scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

A Study on Reliability Differentiated Pricing of Long-Term Transactions

01 Jan 2011-Journal of Electrical Engineering & Technology (The Korean Institute of Electrical Engineers)-Vol. 6, Iss: 1, pp 8-13
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examined the theoretical aspects of an RDP scheme, and derived the optimal decisions of consumers and electric utilities for long-term transactions through a case study on a wheeling service.
Abstract: Reliability differentiated pricing (RDP) is known to improve the efficiency and benefits of consumers and producers. Outage costs representing the economic and non-economic consequences of service curtailments to customers can be used as an effective parameter of RDP in electricity markets. This paper examines the theoretical aspects of an RDP scheme, and derives the optimal decisions of consumers and electric utilities for long-term transactions. The proposed RDP is demonstrated through a case study on a wheeling service.

Summary (2 min read)

1. Introduction

  • Electricity consumers are often given the choice of different levels of service reliability [1]-[3].
  • Moreover, real systems, in general, may not recover the sufficient revenue for the utility.
  • The pricing policy proposed in [5]-[8] could overcome most of the shortcomings entailed in both priority pricing and real-time pricing.
  • It could also differentiate the prices for varying levels of service reliability based on consumer outage costs.
  • One reason for this is the sudden shortage of supply.

2. Theory of Reliability Differentiated

  • A single welfare-maximizing public utility is assumed to own and operate the generating plants and the transmission network of a given electric power system, which is sold independently to customers.
  • It is also assumed that the utility could set and communicate the prices, as well as set a different price range for each customer class, at each moment instantaneously.
  • Supply outages occur randomly in relation to the probability of a possibly known outage.
  • Outages are assumed to be of short duration, such that customers who continue to access the utility service will not find it feasible or profitable to reschedule their production processes (i.e., change their electricity usage pattern) from the high production prices during outage duration.
  • It is assumed that the utility could ration the supply shortages among its targeted customer classes.

2.1 Consumer Behavior [5]

  • Customers are modeled as price-taking, profit-maximizing firms.
  • Consider a short-term rational customer whose benefit from electricity usage at any time depends on consumption at that time only.
  • Then, in real-time, when there is no supply shortage, the customer would choose iQ to maximize † Corresponding Author: Department of Electrical and Electronic Engeering, Hongik University, Korea. (bhkim@wow.hongik.ac.kr).
  • Fig. 1 shows the expected short-run customer demand curve DD, a very short-run customer demand curve D'E, and supply curve SS of electricity.
  • The outage cost function includes loss in customer benefit (the bold letters represent expected values).

2.2 Objective

  • All decision variables, with the exception of those involving reactive power, are nonnegative. .
  • For optimal operating and pricing strategies, the objective is to maximize the subject for the operating and network constraints inherent in the system.

3. Optimal Long-Term Prices

  • Section 2 deals with the short-run problem of a welfaremaximizing utility from which optimal short-term reliability-differentiated prices are derived from.
  • This section examines the long-run social welfare maximization problem of the utility developed from the previous section.
  • Based on these, the authors derive the differentiated prices of long-term reliability, which considers cost of capital or other fixed costs of production.
  • Long-term transactions, such as firm capacity purchased from or by the utility, or purchased from individual generators in the case of a network utility, the access to transmission services and wheeling transactions would require the provision of long-term prices in order for the participants to enter into contracts and to accommodate optimal investment decisions.
  • The customer sets the expected net marginal benefit from the electricity consumption equal to the expected price of electricity.

OC PC ECq

  • Thus, by employing socially optimal investment decision-making, long-term prices of real and reactive power could coincide with short-term reliability-differentiated prices.
  • Another difficulty is the unavailability of proper demand models that could capture the interdependence of intertemporal demands.
  • In principle, one should utilize benefit functions that depend on the entire time stream of demand rather than a single point in time.

