scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

A Zero Attraction Effect in Naturalistic Choice

TL;DR: In the attraction effect, adding a dominated third option to a choice set of two options can reverse the preference for the original two options, and even increase one of the option's choice share as discussed by the authors.
Abstract: In the attraction effect, adding a dominated third option to a choice set of two options can reverse the preference for the original two options, and even increase one of the option’s choice share. This constitutes a violation of the axioms of regularity and independence from irrelevant alternatives, which are core properties of any choice model in which the utility of each option is stable across choice sets. Consequently, in the past 20 years, the attraction effect has driven the development of a set of influential models of multiattribute choice. However, Frederick, Lee, and Baskin (2014) have recently claimed that the attraction effect is only limited to options with numerical attributes, and does not hold for choices between naturalistic options (e.g., snacks, movies) — a claim which would severely undermine its theoretical importance. Huber, Payne, and Puto (2014) criticised Frederick et al.’s experiments, laying down a set of criteria that should be met by any experiment wishing to test for the attraction effect in real-world consumer choices. This article presents the first experiment that meets these criteria. The results show a precisely zero attraction effect.

Summary (3 min read)

Introduction

  • This can constitute a violation of the axioms of regularity and independence from irrelevant alternatives, which are core properties of any choice model in which the utility of each option is stable across choice sets.
  • In the past 20 years, the attraction effect has driven the development of a set of influential models of multiattribute choice.
  • Two studies (Frederick et al., 2014; Yang & Lynn, 2014) involving a series of experiments with naturalistic choice options (e.g., snacks, movies) found no evidence for the attraction effect in choice contexts where alternatives are represented without objectively defined (e.g., numerical) attribute dimensions—a finding that would severely undermine its theoretical importance.
  • The results show a precisely zero attraction effect.

The Attraction Effect

  • Imagine that you are having a nice meal in a restaurant, and you are looking at the two dessert options available on the menu: cheesecake and pecan pie.
  • The introduction of the apple pie to the choice set makes you more likely to choose the pecan pie over the cheesecake .
  • This article has been published under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/ licenses/by/3.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited.
  • Choice options that are represented along two attribute dimensions (perceptual or numerical) can be relatively easily manipulated within a choice experiment, but most real-world choices involve complex, naturalistic objects with a large number of underlying attributes that often cannot be represented in a stylized format.
  • The authors describe a rigorous test of the attraction effect with complex, naturalistic choice options, using a carefully developed experimental methodology that addresses all of the critical conditions discussed by Huber et al. (2014).

Testing the Attraction Effect With Real-World Stimuli

  • The goal of this experiment was to test the attraction effect with naturalistic stimuli.
  • When the stimuli are represented with welldefined attribute dimensions, it is straightforward to construct choice triplets with a target, competitor, and decoy option.
  • First, such stimuli can have a high number of attribute dimensions that might vary across individuals.
  • They chose pairs of movies that are part of the same series or are starring the same actor to create target– decoy pairs.
  • Figure 1 shows an example of two choice triplets created from one such quadruplet of movies (in the experiment participants were presented with real movie posters).

Candidate Choice Set Selection

  • To determine the choice sets used in the experiment, the first step was to create a set of quadruplets, each consisting of two movies that are very similar (for the two target–decoy pairs; i.e., A–A,= B–B=), while making sure that the two pairs are sufficiently different from each other (for the target–competitor pair; i.e., A–B).
  • To obtain the set of 400 movies, the authors first retrieved 40 of the most popular movies from each of 10 distinct genre categories (romance, drama, sci-fi, thriller, comedy, horror, animation, fantasy, crime, action) from IMDb.
  • The authors selected a movie pair as target–decoy candidate if, for a given target candidate movie, the number of overlapping genres with a candidate decoy was equal to the maximum overlap seen for that target across all candidate decoy movies.
  • Participants to rate the similarity of a randomly chosen group of movie pairs, obtaining 10 independent similarity ratings for each of the 1,242 target– decoy candidates.
  • Therefore, the authors decided to pair up the least similar 253 target– decoy pairs (where similarity is captured by genre overlap) to create the quadruplets.

