scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Adverse Selection and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets: When Nudging Hurts

01 Dec 2013-The American Economic Review (American Economic Association)-Vol. 103, Iss: 7, pp 2643-2682
TL;DR: A major change to insurance provision that occurred at a large firm is leveraged to identify substantial inertia, and a choice model is developed and estimated that also quantifies risk preferences and ex ante health risk.
Abstract: This paper investigates consumer inertia in health insurance markets, where adverse selection is a potential concern. We leverage a major change to insurance provision that occurred at a large firm to identify substantial inertia, and develop and estimate a choice model that also quantifies risk preferences and ex ante health risk. We use these estimates to study the impact of policies that nudge consumers toward better decisions by reducing inertia. When aggregated, these improved individual-level choices substantially exacerbate adverse selection in our setting, leading to an overall reduction in welfare that doubles the existing welfare loss from adverse selection. (JEL D82, G22, I13) A number of potential impediments stand in the way of efficient health insur ance markets. The most noted of these is adverse selection, first studied by Akerlof (1970) and Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976). In insurance markets, prices reflect the expected risk (costs) of the insured pool. Whether the reason is price regulation or private information, when insurers cannot price all risk characteristics riskier consumers choose more comprehensive health plans. This causes the equilibrium prices of these plans to rise and healthier enrollees to select less comprehensive coverage than they would otherwise prefer.
Figures (11)

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Online Appendix
Adverse Selection and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets:
When Nudging Hurts
Benjamin Handel
August 29, 2013
Abstract
This online appendix provides supporting analysis for the primary manuscript ’Adverse Selec-
tion and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets: When Nudging Hurts’ published in the American
Economic Review. Appendix A describes the cost model setup and estimation. Appendix B de-
scribes the choice model estimation algorithm in greater detail. Appendix C discusses a robust
check allowing for moral hazard, i.e. a price elasticity of demand for medical expenditures. Ap-
pendix D discusses different interpretations of and foundations for inertia. Appendix E presents
additional supporting analyses.
Department of Economics, University of California at Berkeley. Contact: handel@berkeley.edu.

Online Appendix A: Cost Model Setup and Estimation
This appendix describes the details of the cost model, which is summarized at a high-level in
section 3. The output of this model, F
kjt
, is a family-plan-time specific distribution of predicted
out-of-pocket expenditures for the upcoming year. This distribution is an important input into the
choice model, where it enters as a family’s predictions of its out-of-pocket expenses at the time
of plan choice, for each plan option. We predict this distribution in a sophisticated manner that
incorporates (i) past diagnostic information (ICD-9 codes) (ii) the Johns Hopkins ACG predictive
medical software package (iii) a novel non-parametric model linking modeled health risk to total
medical expenditures using observed cost data and (iv) a detailed division of medical claims and
health plan characteristics to precisely map total medical expenditures to out-of-pocket expenses.
1
The level of precision we gain from the cost model leads to more credible estimates of the choice
parameters of primary interest (e.g. inertia).
In order to most precisely predict expenses, we categorize the universe of total medical claims
into four mutually exclusive and exhaustive subdivisions of claims using the claims data. These
categories are (i) hospital and physician (ii) pharmacy (iii) mental health and (iv) physician office
visit. We divide claims into these four specific categories so that we can accurately characterize the
plan-specific mappings from total claims to out-of-pocket expenditures since each of these categories
maps to out-of-pocket expenditures in a different manner. We denote this four dimensional vector
of claims C
it
and any given element of that vector C
d,it
where d D represents one of the four
categories and i denotes an individual (employee or dependent). After describing how we predict this
vector of claims for a given individual, we return to the question of how we determine out-of-pocket
expenditures in plan j given C
it
.
Denote an individual’s past year of medical diagnoses and payments by ξ
it
and the demographics
age and sex by ζ
it
. We use the ACG software mapping, denoted A, to map these characteristics
into a predicted mean level of health expenditures for the upcoming year, denoted θ:
A : ξ × ζ θ
In addition to forecasting a mean level of total expenditures, the software has an application
that predicts future mean pharmacy expenditures. This mapping is analogous to A and outputs a
prediction λ for future pharmacy expenses.
We use the predictions θ and λ to categorize similar groups of individuals across each of four
claims categories in vector in C
it
. Then for each group of individuals in each claims category, we
use the actual ex post realized claims for that group to estimate the ex ante distribution for each
individual under the assumption that this distribution is identical for all individuals within the cell.
Individuals are categorized into cells based on different metrics for each of the four elements of C:
Pharmacy: λ
it
Hospital / Physician (Non-OV): θ
it
Physician Office Visit: θ
it
Mental Health: C
MH,i,t1
For pharmacy claims, individuals are grouped into cells based on the predicted future mean phar-
1
Features (iii) and (iv) are methodological advances. We are aware of only one previous study that incorporates
diagnostic information in cost prediction for the purposes of studying plan choice (Carlin and Town (2009)) in a
structural setup. Recent work by Einav et al. (2013) use this type of framework as well.
2