4.1 Implications for Pricing Firm Capacity

  • Firm capacity refers to the generation of capacity that is purchased by the utility from neighboring utilities, namely, independent power producers (IPP) and cogenerators, in order to provide customers with long-run higher levels of service reliability.
  • The price paid for firm capacity should equal the value or marginal benefit that the customers derive from the added capacity.
  • Purchasing firm capacity is a long-term contract forged to protect against the loss of customer load due to unplanned outage of generating units.
  • Thus, in order to determine the optimal price of firm capacity purchases, the long-run problem of welfare-maximizing utility given in Equations (9)–(10) must be considered.
  • Again, this problem could be solved when obtaining the optimal values of all variab1es as functions of the parameters of the problem, in particular, piK and q iK (sensitivity theorem).

4.2 Numerical Example: Calculation of Long-Term Rates

  • Consider the simple four-bus system in Fig. 2.
  • In the model, there are two generating units (G2 and G4) and one transmission line (T3) with non-zero forced outage rates.
  • Thus, at each instance over time, there are eight possible system configurations or states that the system can utilize.
  • Hence, under RDP, the total expected revenue from sales to customers is exactly equal to the sum total of all expected costs/payments for the system (i.e., TR = TC).

5. Conclusion and Future Study

  • Outage costs play an essential role in electricity pricing and in the planning of electrical power systems.
  • The central role of outage costs in the optimal investment planning of the power system from a societal point of view, particularly for setting economic reliability standards in the generation, transmission, and distribution planning, has been emphasized by many studies.
  • Unbundling the services by offering consumers options on trade offs for service reliability, quality, and price can potentially increase the economic efficiency of the entire system, producing benefits for both the utility and the customers.
  • The authors propose RDP in examining the proposed pricing scheme of long-term transaction, putting emphasis on the long-term contract of firm capacity.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Journal of Electrical Engineering & Technology Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 8~13, 2011
DOI:
10.5370/JEET.2011.6.1.008
8
A Study on Reliability Differentiated Pricing of
Long-Term Transactions
Balho H. Kim
Abstract – Reliability differentiated pricing (RDP) is known to improve the efficiency and benefits of
consumers and producers. Outage costs representing the economic and non-economic consequences of
service curtailments to customers can be used as an effective parameter of RDP in electricity markets.
This paper examines the theoretical aspects of an RDP scheme, and derives the optimal decisions of
consumers and electric utilities for long-term transactions. The proposed RDP is demonstrated through
a case study on a wheeling service.
Keywords: Reliability Differentiated Pricing (RDP), Outage Costs, Optimal Pricing
1. Introduction
Electricity consumers are often given the choice of dif-
ferent levels of service reliability [1]-[3]. Typically, cus-
tomers would opt for the level of reliability that best suits
their needs and processes. Such a choice is argued to “un-
bundle” the service, resulting in improved efficiency and
benefits to both consumers and producers. However, thus
far, these available priority pricing schemes have led to
economic inefficiencies; they even fall short in attaining
welfare maximization of the utility [4].
Real-time pricing or spot market pricing schemes have
failed to consider long-run costs entailed in electricity pro-
duction, such as capital costs of the added capacity. More-
over, real systems, in general, may not recover the suffi-
cient revenue for the utility. Thus far, the suggested
schemes to recover the required revenue, such as in the
Ramsey-type pricing schemes applied to real-time pricing,
result in welfare loss.
The pricing policy proposed in [5]-[8] could overcome
most of the shortcomings entailed in both priority pricing
and real-time pricing. In addition, under certain assump-
tions, the proposed pricing policy could recover revenues
without any welfare loss. It could also differentiate the
prices for varying levels of service reliability based on con-
sumer outage costs.
In the analysis that follows, outages are assumed to oc-
cur without prior notification and that they occur in “short”
duration. Outage costs are defined as costs incurred by
customers due to sudden shortage in power supply; this is
over and above the loss in relation to consumer benefits
due to the said shortage. One reason for this is the sudden
shortage of supply. Losses occur due to interruption of pro-
duction processes, which could have been avoided if re-
scheduling is carried out. Rescheduling could only be ac-
complished if prior notice of the outage is conducted.
2. Theory of Reliability Differentiated
Pricing (RDP) [4]-[7]
A single welfare-maximizing public utility is assumed to
own and operate the generating plants and the transmission
network of a given electric power system, which is sold
independently to customers. It is also assumed that the util-
ity could set and communicate the prices, as well as set a
different price range for each customer class, at each mo-
ment instantaneously. Supply outages occur randomly in
relation to the probability of a possibly known outage. In
effect, customers only learn of an outage after it occurs.
Outages are assumed to be of short duration, such that cus-
tomers who continue to access the utility service will not
find it feasible or profitable to reschedule their production
processes (i.e., change their electricity usage pattern) from
the high production prices during outage duration. It is
assumed that the utility could ration the supply shortages
among its targeted customer classes.
2.1 Consumer Behavior [5]
Individual customers act independently. Customers are
modeled as price-taking, profit-maximizing firms. Assume
that all customers, can be classified into a finite number of
classes,
iI
at I = {1,...,N}, then each class consisting
of customers would have the same outage cost at a particu-
lar location. Total time T consists of short discrete time
intervals
tT
. Customer i’s electricity demand at time t
is denoted by
it
Q
.
Consider a short-term rational customer whose benefit
from electricity usage at any time depends on consumption
at that time only. Hence, the customer maximizes consumer
surplus at each
t
independently. At any time
t
, let
i
F
be the value-added or benefit function for customer i’s use
of electricity
i
Q
. Then, in real-time, when there is no sup-
ply shortage, the customer would choose
i
Q
to maximize
Corresponding Author: Department of Electrical and Electronic
Engeering, Hongik University, Korea. (bhkim@wow.hongik.ac.kr)
Received: February 5, 2010; Accepted: April 5, 2010

