scispace - formally typeset

BookDOI

A short history of India's economy: A chapter in the Asian drama

01 Oct 2018-Research Papers in Economics (Helsinki: The United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER))-

Abstract: This paper is a short history of the Indian economy since 1968. India today is a changed country from what it was half a century ago, when Myrdal published his Asian Drama. The stranglehold of low growth has been broken, its population below the poverty line has fallen markedly, and India has joined the pantheon of major players globally. This paper analyses the economic policies and the politics behind this transformation; and uses that as a backdrop to take stock of the huge challenges that lie ahead.
Topics: Population (52%), Drama (50%)

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

WIDER Working Paper 2018/124
A short history of India's economy
A chapter in the Asian drama
Kaushik Basu*
October 2018

* Department of Economics and SC Johnson College of Business Cornell University, Ithaca and New York, kb40@cornell.edu.
This study has been prepared within the UNU-WIDER project on ‘Asian Transformations: An Inquiry into the Development of
Nations’.
Copyright © UNU-WIDER 2018
Information and requests: publications@wider.unu.edu
ISSN 1798-7237 ISBN 978-92-9256-566-4 https://doi.org/10.35188/UNU-WIDER/2018/566-4
Typescript prepared by Joseph Laredo.
The United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research provides economic analysis and policy
advice with the aim of promoting sustainable and equitable development. The Institute began operations in 1985 in Helsinki,
Finland, as the first research and training centre of the United Nations University. Today it is a unique blend of think tank, research
institute, and UN agencyproviding a range of services from policy advice to governments as well as freely available original
research.
The Institute is funded through income from an endowment fund with additional contributions to its work programme from
Finland, Sweden, and the United Kingdom as well as earmarked contributions for specific projects from a variety of donors.
Katajanokanlaituri 6 B, 00160 Helsinki, Finland
The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s), and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Institute or the United
Nations University, nor the programme/project donors.
Abstract: This paper is a short history of the Indian economy since 1968. India today is a changed
country from what it was half a century ago, when Myrdal published his Asian Drama. The
stranglehold of low growth has been broken, its population below the poverty line has fallen
markedly, and India has joined the pantheon of major players globally. This paper analyses the
economic policies and the politics behind this transformation; and uses that as a backdrop to take
stock of the huge challenges that lie ahead.
Keywords: India, growth history, political economy, corruption, technological change
JEL classification: A12, B10, B31, N14, O10
Acknowledgements: This paper was presented at WIDER conferences in Hanoi, on 9–10 March
2018, and in Shanghai, on 2930 June 2018. It has benefitted greatly from comments and
suggestions by Tony Addison, Alaka Basu, Amit Bhaduri, Prasenjit Duara, Guanghua Wan, Rolph
van der Hoeven, Sudipto Mundle, Siddiq Osmani, Daniel Poon, Frances Stewart, and Finn Tarp.
I am also grateful to Deepak Nayyar and an anonymous referee for detailed comments on the
penultimate version. I thank Haokun Sun and Gowtham Muthukkumaran for very able research
assistance.

