income tax rate for older individuals.
Journal ArticleDOI

Greater Inequality and Household Borrowing: New Evidence from Household Data

TL;DR: Coibion et al. as discussed by the authors show that low-income households in high-inequality regions (zip codes, counties, states) accumulated less debt relative to their income than low- income households in lower inequality regions.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Indivisible labor and the business cycle

TL;DR: In this paper, a growth model with shocks to technology is studied, and it is shown that, unlike previous equilibrium models of the business cycle, this economy displays large fluctuations in hours worked and relatively small fluctuations in productivity.
Journal ArticleDOI

Finite state markov-chain approximations to univariate and vector autoregressions

TL;DR: In this article, the authors developed a procedure for finding a discrete-valued Markov chain whose sample paths approximate well those of a vector autoregression, which has applications in economics, finance, and econometrics where approximate solutions to integral equations are required.
Journal ArticleDOI

Indivisible labor, lotteries and equilibrium

TL;DR: In this article, the authors consider an economy where labor is indivisible and agents are identical and show that the discontinuity in labor supply at the individual level disappears as a result of aggregation.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Effects of Health, Wealth, and Wages on Labour Supply and Retirement Behaviour

TL;DR: In this paper, a life cycle model of labour supply, retirement, and savings behavior in which future health status and wages are uncertain is presented, and the model establishes that the tax structure of the Social Security system and pensions are key determinants of the high observed job exit rates at ages 62 and 65.
Posted Content

Consumption and Risk Sharing Over the Life Cycle

TL;DR: This article found that uncertainty distributed throughout the working years accounts for 40 percent of life time uncertainty, with the remainder being realized prior to entering the labor market and the shocks received over the life cycle contain a highly persistent component, with an autocorrelation coefficient between 0.98 and unity.
Related Papers (5)