Balho H. Kim
9
profit
.
()
ii ii
F
QPQMax

(1)
i
i
i
dF
P
dQ

(2)
where
i
P
is the price of electricity.
Fig. 1 shows the expected short-run customer demand
curve DD, a very short-run customer demand curve D'E,
and supply curve SS of electricity.
e
i
Q
is the equilibrium
demand of customer
i at time
t
for the published ex-
pected price
e
i
P
. When supp1y is cut back to
0
i
Q
, the area
D’FE would represent the outage cost for the customer.
The area under the short-run demand curve DD gives the
loss in customer benefit.
0
i
P
is the price that the customer
is willing to pay in the very short-run period for the contin-
ued supp1y of e1ectricity. The very short-run demand
curve is initially very steep (vertical), as it represents the
price the customer (end use) is willing to pay to avoid any
service interruption.
Consider the scenario wherein a shortage of supply oc-
curs. In real-time, the customer would choose
i
Q
to
maximize profits:
() ()
e
i
i
Q
ii ii ii
Q
M
ax F Q MOC Q PQ

(3)
=>
i
ii
i
dF
M
OC P
dQ

(4)
where
i
M
OC
is the marginal outage cost of customer i
as a function of usage
i
Q
. At
0
ii
QQ
,
i
M
OC
is equal
to D’F (Fig. 1). The benefit that the customer obtains for
electricity usage
0
i
Q
is highlighted in case of supply
shortage; this is not the area under the very short-run demand
Fig. 1. Customer Demand and the Supply Curves of Elec-
tricity.
curve integrated from 0 to
0
i
Q
. In contrast, the customer
acts along with the very short-run demand curve to mini-
mize losses caused by the shortage. If the duration of the
outage is sufficiently long, or if the outage and subsequent
rise in price are known to the customer in advance, then the
customer would adjust in electricity consumption and set
0
i
i
i
dF
dQ
(i.e., to remain on demand curve DD). However,
the customer could not plan and/or adjust to the outage
condition during unexpected outages of short duration; thus,
the surplus of the consumer for customer
i
is expressed
by Equation (3).
Consider the case of a long-term rational customer
i
benefitting at time
t
.
it
F
depends not only on the electricity
usage of customer
i
at a certain time, but also on the usage
of customer
i
at other times, and possibly, on the usage
by other customers (end uses); that is,
()
it it
FFQ
where
{,}
it
QQiItT

. Assuming that the customer
seeks to maximize the total expected surplus of consumers
(i.e.,
{() }
it
t
E
FQ Costs
) for time T, where E is the
expectation operator. Thus, the customer would choose
it
Q
to maximize the expected profit,