1
1 Gunnar Myrdal and India
My first encounter with Gunnar Myrdal’s Asian Drama was soon after its publication. I joined
Delhi University’s St. Stephen’s College as an undergraduate in 1969. One of our professors,
Kalyanjit Roy Choudhury, a voracious reader, told us with excitement about this new, mammoth
publication. Soon the book became the ultimate fashion statement for students on our campus.
To be seen crossing the college yard with one of the volumes of the book in hand raised one’s
status. To be seen talking about what was in it raised it even more. It was a case of good
competition, which helped raise the level of erudition of my generation of students.
The publication, half a century ago, of this three-volume magnum opus, focused on South Asia,
predominantly India, and more tangentially on several Southeast Asian nations, marked a turning
point not just for the economics students of Delhi University, but for all those engaged in the
study of economic history, political economy, and development. Treating the region as focus,
Myrdal ranged over economics, history, and politics. His work would leave its mark on the region
and on economics itself. Its mark on economics occurred because what Myrdal was attempting,
admittedly in an inchoate way, amounted to an early precursor of both New Institutional
Economics and Behavioural Economics. This was his insistence that to understand the
performance of economies as complex as those of India and its neighbours, we have to view
economics as a discipline embedded in sociology, psychology, and politics.
Because Myrdal was charting such a new course, Asian Drama was both pioneering and flawed, as
we now know with the hindsight of recent research in behavioural and institutional economics.
We can see these twin traits in his analysis of India’s economy. In looking at India’s sluggish growth
and the vast numbers living in extreme poverty, Myrdal often allowed his pessimism to show
through. As he wrote,
If in a country like India the government were really determined to change the
prevailing attitudes and institutions, and had the courage to take the necessary
steps and accept the consequences, then these would include the effective
abolition of caste, prescribed by the constitution, […] land reform and tenancy
legislation, […] the eradication of corruption at all levels [,] forceful attack on the
problem of the educated unemployed and their refusal to do manual work, and so
on. (Myrdal 1968: 368
1
).
One senses in this a pessimism that is deep. It is a concerned pessimism, one that stems almost
from a frustration with a test case of a nationin this case Indiabreaking out of the stranglehold
of colonialism, and one he wishes would succeed and become a prototype for others. This
commitment deserves appreciation, but the remark also suggests an inadequate understanding of
the complexity of interaction between economics and politics and the troublesome idea of the
endogeneity of institutions. His questioning If […] the government were really determinedand
suggestion that the abolition of caste’ and eradication of corruptionare matters of choice by an
agent called government or by individuals that constitute the government reveals a rather simplistic
view of government as an exogenous institution. This is a common presumption in economics.
We would not, for instance, say that the market’s failure shows that consumers are not determined.
It is arguable that the level of determination a government exhibits is not an exogenous variable,
1
All page references to Asian Drama are to the widely used version edited by Seth King (Allen Lane 1972).

2
and, even if it were, it is not clear that governments have within their wherewithal the ability to
control many of the social ills like discrimination and corruption. The persistence of these ills is
not necessarily evidence of political leaders condoning them, even though it often is. We have to
use more sophisticated analysis to separate out the cases where the corruption is being condoned
or even encouraged, and where it is being haplessly suffered because its mitigation is beyond the
leader’s reachor any individual’s reach, for that matter. Many of our worst social ills are collective
traps.
Fortunately, economics has moved on since then and even taken some small steps to reach out to
the neighbouring disciplines of politics, psychology, and sociology by trying to conceptualize
institutions as endogenous structures. While Myrdal deserves credit for venturing out to some of
these, rather treacherous, multi-disciplinary terrains so early, the social sciences at that time did not
have the tools and theoretical constructs to do justice to such inter-disciplinary trespassing. As a
consequence, we can now share the concern that Myrdal had for the theatre of Asia and at the
same time bring some of the more contemporary, multi-disciplinary social science methods to bear
on the project. That is what I shall attempt to do in this paper, whose focus is India and, in
particular, India’s economy. But in keeping with the above observation I look at some of
economics’ neighbouring disciplines insofar as they have a bearing on the subject matter of this
paper.
India is today a changed country from what it was half a century ago. It still has huge challenges
staring it in the face but, at the same time, the country has long since broken with the ‘Hindu rate
of growth, its population below the poverty line has fallen steadily since the late 1960s, and sharply
over the last decade, and it has joined the pantheon of major players globally. One way of
celebrating Asian Drama is to take stock of what India has done since the time of its publication in
1968 and peer into the future to assess the challenges that lie ahead, and that is what I propose to
do in this paper. In the spirit of Myrdal’s work, my aim here is to analyse and not provide a
comprehensive description. The description is done selectively, with an eye to providing material
for the analysis. Myrdal himself noted: As our main concern is analytical rather than merely
descriptive, we have not felt obligated to produce exhaustive factual details.(Myrdal 1968: 17).
The paper continues with a brief analysis of the political backdrop of the Indian economy. This is
followed, in Section 3, by a short and selective description of India’s growth experience since
Independence but with special attention to what happened in the 1970s onward. Thereafter, in
Section 4, I turn to some contemporary challenges for India. It should be pointed out at the outset
that the challenges are numerous; so I select areas within my expertise and where I have some
ideas to offer. The final section of the paper consists of a peering into the future.
2 Politics first
From the vantage point of hindsight, it seems quite remarkable that India did what no other newly
independent developing country did. It invested in politics firstestablishing democracy, free
speech, independent media, and equal rights for all citizens. At one level all progressive leaders
around the world tried this. After the end of World War II, as nations broke from the yoke of
imperialism and became independent, we had not just Jawaharlal Nehru in India, but Bung Karno
Sukarno in Indonesia, Mohammad Ali Jinnah in Pakistan, Kwame Nkrumah in Ghana, Julius
Nyerere in Tanzania, and several other leaders trying to put their nation on an even keel politically,
and build political institutions to promote inclusive economic development. But in most cases it
did not last. Coups, chaotic responses, and the lust for power caused democracy to collapse in one
nation after another, bringing in military rule and conflict. A map of democracy around the world