Experimental Procedures

  • The experiment consisted of three stages: rating stage, choice stage, and a similarity rating stage.
  • Before the choice stage, the authors created a bespoke set of movie triplets for each participant using their ratings from the rating stage.
  • First, based on each participant’s preference ratings, the authors identified the subset of quadruplets where (a) the target and competitor were both rated 4, both rated 5, both rated 6, or both rated 7 and (b) the two decoy movies were rated at least 3 points lower than the two target candidates.
  • The authors recruited 297 English-speaking participants from Prolific Academic who were paid €8 per hour.
  • Out of the 179 participants who were invited back, 152 took part in the choice stage of the experiment.

Exclusion Criteria

  • To conduct a rigorous test of the attraction effect, it is crucial that people take the task seriously and reveal their true preferences.
  • Given that individually rating 231 movies can seem somewhat mundane, the authors specified a set of exclusion criteria to filter those people out who did not take the rating task sufficiently seriously.
  • The authors excluded people who fell into the fastest 5% of the reaction time (RT) distribution, the lowest 5% of the entropy distribution, and the upper and lower 5% of the autocorrelation distribution.
  • Thus, this procedure filtered out response patterns where people (a) spent an unusually short time completing the task, (b) did not use the whole of the ratings scale, (c) often gave the same ratings for consecutive movies, or (d) were giving ratings randomly.
  • When testing for the attraction effect, the authors have also removed all trials where the decoy was chosen.

Results

  • The median number of choice trials per participant was 16 (range: 6–54), and 84% of participants were presented with at least 8 choice trials.
  • In addition, 72% of participants never chose the decoy, and only 2% chose it in more than 25% of the trials.
  • As Figure 6 shows, the overwhelming majority of target–competitor pairs were perceived as not similar, while the majority of target–decoy pairs were perceived as similar, exactly as the authors intended.
  • Using Model 1, the authors calculate that the overall probability of choosing the target is .50, 95% CI [.48, .52], the same as what they see in the mean over subject proportions from Figure 5.
  • None of the ratings modulate the strength of the attraction effect.

Further Analyses

  • During the peer-review process, the authors also completed the following exploratory analyses.
  • Faced with two subsequent choices involving two equally highly rated A–B movie pairs and two different but undesirable decoys, it is possible that the first choice is “sticky” and will be repeated.
  • When all of the covariates are included (Model 8), the authors still do not find evidence for the attraction effect, although the effect is less precisely estimated.
  • Overall, while the results indicate that overall genre preferences slightly influenced choices between the target and competitor, the authors found no evidence that this had any effect on the strength of the attraction effect.
  • While the authors have not found any evidence suggesting that the target– decoy rating difference influenced the strength of the attraction effect (see Model 2 in Table 1), a nonlinear association between target–decoy preference and the attraction effect might still exist.

General Discussion

  • The authors tested for the attraction effect in a choice task with naturalistic choice options.
  • The decoy was only chosen in 4.3% of the trials, which clearly shows that participants were able to spot and avoid the dominated option.
  • Finally, in their analysis, the authors controlled for familiarity with the choice options, perceived similarity of the target– decoy and target– competitor pair, and preference difference between the target and the decoy, but they found that none of these modulated or revealed an attraction effect.
  • Attribute information is spatially separate in a numerical matrix form presentation, but attribute information occurs in the same spatial location for movie thumbnails.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