() ()
it it it
t
M
ax E F Q OC Q P Q

(5)
it it
TT
it
it it
FOC
P
QQ





(6)
where
it
P
is the expected price of electricity. The outage
cost function includes loss in customer benefit (the bold
letters represent expected values). Thus, the customer
would equate the expected net marginal benefit to the ex-
pected price of electricity.
In the analysis that follows, the value-added function of
the customer is extended to include both real and reactive
power demands at the fundamental frequency of 60 Hz:
((), ())
dd
it
it i i i i
F
FP p Qq
(7)
where
d
i
P
: vector of real power demands of customer
i
,
d
i
Q
: vector of reactive power demands of customer
i
,
i
p
: vector of prices of real power for customer
i
, and
i
q
: vector of prices of reactive power for customer
i
.

A Study on Reliability Differentiated Pricing of Long-Term Transactions
10
2.2 Objective
The objective of the short-run operating and optimal
pricing problem in a welfare-maximizing utility using the
criterion of consumers plus producers surplus can be stated
as
(, ) (,)
dd uu
it i i it i i
ti i
WE FPQ OCPQMax


(, ) (,)
gg ss
it it it it it it
ii
PC P Q EC P Q


(8)
where
[]E
: expected value of the argument,
(, )
dd
it i i
F
PQ
: short-run va1ue-added function of customer
i
,
d
i
P
: real power demand of customer
i
,
d
i
Q
: reactive power demand of customer
i
,
u
i
P
: outage of real power for customer
i
,
u
i
Q
: outage of reactive power for customer
i
,
g
i
P
: generation of real power by generator
i
,
g
i
Q
: generation of reactive power by generator
i
,
s
i
P
: emergency purchase of real power at bus
i
,
s
i
Q
: emergency purchase of reactive power at bus
i
,
(, )
uu
it i i
OC P Q
: outage cost function of customer
i
,
(, )
g
g
it it it
P
CPQ
: cost of producing real and reactive power at
bus
i
, and
(, )
s
s
it it it
EC P Q
: cost of purchasing real and reactive power
at bus
i
.
All decision variables, with the exception of those in-
volving reactive power, are nonnegative. . The objective
function is assumed as a differentiable with a continuous
first derivative. For optimal operating and pricing strate-
gies, the objective is to maximize the subject for the oper-
ating and network constraints inherent in the system.
3. Optimal Long-Term Prices
Section 2 deals with the short-run problem of a welfare-
maximizing utility from which optimal short-term reliabil-
ity-differentiated prices are derived from. This section ex-
amines the long-run social welfare maximization problem
of the utility developed from the previous section. Based
on these, we derive the differentiated prices of long-term
reliability, which considers cost of capital or other fixed
costs of production. Long-term transactions, such as firm
capacity purchased from or by the utility, or purchased
from individual generators in the case of a network utility,
the access to transmission services and wheeling transac-
tions would require the provision of long-term prices in
order for the participants to enter into contracts and to ac-
commodate optimal investment decisions.
Consider the long-run resource planning problem of a
welfare-maximizing utility. To obtain the given values of
customer demands, the welfare-maximizing utility must
first solve the following problem of minimizing long-run
expected societal costs in order to determine the optimal
resource plan,
{(,) (,) (,)
dd uu gg
it i i it i i it it it
ti i i
M
axW E FPQ OCPQ PCPQ


(, )} ( , )
s
spq
it it it i i i
ii
E
CPQ CCK K


(9)
max
(,) ( )
pq
ii i K
k
ik
SC S S TC T
which is subject to the following constraints:
()0
gsud
it it it it it jt ij ij jt it
j
PPPP VVVCos

