scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

A Simple and Flexible Alternative to Stability and Growth Pact Deficit Ceilings: Is it at Hand?

TL;DR: In this article, the authors model a monetary union where fiscal discretion generates excessive debt accumulation in steady state and inefficiently delayed debt adjustment following shocks, and call for more focused supervision tasks for the European Commission and for parliamentary discussion whenever a disagreement arises between the Commission and a national government.
About: This article is published in European Journal of Political Economy.The article was published on 2012-03-01 and is currently open access. It has received 66 citations till now. The article focuses on the topics: Debt adjustment & Stability and Growth Pact.

Summary (2 min read)

1. Introduction

  • The Maastricht Treaty and the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) provide the institutional framework that regulates fiscal policies within the European Monetary Union.
  • In this paper the authors review the working of the SGP after the 2005 reform and in the light of novel empirical evidence they advocate further reform.
  • In addition, the Greek debt buildup highlights a dramatic failure of both the surveillance framework and the pre-emptive arm of the Pact (Rehn, 2010).
  • The authors results call for the de facto demise of deficit ceilings, that cause inefficient stabilisation in the face of adverse shocks but in normal times allow countries to satisfy the ceiling even if policies are relatively undisciplined.
  • The European Commission would act as the “sound fiscal conscience” for national governments, and public debates in national Parliaments would trigger media coverage sufficient to provide adequate information to voters.

2. From the old to the new Pact

  • The Maastricht Treaty specifies that EU fiscal policies are run nationally, following EU-wide objectives defined for a three year period by the Council of Economic and Finance Ministers in the Broad Economic Policy Guidelines2 , and within the limits set by the SGP.
  • The MTO is expected to vary according to a country’s own initial debt-to-GDP ratio and to potential growth.
  • Hence the key commitment of the original SGP was to set the "… medium-term objective of budgetary positions close to balance or in surplus…" which "… will allow all Member States to deal with normal cyclical fluctuations while keeping the government deficit within the reference value of 3% of GDP".
  • The sanctions for breaking the 3% upper ceiling are detailed in the Excessive Deficit Procedure (EDP) which is specified by Council Regulation 1467/97 included in the SGP.
  • Several contributions pointed out that the old ‘corrective arm’ could not discipline procyclical fiscal in good times (Bean, 1998; CESifo, 2002; Canzoneri and Diba, 2001).

3. EMU fiscal policies in practice

  • There seems to be a general consensus that “a counter-cyclical response of discretionary fiscal policies seems to be the exception rather than the rule.”.
  • Estimates of changes in CAPB run separately for good and bad times reveal a pro-cyclical bias in good times and no bias in bad times.
  • The improvement of the overall balance for EMU countries since the adoption of the SGP actually masks unchanged (small countries) or deteriorating (large countries) cyclically adjusted primary balances with respect to the early post-Maastricht years.
  • Unlike the studies quoted above, the authors do not consider the pre-1999 period.
  • In Table 2 the authors present some basic correlations, confirming this analysis.

4. Theoretical underpinnings of a flexible debt targeting approach

  • The authors consider here a version of Jensen’s (1994) model of debt accumulation, extended to account for both supply shocks and the loss of monetary sovereignty that characterizes EMU membership.
  • In each country, the social welfare function is11 ststististi s sti s ti kGGkyL LW (3) where * is the discount factor, *, ~GG sti and *~ st denote public expenditure and inflation deviations from the socially optimal levels respectively.
  • The combination of idiosyncratic shocks and inflation targeting implies that sst *~ and allows to sharpen the analysis of fiscal policy12.
  • For sake of simplicity the authors therefore neglect this component of the budget constraint.
  • Thus, the term DDk sti ~,3 may be interpreted as follows: i) the target D~ defines the level of debt which would emerge if non-distortionary taxes were available in a world where bequest-constrained individuals affect politico-economic equilibria; ii) 3k represents the political cost of tolerating debt deviations from D~ 16.

4.3 The fiscal policy problem under a debt targeting rule

  • Furthermore, the model has a clear policy prescription, linking national deficits to country-specific cyclical conditions and to country-specific accumulation of debt.
  • In the next section the authors shall discuss how, in principle, EMU institutions could deliver that.