A Zero Attraction Effect in Naturalistic Choice
Anna Trendl, Neil Stewart, and Timothy L. Mullett
Behavioural Science Group, Warwick Business School, University of Warwick
In the attraction effect, adding a dominated third option to a choice set of two options
can alter preferences for the original two options and increase the dominating option’s
choice share. This can constitute a violation of the axioms of regularity and indepen-
dence from irrelevant alternatives, which are core properties of any choice model in
which the utility of each option is stable across choice sets. In the past 20 years, the
attraction effect has driven the development of a set of influential models of multiat-
tribute choice. However, two studies (Frederick et al., 2014; Yang & Lynn, 2014)
involving a series of experiments with naturalistic choice options (e.g., snacks, movies)
found no evidence for the attraction effect in choice contexts where alternatives are
represented without objectively defined (e.g., numerical) attribute dimensions—a find-
ing that would severely undermine its theoretical importance. Huber et al. (2014)
criticized these studies, laying down a set of criteria that should be met by any
experiment wishing to test for the attraction effect in real-world consumer choices.
Based on these criteria, this article presents a carefully designed experiment testing the
attraction effect with movies as naturalistic choice options. The results show a precisely
zero attraction effect.
Keywords: attraction effect, context effects, consumer choice
The Attraction Effect
Imagine that you are having a nice meal in
a restaurant, and you are looking at the two
dessert options available on the menu:
cheesecake and pecan pie. You are torn be-
tween the creamy texture of the cheesecake
and the rich, nutty flavor of the pecan pie.
You resolve to have the cheesecake. As the
waiter approaches to take your order, he in-
forms you that a third dessert option, apple
pie—which you find quite bland—is also
available today. But now you have changed
your mind and decide to order the pecan pie.
Tsetsos et al. (2010) give just this hypotheti-
cal example: The availability of the third op-
tion, which you do not want, makes you
switch between the original two options.
This is an example of the attraction effect
(also known as asymmetric dominance effect).
The introduction of the apple pie (decoy) to the
choice set makes you more likely to choose the
pecan pie (target) over the cheesecake (compet-
itor). In essence, it states that when the decision
maker is indifferent between the target and the
competitor (pecan pie and cheesecake in the
example), the addition of an inferior decoy op-
tion that resembles the target (apple pie is sim-
ilar to pecan pie but is less liked by the decision
maker) increases the likelihood that the target
will be chosen.
Anna Trendl X https://orcid.org/0000-0003-1994-4207
Neil Stewart X
https://orcid.org/0000-0002-2202-018X
Timothy L. Mullett X https://orcid.org/0000-0002-4082-2813
This research was funded in part by Economic and Social
Research Council Grants ES/K002201/1, ES/P008976/1, and
ES/N018192/1 and Leverhulme Trust Grant RP2012-V-022.
This article has been published under the terms of the Creative
Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/
licenses/by/3.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribu-
tion, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original
author and source are credited. Copyright for this article is
retained by the author(s). Author(s) grant(s) the American
Psychological Association the exclusive right to publish the
article and identify itself as the original publisher.
Correspondence concerning this article should be addressed
to Anna Trendl, Behavioural Science Group, Warwick Busi-
ness School, University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL,
United Kingdom. Email: anna.trendl@wbs.ac.uk
Decision
© 2021 The Author(s) 2021, Vol. 8, No. 1, 55– 68
ISSN: 2325-9965 https://doi.org/10.1037/dec0000145
55