 
(10-1)
()0
gsud
it it it it it jt ij ij jt it
j
QQQQ VVVSin

 
(10-2)
0
gp
it i it
P
Ka
(10-3)
qgq
iit it iit
K
aQ Ka
(10-4)
max
ijt ij ijt
TTb
(10-5)
min max
iiti
VVV
(10-6)
(, , , ,,)0
ddggss
tt t t t t t
gP Q P Q PQ
(10-7)
0
s
p
it i
P
S
(10-8)
0
s
q
it i
QS
(10-9)
ng n n
iit it it
eP E A
(10-10)
ng n n
iit t t
i
eP E A
(10-11)
hhd
it i it
I dP
h=2,3,4,… (10-12)
hhh
it ij jt
j
VZI
h=2,3,4,… (10-13)
2
h
it
2
2
l
it
h
t
i
V
THD
NB V
(10-14)
maxt
THD D
(10-15)
0
u
it
P
(10-16)
0
u
it
Q
(10-17)
where
p
i
K
: real power generation capacity of generator i,
q
i
K
: reactive power generation capacity of generator i,
p
i
S
: real power spinning reserve capacity at bus i,

Balho H. Kim
11
q
i
S
: reactive power spinning reserve capacity at bus i,
and
max
k
T
: volt-ampere transmission capacity of line k
are the decision variables. In addition,
(,)
pq
ii i
CC K K
: capital cost of capacity for generator i,
(,)
pq
ii i
SC S S
: purchase price of spinning reserve at bus i,
and
max
()
kk
TC T
: capital cost of capacity for transmission line k.
This problem can be solved accordingly. By taking
d
it
P
and
d
it
Q
as the parameters of the problem, in order to ob-
tain the optimal values of all variables as the functions of
the parameters (i.e.,
d
it
P
and
d
it
Q
(sensitivity theorem), the
objective function can be written as
(,) (,) (,) (,)
dd dd dd dd
tt ttt ttt
it i i it
ti i
opt
F PQ OC P Q PCP Q ECP QW







(, ) (, ) (, )
dd dd dd
iik
iik
CCPQ SCPQ TCPQ

(11)
where
;,
dd
it
PPiItT
,
;,
dd
it
QQiItT
.
The customer sets the expected net marginal benefit
from the electricity consumption equal to the expected
price of electricity. Then, the respective optimal long-term
prices for real and reactive power inducing customers to
behave in a social welfare-maximizing manner are given
by:
L
it t t
jt
ddd
ij
j
tjtjt
OC PC EC
P
PPP



(12)
L
it t t
jt
ddd
ij
j
tjtjt
OC PC EC
q
QQQ



(13)
Thus, by employing socially optimal investment deci-
sion-making, long-term prices of real and reactive power
could coincide with short-term reliability-differentiated
prices. However, optimal investments require the evalua-
tion of future uncertainty, which is often difficult to carry
out. Another difficulty is the unavailability of proper de-
mand models that could capture the interdependence of
intertemporal demands. In principle, one should utilize
benefit functions that depend on the entire time stream of
demand rather than a single point in time.
4. Case Study
4.1 Implications for Pricing Firm Capacity
Firm capacity refers to the generation of capacity that is
purchased by the utility from neighboring utilities, namely,
independent power producers (IPP) and cogenerators, in
order to provide customers with long-run higher levels of
service reliability. The price paid for firm capacity should
equal the value or marginal benefit that the customers de-
rive from the added capacity. Purchasing firm capacity is a
long-term contract forged to protect against the loss of cus-
tomer load due to unplanned outage of generating units.
Thus, in order to determine the optimal price of firm capac-
ity purchases, the long-run problem of welfare-maximizing
utility given in Equations (9)–(10) must be considered.
Again, this problem could be solved when obtaining the
optimal values of all variab1es as functions of the parame-
ters of the problem, in particular,
p
i
K
and
q
i
K
(sensitivity
theorem).
The shadow price of added capacity (i.e., the Lagrange
multiplier of the capacity constraint) represents the will-
ingness of customers to pay for the obtained added capacity.
Based on Equations (12) and (13), the respective optimal
firm capacity purchase prices at bus j for real and reactive
power capacity are expressed by
P
ittt
j
PPP
tT i
jjj
OC PC EC
KKK