3
in 1985 would show a bleak landscape in virtually all developing and emerging nations. India was
the exception.
While a large part of the credit for this does go to the early political leaders, Mahatma Gandhi,
Nehru, and Ambedkar, and to progressive writers and intellectuals like Rabindranath Tagore,
Periyar E.V. Ramaswamy, and Sarojini Naidu, as in all matters of history, luck also plays a role.
And India had it in ample measure. In any case, the upshot was that in terms of political design
and structure, with regular elections, a progressive constitution, secularism, free media, and an
empowered supreme court, India resembled an advanced nation, and in this respect had very few
peers in the developing world.
2
India’s downside turned out to be its economy. With growth sluggish, large swathes of population
living in abject poverty, and widespread illiteracy, the country trudged along decade after decade,
while several other nations, like South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, and Hong Kong, starting from
roughly the same level of economic prosperity in the 1950s, took off in spectacular ways. Some
would argue that this sluggishness was in part caused by India’s democracy and progressive politics,
and that, if there had been a dictator, he or she would have pulled the economy out of the vicious
circle of poverty. I will comment on this later. But the fact remains that whether or not this causal
explanation from politics to economics has any merit, two things do stand out: early India’s
remarkable political achievements and the persistent economic stagnation for at least three decades
after its independence.
Two caveats to the above claim ought to be made. First, the description should not convey the
impression of nothing happening during these first decades. Despite overall growth remaining
subdued at around 3.5 per cent per annum, much was happening beneath that. Taking a page out
of the Soviet model, India tried to institute five-year planning, with an effort to set up heavy
industries, large-scale steel production, and dam-building to generate electricity on a large scale.
Second, somewhere in the mid-1960s India had a successful ‘green revolution’ and broke out of
the trap of low agricultural productivity and frequent famines. Though this was most visible in
Punjab, Haryana, and western Uttar Pradesh, its benefits were felt across the nation.
The second caveat is that the slow growth of the early years should not be taken as an indicator of
the nation’s independence not having an impact on the economy. Independence was good for
India, even in terms of the yardstick of pure economic growth. Sivasubramonian’s (2000)
comprehensive statistical study shows that annual growth, from being negligible during the first
50 years of the 20
th
century, moved up to somewhere between 3 and 3.5 per cent in the decades
immediately after the country’s independence in 1947. Nayyar (2006) in his Kingsley Martin lecture
at Cambridge University in fact identifies 1951 and 1980 as the two turning points in India’s growth
in the 20th century. I will have occasion to dispute his second turning point but that will come
later.
There would be a short interruption in democracy in 1975, when the Prime Minister, Indira
Gandhi, declared an Emergency and took dictatorial control over the nation. For those who
believe dictatorship helps economic growth, the Emergency seemed like a godsend because, in
1975/76, India’s GDP growth rate hit 9 per cent, an unimaginable figure at that time and, it is also
believed, the trains ran on time. However, if these hardliners studied the growth trend thereafter,
they would be deflated. Growth thereafter began to decline and, by 1979/80, it had plummeted to
2
For discussion, see Sen (2005) and Basu (2009). For one of the most authoritative studies of the interface between
politics and economics in India, see Bardhan (1998).