The attraction effect is important, because it
poses a challenge to all choice models that rely
on the assumption of simple scalability, which
holds when options in a choice set can be given
a scale value, and choice probability is repre-
sented as a monotone function of these scale
values (Trueblood et al., 2013). The attraction
effect also violates the property of indepen-
dence from irrelevant alternatives, which re-
quires that the relative choice probability of two
options should not be affected by adding new
options to the choice set (Pleskac, 2015). In
addition, the attraction effect can violate the
regularity condition, which states that an op-
tion’s choice probability cannot increase when
the choice set is extended (Luce, 1977; Tversky,
1972).
Due to its theoretical importance, the attrac-
tion effect has played a substantial role in the
evolution of multialternative, multiattribute
models of choice, with a significant number of
various theoretical accounts being developed
over the past 20 years (e.g., multialternative
decision field theory, Roe et al., 2001; leaky
competing accumulators, Usher & McClelland,
2004; multialternative attentional drift– diffu-
sion model, Krajbich et al., 2010; range-
normalization model, Soltani et al., 2012; asso-
ciative accumulation model, Bhatia, 2013;
multiattribute linear ballistic accumulator, True-
blood et al., 2014; multialternative decision by
sampling, Noguchi & Stewart, 2018).
The first multiattribute choice experiments
demonstrating the attraction effect (e.g., Huber
et al., 1982; Simonson & Tversky, 1992) almost
exclusively used stylized stimuli with objec-
tively defined attribute dimensions (e.g., cars
presented as numerical values for gas mileage
and ride quality). Trueblood et al. (2013) have
also found evidence for the attraction effect in a
perceptual choice experiment, where partici-
pants were asked to select the largest from three
rectangles with varying widths and heights.
However, recent research suggests that the
attraction effect might only occur under very
specific conditions. In particular, it had been
shown that the effect is much more likely to
manifest when an attribute-wise comparison
strategy is employed in the choice process, as
opposed to an alternative-wise strategy (Nogu-
chi & Stewart, 2014). In addition, the attraction
effect seems to be highly dependent on the exact
presentation format of the choice options (e.g.,
Cataldo & Cohen, 2019; Frederick et al., 2014;
Spektor et al., 2018). Since stimulus presenta-
tion format fundamentally affects the underly-
ing comparison strategy, a natural concern is
then whether this hugely influential decision
bias generalizes to real-world choice situations
with nonstylized alternatives (i.e., options that
cannot be represented with objectively defined
attribute dimensions).
Choice options that are represented along two
attribute dimensions (perceptual or numerical)
can be relatively easily manipulated within a
choice experiment, but most real-world choices
involve complex, naturalistic objects with a
large number of underlying attributes that often
cannot be represented in a stylized format.
These naturalistic options are represented in a
pictorial format without objectively defined at-
tributes.
Recent experiments in multiattribute choice
introduced what can perhaps be considered as
more ecologically valid stimuli (e.g., movies
presented as thumbnails and titles on Netflix or
photographs of popular snacks). Results from
these experiments indicate that significant dif-
ferences might exist in the processing of styl-
ized and nonstylized (naturalistic) stimuli. For
example, Bhatia and Stewart (2018) find that,
with naturalistic stimuli, the weighted additive
model on a high-dimensional semantic repre-
sentation generalizes to new choices better than
the simpler heuristic models that perform so
well on stimuli presented in a stylized format.
Recently, the existence of the attraction effect
in choices that involve naturalistic options has
become a contentious issue in the decision-
making literature. Based on 38 experiments,
Frederick et al. (2014) presented an extensive
investigation of the boundary conditions of the
attraction effect. These experiments included
choice options represented with numerical attri-
butes, as well as complex, real-world stimuli
(e.g., fruits, bottled water, apartments), and in
some of these experiments, participants could
even sample the choice options (e.g., Kool-Aid,
facial tissue, jelly beans). The overall conclu-
sion of this study was that while the presence of
the decoy seemed to affect choices when the
options were represented in a numerical format,
it was absent in experiments with more com-
plex, naturalistic stimuli. In light of these re-
sults, Frederick et al. posited that the psycho-
logical processes underlying decisions where
56 TRENDL, STEWART, AND MULLETT