5. Turning the SGP into a flexible debt targeting regime

  • Taken at face value, the new SGP is consistent with their proposal of endorsing a long-term debt target.
  • Third, the new SGP acknowledges the role of past debt in assessing a country’s budgetary objectives ex-ante, but fails to condition deficits on past debt: deviations from MTOs are corrected in a fixed proportion of GDP and faster adjustment is typically enforced on countries characterized by relatively low debt ratios (see their discussion in section 3 above).
  • The Commission’s recommendation was certainly consistent with the SGP provisions.
  • To obtain this, new provisions should require that, in case of disagreement with the Commission, the government would then be required to report to national Parliament, publicly motivating its decisions.
  • In New Zealand the government chooses the inflation target.

6. Conclusions

  • Compared to the SGP, even in its ‘new’ post-2005 form, their proposal scores better with respect to the twin goals of long-term public finance sustainability and economic stabilization in the face of adverse shocks.
  • In their view, their comparison with fiscal policies implemented in non-EMU countries once more confirms that the SGP binds when it should not.
  • The sensitivity of expenditures to the current debt burden (equation 13) may be interpreted as follows.
  • The policymaker’s reluctance to tolerate debt deviations from the target works in the opposite direction: the larger is coefficient 3k , the less sensitive is the deficit to shock.
  • The authors wish to thank for very useful comments Enzo Dia and Jacques Melitz.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors theoretically and empirically document a puzzle that arises when an RBC economy with a job matching function is used to model unemployment, and show that either sticky wages or match-specific productivity shocks can improve the model's performance by making the firm's flow of surplus more procyclical.

412 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, a generalized theoretical approach to study imitation and subject it to rigorous experimental testing is introduced and the authors find that the different predictions of previous imitation models are mainly explained by different informational assumptions, and to a lesser extent by different behavioral rules.

259 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: The hypothesis is worth considering that this adverse development is related to the greater social inequality, an inferior health care system, and fewer social safety nets in the United States than in Western and Northern Europe, in spite of higher per capita income.
Abstract: Within the course of the 20th century the American population went through a metamorphosis from being the tallest in the world, to being among the most overweight. The American height advantage over Western and Northern Europeans was between 3 and 9 cm in the middle of the 19th century. Americans were also underweight. However, today, the exact opposite is the case as the Dutch, Swedes, and Norwegians are the tallest, and the Danes, British and Germans - even the East-Germans - are also taller, towering over the Americans by as much as 3-7 cm. Americans also live shorter. The hypothesis is worth considering that this adverse development is related to the greater social inequality, an inferior health-care system, and fewer social safety nets in the United States than in Western and Northern Europe, in spite of higher per capita income. The West- and Northern European welfare states, with cradle to grave health and unemployment insurance currently provide a more propitious environment for the biological standard of living than its US counterpart.

242 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors developed a framework to analyze the incentives to form a patent pool or engage in cross-licensing arrangements in the presence of uncertainty about the validity and coverage of patents that makes disputes inevitable.
Abstract: This paper develops a framework to analyze the incentives to form a patent pool or engage in cross-licensing arrangements in the presence of uncertainty about the validity and coverage of patents that makes disputes inevitable. It analyzes the private incentives to litigate and compares them with the social incentives. It shows that pooling arrangements can have the effect of sheltering invalid patents from challenges. This result has an antitrust implication that patent pools should not be permitted until after patentees have challenged the validity of each other’s patents if litigation costs are not too large.

187 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: This paper examined the identity and development of the European business cycle using quarterly GDP data for some 30 years up to and including 2001, and concluded that it is quite hard to discern a homogeneous or developing "European cycle" with these data.
Abstract: The paper uses quarterly GDP data for some 30 years up to and including 2001, to examine the identity and development of the European business cycle. Cycles are identified by using a band-pass filter version of the Hodrick-Prescott filter and affiliations are examined using clustering techniques and classical multidimensional scaling applied to cross-correlations and other measures of cyclical sympathy. Twenty-three (23) countries are examined, of which 15 are European. The sample is divided into three 10-year periods to examine changes in affiliation. The overall verdict is that it is quite hard to discern a homogenous or developing "European cycle" with these data. Put loosely, globalization may be proceeding as fast as Europeanization.