macy claims measure output by the ACG software, λ
it
. For the categories of hospital / physician
(non office visit) and physician office visit claims individuals are grouped based on their mean pre-
dicted total future health expenses, θ
it
. Finally, for mental health claims, individuals are grouped
into categories based on their mental health claims from the previous year, C
MH,i,t1
since (i)
mental health claims are very persistent over time in the data and (ii) mental health claims are
uncorrelated with other health expenditures in the data. For each category we group individuals
into a number of cells between 8 and 10, taking into account the trade off between cell size and
precision. The minimum number of individuals in any cell is 73 while almost all cells have over
500 members. Thus since there are four categories of claims, each individual can belong to one of
approximately 10
4
or 10,000 combination of cells.
Denote an arbitrary cell within a given category d by z. Denote the population in a given
category-cell combination (d, z) by I
dz
. Denote the empirical distribution of ex-post claims in
this category for this population
ˆ
G
I
dz
(·). Then we assume that each individual in this cell has a
distribution equal to a continuous fit of
ˆ
G
I
dz
(·), which we denote G
dz
:
$ :
ˆ
G
I
dz
(·) G
dz
We model this distribution continuously in order to easily incorporate correlations across d. Oth-
erwise, it would be appropriate to use G
I
dz
as the distribution for each cell.
The above process generates a distribution of claims for each d and z but does not model
correlations over D. It is important to model correlation over claim categories because it is likely
that someone with a bad expenditure shock in one category (e.g. hospital) will have high expenses in
another area (e.g. pharmacy). We model correlation at the individual level by combining marginal
distributions G
idt
d with empirical data on the rank correlations between pairs (d, d
0
).
2
Here, G
idt
is the distribution G
dz
where i I
dz
at time t. Since correlations are modeled across d we pick the
metric θ to group people into cells for the basis of determining correlations (we use the same cells
that we use to determine group people for hospital and physician office visit claims). Denote these
cells based on θ by z
θ
. Then for each cell z
θ
denote the empirical rank correlation between claims of
type d and type d
0
by ρ
z
θ
(d, d
0
). Then, for a given individual i we determine the joint distribution
of claims across D for year t, denoted H
it
(·), by combining i’s marginal distributions for all d at t
using ρ
z
θ
(d, d
0
):
Ψ : G
iDt
× ρ
z
θ
it
(D, D
0
) H
it
Here, G
iDt
refers to the set of marginal distributions G
idt
d D and ρ
z
θ
it
(D, D
0
) is the set of
all pairwise correlations ρ
z
θ
it
(d, d
0
)(d, d
0
) D
2
. In estimation we perform Ψ by using a Gaussian
copula to combine the marginal distribution with the rank correlations, a process which we describe
momentarily.
The final part of the cost model maps the joint distribution H
it
of the vector of total claims C
over the four categories into a distribution of out of pocket expenditures for each plan. For each
of the three plan options we construct a mapping from the vector of claims C to out of pocket
expenditures OOP
j
:
j
: C OOP
j
This mapping takes a given draw of claims from H
it
and converts it into the out of pocket expendi-
tures an individual would have for those claims in plan j. This mapping accounts for plan-specific
2
It is important to use rank correlations here to properly combine these marginal distribution into a joint distri-
bution. Linear correlation would not translate empirical correlations to this joint distribution appropriately.
3