options are represented with numerical attri-
butes are fundamentally different from those
employed in decisions where the stimuli have a
more naturalistic format. This conclusion was
also supported by Yang and Lynn (2014), who
demonstrated difficulties replicating the attrac-
tion effect in experiments where the stimuli had
qualitative-verbal or pictorial depictions, as op-
posed to cases where the attributes were pre-
sented numerically.
These two studies sparked considerable inter-
est among decision-making researchers and led
to the reexamination of the boundary conditions
of the attraction effect. While the results from
these studies are consistent in showing no evi-
dence for the attraction effect across a wide
variety of naturalistic choice options, the degree
to which the individual experiments presented
in these studies invoked an attraction effect–
type choice scenario, thus constituting a strin-
gent test of the attraction effect, has been sub-
sequently questioned.
In particular, Huber et al. (2014) discussed
five critical conditions that can inhibit the at-
traction effect and argued that many of these are
present in the experiments reported by Freder-
ick et al. (2014) and Yang and Lynn (2014). The
five critical conditions are to avoid (a) strong
prior preferences over the target and competitor,
(b) inability to identify the dominance relation-
ship between the target and the decoy, (c) het-
erogeneity in prior preferences over the target
and competitor, (d) an undesirable decoy, and
(e) a decoy that is too desirable. In addition,
Simonson (2014) further stressed the impor-
tance of detecting the dominance relationship in
observing the attraction effect.
Due to the theoretical significance of the at-
traction effect, it is important to know if the
attraction effect is confined to choice settings
with stimuli presented in an attribute-by-
alternative format. Arguably, while most con-
sumer choices in the real world involve stimuli
that are often presented in a rich naturalistic
form (Bhatia & Stewart, 2018), the develop-
ment of formal models of choice has been al-
most exclusively reliant on results from exper-
iments where the options are represented with
numerical attributes. Exploring how the
strength of the effect depends on the presenta-
tion format of the choice alternatives also pro-
vides us with invaluable information about the
cognitive process underlying the attraction ef-
fect.
In this article, we describe a rigorous test of
the attraction effect with complex, naturalistic
choice options, using a carefully developed ex-
perimental methodology that addresses all of
the critical conditions discussed by Huber et al.
(2014). Our results show a precisely zero attrac-
tion effect. Taken together with earlier results
from Frederick et al. (2014) and Yang and Lynn
(2014), we see this as strong evidence for the
claim that the attraction effect is limited to
choice tasks where options are represented in a
stylized format with objectively defined attri-
butes.
Testing the Attraction Effect With
Real-World Stimuli
The goal of this experiment was to test the
attraction effect with naturalistic stimuli. We
chose to use the most popular movies on IMDb
as stimuli. Choosing between movies is a real-
istic, everyday task. In addition, the movie
space is rich, and thus it allows us to create a
wide range of unique choice triplets to test the
attraction effect.
When the stimuli are represented with well-
defined attribute dimensions, it is straightfor-
ward to construct choice triplets with a target,
competitor, and decoy option. However, with
naturalistic stimuli, this task is significantly
more complicated. First, such stimuli can have a
high number of attribute dimensions that might
vary across individuals. In addition, it is entirely
possible that preferences are not monotonic
over these attribute dimensions (while this
could also be the case for alternative-by-
attribute representations, these dimensions are
usually constructed to ensure monotonic prefer-
ences, e.g., probability of winning, amount to
win).
Frederick et al. (2014) have also used movie
stimuli in two of their experiments: They chose
pairs of movies that are part of the same series
or are starring the same actor to create target–
decoy pairs. In these experiments, the role of
each of the three movies (target, competitor,
decoy) was always the same for all participants
and based upon average population-level rat-
ings rather than individual ratings.
Our novel experimental design takes individ-
ual preferences into account when creating tar-
57ZERO ATTRACTION EFFECT IN NATURALISTIC CHOICE

get– competitor– decoy triplets and ensures that
decision makers are indifferent between the tar-
get and competitor and are able to clearly iden-
tify the lowest-rated option in the choice set. To
increase the statistical power of our experiment,
we used a within-subjects design. We presented
participants with both A, B, A= and B, A, B=
triplet pairs (where X= is the dominated option).
Two triplet pairs were created from “quadru-
plets” of movies, using two distinctly different
target– decoy pairs. Figure 1 shows an example
of two choice triplets created from one such
quadruplet of movies (in the experiment partic-
ipants were presented with real movie posters).
Method
Preregistration
The study design, exclusion criteria, and all
the analyses were planned and registered before
we collected any choice data. The preregistration
can be accessed here https://osf.io/fme6c/?view_
only31da4193689f4247a76af93b2f98fcef.
Candidate Choice Set Selection
To determine the choice sets used in the
experiment, the first step was to create a set of
quadruplets, each consisting of two movies that
are very similar (for the two target– decoy pairs;
i.e., A–A,= B–B=), while making sure that the
two pairs are sufficiently different from each
other (for the target–competitor pair; i.e., A–B).
The details of the construction of these qua-
druplets are somewhat arbitrary—a different
recipe could have been used. However, the main
point is that the choice triplets created from
these quadruplets pass Huber et al.’s (2014)
criteria, as we detail below. The main steps in
the quadruplet construction process we describe
in detail in the remainder of this section are
depicted in Figure 2.
To obtain the set of 400 movies, we first
retrieved 40 of the most popular movies from
each of 10 distinct genre categories (romance,
drama, sci-fi, thriller, comedy, horror, anima-
tion, fantasy, crime, action) from IMDb. The
popularity of each movie was defined by the
number of ratings it has received. We selected a
wide range of genres to obtain a sufficiently rich
stimuli space, as we wanted our participants to
have a variety of preferences over our stimuli.
We omitted any sequels.
Due to the multidimensional nature of the
stimuli, one of the main difficulties in creating
attraction effect choice triplets from real-world
Figure 1
Two Choice Triplets Used in the Experiment
Decoy
Decoy
Target Competitor
TargetCompetitor
Goodfellas
The
Godfather
The
Godfather
Knocked Up
Friends
with
Benefits
Friends
with
Benefits
Note. In the experiment, participants were presented with actual movie posters.
58 TRENDL, STEWART, AND MULLETT