166 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that the difference between the decision-making procedures "market" and "hierarchy" affects individual wellbeing beyond outcomes, and they take self-employment as an important case of independence, and show that the self-employed derive higher satisfaction from work than those employed in organizations.
Abstract: One can be independent, or one can be subject to decisions made by others. This paper argues that this difference, embodied in the institutional distinction between the decision-making procedures ‘market’ and ‘hierarchy’, affects individual wellbeing beyond outcomes. Taking self-employment as an important case of independence, it is shown that the self-employed derive higher satisfaction from work than those employed in organizations, irrespective of income gained or hours worked. This is evidence for procedural utility: people value not only outcomes, but also the processes leading to outcomes.

698 citations

Posted Content

637 citations


"A Simple and Flexible Alternative t..." refers background in this paper

  • ...The literature on the optimal trade-off between credibility and flexibility suggests that ex-post deviations of actual policies from announced targets should be made “costly” (Lohmann 1992)....

    [...]

  • ...announced targets should be made “costly” ( Lohmann 1992 )....

    [...]

01 Jan 1990

630 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors evaluate alternative rules by which the Fed may set interest rates using the small model of the U.S. economy estimated in Rotemberg and Woodford (1997).
Abstract: This paper evaluates alternative rules by which the Fed may set interest rates using the small model of the U.S. economy estimated in Rotemberg and Woodford (1997). Our main substantive finding is that low and stable inflation together with stable interest rates can be achieved by letting the funds rate respond positively to inflation while also responding, with a coefficient bigger than one, to the lagged funds rate itself. A rule in which the interest rate is set in this extremely simple way does almost as well as a more complicated rule which is optimal in our setting, in the sense of maximizing expected utility to the representative household. Furthermore, when the funds rate responds to inflation only with a delay, due to delay in the availability of inflation data, performance under the rule is only slightly reduced.

606 citations

ReportDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors propose to delegate monetary policy to a discretionary instrument-independent central bank with an optimal inflation target, which can eliminate the discretionary inflation bias, mimic the optimal linear inflation contract suggested by Walsh and extended by Persson and Tabellini, and achieve the equilibrium corresponding to an optimal rule with commitment.
Abstract: Inflation target regimes (like those if New Zealand, Canada, U.K., Sweden and Finland) are interpreted as having explicit inflation targets and implicit output/unemployment targets. Without output/unemployment persistence, delegation of monetary policy to a discretionary instrument-independent central bank with an optimal inflation target can eliminate the discretionary inflation bias, mimic the optimal linear inflation contract suggested by Walsh and extended by Persson and Tabellini, and achieve the equilibrium corresponding to an optimal rule with commitment. Thus an 'inflation target-conservative' central bank with an inflation target equal to the socially best inflation rate less any inflation bias dominates a Rogoff 'weight-conservative' central bank with increased weight on inflation stabilization, which suboptimally increases output/unemployment variability. With output/unemployment presistence, a constant inflation target is equivalent to a constant linear inflation contract. They can both eliminate the average inflation bias but not the state-contingent part of the inflation bias. Inflation variability is too high, and output variability too low, compared to the equilibrium corresponding to an optimal rule. An optimal state-contingent inflation target can remove all inflation bias, but in contrast to an optimal-state-contingent llinear inflation contract it still leaves inflation variability too high. Delegation with an optimal state-contingent inflation target to a Rogoff 'weight-conservative' central bank can then achieve the equilibrium corresponding to an optimal rule. Inflation targets mau on average be exceeded, and they may have imperfect credibility. Nevertheless they may usefully reduce inflation, and they appear much easier to implement than linear inflation contracts.

559 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (2)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "A simple and flexible alternative to the stability and growth pact deficit ceilings. is it at hand?" ?

The authors use a simple theoretical model of a monetary union where myopic discretionary fiscal policies generate excessive debt accumulation in steady state and inefficiently delayed debt adjustment following a shock. By setting a long-term debt target and by raising the political cost associated to deviations from the optimal pace of debt reversal following a shock ̧ institutional design induces the fiscal policymaker to implement unbiased discretionary responses to shocks. This is a completely revised version of CESifo Working Paper n. 1006. The authors wish to thank for very useful comments Enzo Dia and Jacques Melitz. 

21 Note that 0ˆ/1ˆ is a necessary condition for stability, and that the stability condition r 1ˆ can be reinterpreted as a ceiling to the proportion of adjustment shifted onto the future.