Citations
More filters

Journal ArticleDOI
Heather Eggins1Institutions (1)

25 citations


ReportDOI
Abstract: Globalization and robotics (globotics) are transforming the world economy at an explosive pace. While much of the literature has focused on rich nations, the changes are quite likely to affect developing nations in important ways. The premise of the paper - which should be regarded as a thought-piece - is based on an extreme thought experiment. What does development look like when digitech has rendered manufacturing jobless and many services freely traded? Our conclusion is that the service-led development path may become the norm rather than the exception; think India, not China. Since success in the service sector is based on quite different factors than success in manufacturing, development strategies and mindsets may have to change. This is an optimistic conclusion since it suggests that developing nations can directly export the source of their comparative advantage - low-cost labor - without having first to make goods with that labor.

16 citations


Book ChapterDOI
01 Jan 2012

7 citations


BookDOI
01 Dec 2018

5 citations


Cites background from "A short history of India's economy:..."

  • ...…spectrum from almost unrestricted openness in Singapore, through moderated openness in Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Thailand, and Turkey, or calibrated also discuss the role of the state—see Lin (2018), Basu (2018), Timmer (2018), Tarp (2018), Wade (2018), Montes (2018), and Osmani (2018)....

    [...]

  • ...18 See Lin (2018), Basu (2018), Timmer (2018), Tarp (2018), Wade (2018), Montes (2018), and Osmani (2018)....

    [...]


Posted Content
Abhijit Banerjee1Institutions (1)
Abstract: A wide range of interventions, from subsidized grains all the way to conditions on nutrition in conditional cash transfers, have either been tried or put in place in different countries in order to fight under-nutrition. A number of important policy experiments in recent years, directly or indirectly, offer important insights into how best to design these interventions. This essay is an attempt to pull together some of those insights, with the aim of saying something about what the optimal design should look like.

4 citations


References
More filters

Book
01 Jan 1995
Abstract: From the Publisher: In recent years, debate on the state's economic role has too often devolved into diatribes against intervention. Peter Evans questions such simplistic views, offering a new vision of why state involvement works in some cases and produces disasters in others. To illustrate, he looks at how state agencies, local entrepreneurs, and transnational corporations shaped the emergence of computer industries in Brazil, India, and Korea during the seventies and eighties. Evans starts with the idea that states vary in the way they are organized and tied to society. In some nations, like Zaire, the state is predatory, ruthlessly extracting and providing nothing of value in return. In others, like Korea, it is developmental, promoting industrial transformation. In still others, like Brazil and India, it is in-between, sometimes helping, sometimes hindering. Evans's years of comparative research on the successes and failures of state involvement in the process of industrialization have here been crafted into a persuasive and entertaining work, which demonstrates that successful state action requires an understanding of its own limits, a realistic relationship to the global economy, and the combination of coherent internal organization and close links to society that Evans calls "embedded autonomy."