objects is establishing a criterion for matching
up similar objects. We used genre and subgenre
information from the website allmovie.com to
create target– decoy pairs with many shared
genres that are likely to be perceived as similar,
and target– competitor pairs with no genre over-
lap that are likely to be perceived as different.
We conjectured that it will be harder to find
movie pairs that will be perceived as similar, be-
cause any given movie is similar to only a few
movies and dissimilar to all of the others. For this
reason, we started the quadruplet creation with
selecting potential target– decoy pairs.
The genre information on allmovie.com is
very rich: Compared to the 18 genre categories
on IMDb, there are 156 genre and subgenre
categories, capturing many important aspects of
the movies. Using this rich genre information,
we created a movie-by-movie (400 400) ma-
trix, where each cell was the number of over-
lapping genre categories between the two mov-
ies. We selected a movie pair as target– decoy
candidate if, for a given target candidate movie,
the number of overlapping genres with a candi-
date decoy was equal to the maximum overlap
seen for that target across all candidate decoy
movies. This resulted in 2,271 target– decoy
candidate movie pairs overall. We also added
806 movie pairs obtained from the mutually
closest 10% of movies based on a latent seman-
tic analysis
1
that were not already in our list of
target– decoy candidates. The rationale behind
using semantic proximity as an additional crite-
rion was to capture movie pairs that are very
close to each other in terms of the story themes
but are not the closest on the genre dimension.
Overall, we had 3,011 unique target–decoy can-
didate pairs at this point.
We then reduced the size of this list by se-
lecting the most similar movie pairs. This was
done manually by two researchers, who inde-
pendently judged the similarity of each movie
pair (not similar at all/similar). We then only
kept the movie pairs that were judged as similar
by both researchers, weeding out the movie
pairs that were obviously not similar, resulting
in 1,242 target– decoy candidates. We then di-
vided the 1,242 pairs into six groups of 207
pairs and ran a pilot study where we asked 60
1
The latent semantic analysis assesses the similarity of
two items based on the text associated with them. For this
analysis, we used the summary text about the movies as well
as plot keywords, actor names, and director names, all
retrieved from IMDb.
Figure 2
Summary of the Quadruplet Construction Process
59ZERO ATTRACTION EFFECT IN NATURALISTIC CHOICE