features such as the deductible, co-insurance, co-payments, and out of pocket maximums listed in
table A-2. I test the mapping
j
on the actual realizations of the claims vector C to verify that
our mapping comes close to reconstructing the true mapping. Our mapping is necessarily simpler
and omits things like emergency room co-payments and out of network claims. We constructed our
mapping with and without these omitted categories to insure they did not lead to an incremental
increase in precision. We find that our categorization of claims into the four categories in C passed
through our mapping
j
closely approximates the true mapping from claims to out-of-pocket ex-
penses. Further, we find that it is important to model all four categories described above: removing
any of the four makes
j
less accurate. Figure A-1 shows the results of one validation exercise
for P P O
250
. The top panel reveals that actual employee out-of-pocket spending amounts are quite
close to those predicted by
j
, indicating the precision of this mapping. The bottom panel repeats
this mapping when we add out of network expenses as a fifth category. The output in this case is
similar to that in the top panel without this category, implying that including this category would
not markedly change the cost model results.
Once we have a draw of OOP
ijt
for each i (claim draw from H
it
passed through
j
) we map
individual out of pocket expenditures into family out of pocket expenditures. For families with less
than two members this involves adding up all the within family OOP
ijt
. For families with more than
three members there are family level restrictions on deductible paid and out-of-pocket maximums
that we adjust for. Define a family k as a collection of individuals i
k
and the set of families as K.
Then for a given family out-of-pocket expenditures are generated:
Γ
j
: OOP
i
k
,jt
OOP
kjt
To create the final object of interest, the family-plan-time specific distribution of out of pocket
expenditures F
kjt
(·), we pass the claims distributions H
it
through
j
and combine families through
Γ
j
. F
kjt
(·) is then used as an input into the choice model that represents each family’s information
set over future medical expenses at the time of plan choice. Eventually, we also use H
it
to calculate
total plan cost when we analyze counterfactual plan pricing based on the average cost of enrollees.
Figure A-2 outlines the primary components of the cost model pictorially to provide a high-level
overview and to ease exposition.
We note that the decision to do the cost model by grouping individuals into cells, rather then by
specifying a more continuous form, has costs and benefits. The cost is that all individuals within a
given cell for a given type of claims are treated identically. The benefit is that our method produces
local cost estimates for each individual that are not impacted by the combination of functional form
and the health risk of medically different individuals. Also, the method we use allows for flexible
modeling across claims categories. Finally, we note that we map the empirical distribution of claims
to a continuous representation because this is convenient for building in correlations in the next
step. The continuous distributions we generate very closely fit the actual empirical distribution of
claims across these four categories.
Cost Model Identification and Estimation. The cost model is identified based on the two
assumptions of (i) no moral hazard / selection based on private information and (ii) that individ-
uals within the same cells for claims d have the same ex ante distribution of total claims in that
category. Once these assumptions are made, the model uses the detailed medical data, the Johns
Hopkins predictive algorithm, and the plan-specific mappings for out of pocket expenditures to
generate the the final output F
kjt
(·). These assumptions, and corresponding robustness analyses,
are discussed at more length in the main text.
Once we group individuals into cells for each of the four claims categories, there are two statistical
4

components to estimation. First, we need to generate the continuous marginal distribution of claims
for each cell z in claim category d, G
dz
. To do this, we fit the empirical distribution of claims G
I
dz
to a Weibull distribution with a mass of values at 0. We use the Weibull distribution instead of the
log-normal distribution, which is traditionally used to model medical expenditures, because we find
that the log-normal distribution overpredicts large claims in the data while the Weibull does not.
For each d and z the claims greater than zero are estimated with a maximum likelihood fit to the
Weibull distribution:
max
(α
dz
dz
)
Π
iI
dz
β
dz
α
dz
(
c
id
α
dz
)
β
dz
1
e
(
c
id
α
dz
)
β
dz
Here, ˆα
dz
and
ˆ
β
dz
are the shape and scale parameters that characterize the Weibull distribution.
Denoting this distribution W ( ˆα
dz
,
ˆ
β
dz
) the estimated distribution
ˆ
G
dz
is formed by combining this
with the estimated mass at zero claims, which is the empirical likelihood:
ˆ
G
dz
(c) =
(
G
I
dz
(0) if c = 0
G
I
dz
(0) +
W ( ˆα
dz
,
ˆ
β
dz
)(c)
1G
I
dz
(0)
if c > 0
Again, we use the notation
ˆ
G
iDt
to represent the set of marginal distributions for i over the
categories d: the distribution for each d depends on the cell z an individual i is in at t. We
combine the distributions
ˆ
G
iDt
for a given i and t into the joint distribution H
it
using a Gaussian
copula method for the mapping Ψ. Intuitively, this amounts to assuming a parametric form for
correlation across
ˆ
G
iDt
equivalent to that from a standard normal distribution with correlations
equal to empirical rank correlations ρ
z
θ
it
(D, D
0
) described in the previous section. Let Φ
i
1|2|3|4
denote the standard multivariate normal distribution with pairwise correlations ρ
z
θ
it
(D, D
0
) for all
pairings of the four claims categories D. Then an individual’s joint distribution of non-zero claims
is:
ˆ
H
i,t
(·) = Φ
1|2|3|4
1
1
(
ˆ
G
id
1
t
), Φ
1
2
(
ˆ
G
id
2
t
), Φ
1
3
(
ˆ
G
id
3
t
), Φ
1
4
(
ˆ
G
id
4
t
))))
Above, Φ
d
is the standard marginal normal distribution for each d.
ˆ
H
i,t
is the joint distribution
of claims across the four claims categories for each individual in each time period. After this is
estimated, we determine our final object of interest F
kjt
(·) by simulating K multivariate draws
from
ˆ
H
i,t
for each i and t, and passing these values through the plan-specific total claims to out of
pocket mapping
j
and the individual to family out of pocket mapping Γ
j
. The simulated F
kjt
(·)
for each k, j, and t is then used as an input into estimation of the choice model.
Table A-1 presents summary results from the cost model estimation for the final choice model
sample, including population statistics on the ACG index θ, the Weibull distribution parameters
ˆα
dz
and
ˆ
β
dz
for each category d, as well as the across category rank correlations ρ
z
θ
it
(D, D
0
). These
are the fundamentals inputs used to generate F
kjt
, as described above, and lead to very accurate
characterizations of the overall total cost and out-of-pocket cost distributions (validation exercises
which are not presented here).
5