(14)
q
ittt
j
qqq
tT i
jjj
OC PC EC
KKK





(15)
4.2 Numerical Example: Calculation of Long-Term
Rates
Consider the simple four-bus system in Fig. 2. In the
figure, Gi and Li represent generating unit and load at Bus
i
, while Ti represents transmission line
i
. The character-
istics of the system are as follows:
G1: Rating = 200 MW, FOR= 0.00, Generation cost =
$30/MWH
G2: Rating = 250 MW, FOR= 0.10, Generation cost =
$0/MWH
G3: Rating = 110 MW, FOR = 0.00, Generation cost =
$40/MWH
G4: Rating = 250 MW, FOR = 0.20, Generation cost =
$20/MWH
L1: Customer load = 180 MW, Outage cost = $600/
MWH
L2: Customer load = 150 MW, Outage cost = $200/
MWH
L3: Customer load = 100 MW, Outage cost = $600/
MWH
L4: Customer load = 200 MW, Outage cost = $400/
MWH
T1: Rating = 100 MW, FOR = 0.00
T2: Rating = 120 MW, FOR = 0.00
T3: Rating = 80 MW, FOR = 0.30
T4: Rating = 80 MW, FOR = 0.00

A Study on Reliability Differentiated Pricing of Long-Term Transactions
12
Fig. 2. Four-Bus Power System for Sample Rate Calcula-
tions.
In the model, there are two generating units (G2 and G4)
and one transmission line (T3) with non-zero forced outage
rates. Thus, at each instance over time, there are eight pos-
sible system configurations or states that the system can
utilize. The load at each bus is assumed consisting of 1
MW of individual customer load for those that belong to
the same class (i.e., classes that have the same outage cost.)
Assuming that the system is operated optimally by a sin-
gle welfare-maximizing utility, then the expected reliabil-
ity-differentiated price for customers of class j is given by
i
j
ij
jj
OC
P
C
P
L
L


Thus, the expected prices for the customer classes of the
system are
1
P
= $72.96/MWH,
2
P
= $52.45/MWH
3
P
= $72.96/MWH,
4
P
= $87.72/MWH
The probability of service interruption (POSI) for cus-
tomers of each class, which measures the level of reliabil-
ity in which each customer class is served, are
POSI
1
= 0.0000, POSI
2
= 0.0825,
POSI
3
= 0.0000, POSI
4
= 0.0746.
The total expected cost of unserved energy for this linear
system is
$8, 444.00
i
ii
ii
i
OC
OC MOC PU
L


where
i
M
OC
is the marginal outage cost of customer
i
(e.g.,
2
M
OC
= $200/MWH).
The total expected revenue from the sale of electric
power is
$45,848.80
ii
i
TR PL
The total expected cost of generation is
$9,612.00
ii
i
PC MPC PG
where
i
M
PC
is the marginal production cost of generator
i
(e.g.,
1
M
PC
= $30/MWH).
The price of capacity purchase from generator
i
is
given by
j
i
j
ii
OC
P
C
K
K


Thus, the prices of capacity purchase from the genera-
tors of the system are
1
= $42.96/MW,
2
= $48.96/MW
3
= $40.16/MW,
4
= $21.60/MW.
The total payment to the generators for capacity pur-
chase is
$30,649.60
ii
i
CP K

The price of capacity purchase from transmission line k
is given by
max max
j
k
j
kk
OC
P
C
TT


Thus, the prices of capacity purchase from the transmis-
sion lines are
1
= $0.00/MW,
2
= $0.00/MW
3
= $25.20/MW,
4
= $44.64/MW
The total payment to the transmission lines for capacity
purchase is
max
$5,587.20
kk
k
TP T

The sum total of all expected costs/payments for the sys-
tem is
TC = PC + CP + TP =$45,848.80

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the role played by demand uncertainty in determining the optimal electricity rate structure and capacity planning is discussed, with the exception of Tschirhart and Jen and Marchand, which do not directly address the question of service reliability from the customer's perspective.
Abstract: Recent research on electricity pricing extends the traditional peak load pricing problem in many directions. Some notable studies include the time-of-use (TOU) papers by Crew and Kleindorfer (1976, 1978); the cycling analysis by Dansby (1977); the Demand Subscription Service (DSS) studies by Tschirhart and Jen (1979), Panzar and Sibley (1978), and Marchand (1974). Central to these papers is the role played by demand uncertainty in determining the optimal electricity rate structure and capacity planning. With the exception of Tschirhart and Jen and Marchand, these papers do not directly address the question of service reliability from the customer's perspective. Moreover, the supply-side uncertainty caused by random plant outages (as indicated by Chao, 1983) is largely ignored. Finally, these studies, though elegant and innovative, do not analyze the problem of residential rate options, which recently have gained considerable popularity in the United States, especially in California.