Citations
More filters
Book ChapterDOI
01 Apr 2010

34 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: The authors showed that the decoy effect is a transitory phenomenon that emerges only in the early stages of the choice process to later disappear, and that participants are fast then slow to choose the dominant option to avoid the dominated decoy and then progressively revise their choices until choice shares come to correspond to price differences only.
Abstract: In this paper we provide choice-process experimental evidence that the attraction effect is a short-term phenomenon, that disappears when individuals are given time and incentives to revise their choices.The attraction (or decoy) effect is the most prominent example of context effects, and it appears when adding a dominated option to a choice set increases the choice share of the now dominant option at the expense of other options. While widely replicated, the attraction effect is usually tested in hypothetical or payoff-irrelevant situations and without following the choice process. We run a laboratory experiment where we incentivize choice, vary the difference in utility between options and track which option participants consider best over time. We find that the effect is a transitory phenomenon that emerges only in the early stages of the choice process to later disappear. Participants are fast then slow: they first choose the dominant option to avoid the dominated decoy and then progressively revise their choices until choice shares come to correspond to price differences only. We expand our analysis by considering differences in utility among options and differences in the presentation of options (numerical or graphical). We also consider differences in the choice processes followed by individuals (intuitive vs. deliberative). This allows us to ascribe more precisely the role of fast and slow cognitive process in the emergence and disappearance of the attraction effect.

7 citations


Cites background from "A Zero Attraction Effect in Natural..."

  • ...The AE also failed to replicate in a recent large experiment with real-world consumer choices (Trendl et al., 2018) that complied with all the conditions laid down by the original authors to allow successful replication (Huber et al., 2014)....

    [...]

  • ...The AE also failed to replicate in a recent large experiment with real-world consumer choices (Trendl et al., 2018) that complied with all the conditions laid down by the original authors to allow successful replication (Huber et al....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: The authors found strong evidence for status quo bias and no evidence for the decoy effect in a between-subjects lab experiment that featured a single decision over two or three money lotteries.
Abstract: Inertia and context-dependent choice effects are well-studied classes of behavioural phenomena. While much is known about these effects in isolation, little is known about whether one of them "dominates" the other when both can potentially be present. Knowledge of any such dominance is relevant for effective choice architecture and descriptive modelling. We initiate this empirical investigation with a between-subjects lab experiment that featured a single decision over two or three money lotteries. Our experiment was designed to test for dominance between *status quo bias* and the *decoy effect*. We find strong evidence for status quo bias and no evidence for the decoy effect. We also find that status quo bias is powerful enough so that, at the aggregate level, a fraction of subjects switch from being risk-averse to being risk-seeking. Survey evidence suggests that this is due to subjects focusing on the maximum possible amount when the risky lottery is the default and on the probability of winning more than the smallest amount when there is no default lottery. The observed reversal in risk attitudes is explainable by a large class of reference-dependent preferences.

2 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
03 May 2020
TL;DR: The decoy effect refers to the phenomenon whereby an inferior, unpreferable option reverses people's preferences and increases the choice share of a targeted option as discussed by the authors, which is called decoy bias.
Abstract: The decoy effect refers to the phenomenon whereby an inferior, unpreferable option reverses people’s preferences and increases the choice share of a targeted option. In two pre-registered experimen...

2 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors found that offering an inferior and rarely chosen third (decoy) option to decision makers choosing between two options has a paradoxical effect: it increases the choice share of the option most similar to the decoy.
Abstract: Offering an inferior and rarely chosen third (decoy) option to decision makers choosing between two options has a paradoxical effect: It increases the choice share of the option most similar to the decoy. This attraction effect is robust when options are numeric but rarely occurs in humans when options are visual, even though it occurs in animals. Building on psychophysics, we examined two types of visual attributes: quantitative and qualitative. Quantitative visual attributes (e.g., different bottle volumes) can be perceived as magnitudes. Qualitative visual attributes (e.g., different colors), however, do not fall onto a magnitude scale. One can perceive that a bottle’s volume is twice that of another bottle but not that a green bottle’s color is twice that of a red bottle. We observed robust attraction effects for quantitative visual attributes (4,602 adults, 237 college-age participants), which reversed to repulsion effects when the visual attributes were qualitative (6,005 adults).

1 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

3,365 citations


"A Zero Attraction Effect in Natural..." refers background in this paper

  • ...In addition, the attraction effect can violate the regularity condition, which states that an option’s choice probability cannot increase when the choice set is extended (Luce, 1977; Tversky, 1972)....

    [...]