3,803 citations


Book
01 Jun 1968
Abstract: Every once in a long while the flood of new publications will wash a book onto the market that manages a particularly astute grasp of our present situation with a combination of originality and sharp analytical under standing. We may then be provided with an entirely new basis for the discussion of some of our traditional problems. Such is the case with Gunnar Myrdal's new epic An Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations. Myrdal's inquiry into the economic problems of the countries of South Asia lasted nearly ten years. The result is a three-volume study of monu mental proportions covering 2,284 pages. Prologue and introduction alone run to 70 pages and are, strictly speaking, already a small, self-contained book on problems of applied methodology. A search for a handy con cluding chapter turns out to be in vain. A course in speed-reading, then, appears to be a prerequisite. This book has been received in the West with decided discomfort, not to say horror, while in the underdeveloped countries of Asia it has caused consternation and pain: horror in the West for fear that Myrdal is saying the billions spent on development aid over the last 20 years have been wasted; pain in Asia for fear that he is saying the whole economic and social mess is really the fault of the Asians themselves. v Myrdal is saying both. Indeed, his analysis bears some superficial re semblance to the rhetoric that comes out of Peking, Algiers and Havana. But he has scrupulously avoided the doctrinaire muddle that has paralyzed development in China, Algeria and Cuba. Instead he opts for a new pragmatism that is neither pure capitalism nor pure Marxism but incor porates elements of both. His emphasis is on clarity of expression and thought, his search for true scientific freedom from bias and prejudice. This was no easy task. The difficulties started with the available statis tics that have been quoted in professional journals and elsewhere for a long time and with surprising confidence. Myrdal found, however, that in 118

1,218 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
Abstract: Opinions on the causes of India's growth deceleration vary. World economic growth was slower in the second half of the 1990s, and that would have had some dampening effect, but India's dependence on the world economy is not large enough for this to account for the slowdown. Critics of liberalization have blamed the slowdown on the effect of trade policy reforms on domestic industry. However, the opposite view is that the slowdown is due not to the effects of reforms, but rather to the failure to implement the reforms effectively. This in turn is often attributed to India's gradualist approach to reform, which has meant a frustratingly slow pace of implementation. However, even a gradualist pace should be able to achieve significant policy changes over ten years. This paper examines India's experience with gradualist reforms from this perspective.

607 citations


"A short history of India's economy:..." refers background in this paper

  • ...The economic reforms of 1991–93 in India have been analysed extensively (see Nayyar 1996; Ahluwalia 2002; Mohan 2002)....

    [...]


Book
Ronald J. Herring1Institutions (1)
01 Jan 1984

488 citations


"A short history of India's economy:..." refers background in this paper

  • ...For one of the most authoritative studies of the interface between politics and economics in India, see Bardhan (1998)....

    [...]

  • ...2 For discussion, see Sen (2005) and Basu (2009). For one of the most authoritative studies of the interface between politics and economics in India, see Bardhan (1998)....

    [...]


Journal ArticleDOI
Abstract: Twenty-five percent of teachers were absent from school, and only about half were teaching, during unannounced visits to a nationally representative sample of government primary schools in India. Absence rates varied from 15% in Maharashtra to 42% in Jharkhand, with higher rates concentrated in the poorer states. We do not find that higher pay is associated with lower absence. Older teachers, more educated teachers, and head teachers are all paid more but are also more frequently absent; contract teachers are paid much less than regular teachers but have similar absence rates; and although relative teacher salaries are higher in poorer states, absence rates are also higher. Teacher absence is more correlated with daily incentives to attend work: teachers are less likely to be absent at schools that have been inspected recently, that have better infrastructure, and that are closer to a paved road. We find little evidence that attempting to strengthen local community ties will reduce absence. Teachers from the local area have similar absence rates as teachers from outside the community. Locally controlled nonformal schools have slightly higher absence rates than schools run by the state government. The existence of a PTA is not correlated with lower absence. Private-school teachers are only slightly less likely to be absent than public-school teachers in general, but are 8 percentage points less likely to be absent than public-school teachers in the same village. (JEL: O15, I21, H41, H52)

406 citations


"A short history of India's economy:..." refers background in this paper

  • ...It is otherwise hard to explain why, though teachers are paid the same salary and subjected to the same rules of economic incentives and punishments across the nation, teacher truancy is Jharkhand is about three times as high as that in Maharashtra, as the Kremer et al. (2004) study shows....

    [...]

  • ...A multi-country study in which researchers made surprise visits to government-run primary schools shows that in terms of teacher truancy, India is second only to Uganda (Kremer et al. 2004)—and by a short head....

    [...]


Performance
Metrics
No. of citations received by the Paper in previous years
YearCitations
20211
20201
20192
20181
20151
20122