17 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A novel sustain driver employing an energy recovery faculty is proposed for efficient driving of a plasma display panel (PDP) in the sustaining mode operation using dual resonance.
Abstract: A novel sustain driver employing an energy recovery faculty is proposed for efficient driving of a plasma display panel (PDP) in the sustaining mode operation. The proposed driver uses dual resonance. One is a main resonance between an inductor and an external capacitor to produce alternative pulses and the other is a subresonance between an inductor and a panel to recover the energy consumption by the capacitive displacement current of the PDP. The operational principle and design procedure of the proposed circuit are presented with theoretical analysis. The validity of the proposed sustain driver is verified through the simulated and experimental results based on a 7.5-in diagonal panel with 200-kHz operating frequency.

15 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The importance of an optimal pricing policy for pricing non-utility generated power is pointed out in this article, which leads to benefits for all concerned: the utility, industry and the utility's other customers.
Abstract: The importance of an optimal pricing policy for pricing nonutility generated power is pointed out in this paper. An optimal pricing policy leads to benefits for all concerned: the utility, industry, and the utility's other customers. In this paper, it is shown that reliability differentiated real-time pricing provides an optimal nonutility generated power pricing policy, from a societal welfare point of view. Firm capacity purchase, and hence an optimal price for purchasing firm capacity, are an integral part of this pricing policy. A case study shows that real-time pricing without firm capacity purchase results in improper investment decisions and higher costs for the system as a whole. Without explicit firm capacity purchase, the utility makes greater investment in capacity addition in order to meet its reliability criteria than is socially optimal. It is concluded that the nonutility generated power pricing policy presented in this paper and implied by reliability differentiated pricing policy results in social welfare-maximizing investment and operation decisions. >

15 citations


"A Study on Reliability Differentiat..." refers background in this paper

  • ...The pricing policy proposed in [5]-[8] could overcome most of the shortcomings entailed in both priority pricing and real-time pricing....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors proposed a method to calculate magnetostrictive forces, displacement, and vibration modes of a large-scale brushless DC motor by using a magneto-mechanically strong coupling formulation.
Abstract: This paper proposes a method to calculate magnetostrictive forces, displacement, and vibration modes of a large-scale Brushless DC(BLDC) motor by using a magneto-mechanically strong coupling formulation. The force is calculated using the energy method with magnetostrictive stress tensor. The mechanical vibration modes are also analyzed by using the principle of Hamilton and the calculated magneto-elastic forces acting on the surfaces of the stator. To verify the algorithm, 3 MW BLDC motor is simulated, and the forces, displacements, and vibration modes are calculated. The result shows that the mechanically stressed core has more deformation or displacements than those of the normal condition.

14 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A new series resonant sustainer is presented to reduce the cost and power consumption of PDP TV, which employs address-and-display-period-separated (ADS) driving method.
Abstract: A new series resonant sustainer is presented to reduce the cost and power consumption of PDP TV, which employs address-and-display-period-separated (ADS) driving method. The proposed sustain driver can reduce the number of components compared with the prior approaches. It also improves the energy recovery efficiency about 3%. The operational principle and its features are illustrated and compared with the conventional approaches. The high-performance of the proposed sustain driver is verified by computer-aided simulations and experiments using a prototype equipped with a 7.5-inch diagonal panel, which is operated at 200 kHz switching frequency.

10 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (2)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "A study on reliability differentiated pricing of long-term transactions" ?

This paper examines the theoretical aspects of an RDP scheme, and derives the optimal decisions of consumers and electric utilities for long-term transactions. The proposed RDP is demonstrated through a case study on a wheeling service. 

However, the implications of the proposed pricing scheme for the wheeling service and transmission service needs to be dealt with further by future studies.