Book
01 Jan 1959

2,474 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A computational model of value-based binary choice in which fixations guide the comparison process and it is found that the model can quantitatively explain complex relationships between fixation patterns and choices, as well as several fixation-driven decision biases.
Abstract: Most organisms facing a choice between multiple stimuli will look repeatedly at them, presumably implementing a comparison process between the items' values. Little is known about the nature of the comparison process in value-based decision-making or about the role of visual fixations in this process. We created a computational model of value-based binary choice in which fixations guide the comparison process and tested it on humans using eye-tracking. We found that the model can quantitatively explain complex relationships between fixation patterns and choices, as well as several fixation-driven decision biases.

1,018 citations


"A Zero Attraction Effect in Natural..." refers background in this paper

  • ...…decision field theory, Roe et al., 2001; leaky competing accumulators, Usher & McClelland, 2004; multialternative attentional drift–diffusion model, Krajbich et al., 2010; rangenormalization model, Soltani et al., 2012; associative accumulation model, Bhatia, 2013; multiattribute linear ballistic…...

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors interpret decision field theory (J. R. Busemeyer and J. T. Townsend, 1993) as a connectionist network and extend it to accommodate multialternative preferential choice situations.
Abstract: The authors interpret decision field theory (J. R. Busemeyer & J. T. Townsend, 1993) as a connectionist network and extend it to accommodate multialternative preferential choice situations. This article shows that the classic weighted additive utility model (see R. L. Keeney & H. Raiffa, 1976) and the classic Thurstone preferential choice model (see L. L. Thurstone, 1959) are special cases of this new multialternative decision field theory (MDFT), which also can emulate the search process of the popular elimination by aspects (EBA) model (see A. Tversky, 1969). The new theory is unique in its ability to explain several central empirical results found in the multialternative preference literature with a common set of principles. These empirical results include the similarity effect, the attraction effect, and the compromise effect, and the complex interactions among these three effects. The dynamic nature of the model also implies strong testable predictions concerning the moderating effect of time pressure on these three effects.

616 citations


"A Zero Attraction Effect in Natural..." refers background in this paper

  • ...…with a significant number of various theoretical accounts being developed over the past 20 years (e.g., multialternative decision field theory, Roe et al., 2001; leaky competing accumulators, Usher & McClelland, 2004; multialternative attentional drift–diffusion model, Krajbich et al., 2010;…...

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A survey of the choice axiom and its application in psychophysical theory can be found in this paper, with a focus on the use of choice models in the context of psychophysics.
Abstract: This survey is divided into three major sections. The first concerns mathematical results about the choice axiom and the choice models that devoIve from it. For example, its relationship to Thurstonian theory is satisfyingly understood; much is known about how choice and ranking probabilities may relate, although little of this knowledge seems empirically useful; and there are certain interesting statistical facts. The second section describes attempts that have been made to test and apply these models. The testing has been done mostly, though not exclusively, by psychologists; the applications have been mostly in economics and sociology. Although it is clear from many experiments that the conditions under which the choice axiom holds are surely delicate, the need for simple, rational underpinnings in complex theories, as in economics and sociology, leads one to accept assumptions that are at best approximate. And the third section concerns alternative, more general theories which, in spirit, are much like the choice axiom. Perhaps I had best admit at the outset that, as a commentator on this scene, I am qualified no better than many others and rather less well than some who have been working in this area recently, which I have not been. My pursuits have led me along other, somewhat related routes. On the one hand, I have contributed to some of the recent, purely algebraic aspects of fundamental measurement (for a survey of some of this material, see Krantz, Lute, Suppes, & Tversky, 1971). And on the other hand, I have worked in the highly probabilistic area of psychophysical theory; but the empirical materials have led me away from axiomatic structures, such as the choice axiom, to more structural, neural models which are not readily axiomatized at the present time. After some attempts to apply choice models to psychophysical phenomena (discussed below in its proper place), I was led to conclude that it is not a very promising approach to, these data, and so I have not been actively studying any aspect of the choice axiom in over 12 years. With that understood, let us begin.

535 citations


"A Zero Attraction Effect in Natural..." refers background in this paper

  • ...In addition, the attraction effect can violate the regularity condition, which states that an option’s choice probability cannot increase when the choice set is extended (Luce, 1977; Tversky, 1972)....

    [...]