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
Raj Chetty1
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a more pragmatic perspective on behavioral economics that focuses on its value for improving empirical predictions and policy decisions, and discuss three ways in which behavioral economics can contribute to public policy.
Abstract: The debate about behavioral economics { the incorporation of insights from psychology into economics { is often framed as a question about the foundational assumptions of economic models. This paper presents a more pragmatic perspective on behavioral economics that focuses on its value for improving empirical predictions and policy decisions. I discuss three ways in which behavioral economics can contribute to public policy: by oering new policy tools, improving predictions about the eects

411 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper analyzes the industrial organization literature on health care markets focusing on the impact of competition on price, quality and treatment decisions for health care providers and health insurers and concludes with a discussion of research opportunities for industrial organization economists.
Abstract: The U.S. health-care sector is large and growing—health-care spending in 2011 amounted to $2.7 trillion and 18 percent of GDP. Approximately half of health-care output is allocated via markets. In this paper, we analyze the industrial organization literature on health-care markets, focusing on the impact of competition on price, quality, and treatment decisions for health-care providers and health insurers. We conclude with a discussion of research opportunities for industrial organization economists, including opportunities created by the U.S. Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act.

338 citations


Cites background from "Adverse Selection and Inertia in He..."

  • ...Handel (2013) fits into this category....

    [...]

  • ...However, any frictions in the decision-making process, caused by switching costs or other types of inertia (Handel, 2013), could limit the increase in consumer welfare....

    [...]

  • ...One question raised by Handel (2013) is what causes this substantial consumer inertia, and what policy changes could (or should) be made to address it....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: It is shown that, at least in this context, abstracting from selection on moral hazard could lead to over-estimates of the spending reduction associated with introducing a high-deductible health insurance option.
Abstract: In this paper we explore the possibility that individuals may select insurance coverage in part based on their anticipated behavioral response to the insurance contract. Such "selection on moral hazard" can have important implications for attempts to combat either selection or moral hazard. We explore these issues using individual-level panel data from a single firm, which contain information about health insurance options, choices, and subsequent claims. To identify the behavioral response to health insurance coverage and the heterogeneity in it, we take advantage of a change in the health insurance options offered to some, but not all of the firm's employees. We begin with descriptive evidence that is suggestive of both heterogeneous moral hazard as well as selection on it, with individuals who select more coverage also appearing to exhibit greater behavioral response to that coverage. To formalize this analysis and explore its implications, we develop and estimate a model of plan choice and medical utilization. The results from the modeling exercise echo the descriptive evidence, and allow for further explorations of the interaction between selection and moral hazard. For example, one implication of our estimates is that abstracting from selection on moral hazard could lead one to substantially over-estimate the spending reduction associated with introducing a high deductible health insurance option.

325 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors combine a field experiment with a simple theoretical framework to evaluate the welfare effects of one especially policy-relevant intervention, home energy social comparison reports, and develop a prediction algorithm for optimal targeting; this approach would double the welfare gains.
Abstract: "Nudge"-style interventions are often deemed successful if they generate large behavior change at low cost, but they are rarely subjected to full social welfare evaluations. We combine a field experiment with a simple theoretical framework to evaluate the welfare effects of one especially policy-relevant intervention, home energy social comparison reports. In our sample, the reports increase social welfare, although traditional evaluation approaches overstate gains because they ignore significant costs incurred by nudge recipients. Overall, home energy report welfare gains might be overstated by $620 million. We develop a prediction algorithm for optimal targeting; this approach would double the welfare gains.

268 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper combines new administrative data on health plan choices and claims with unique survey data on consumer information to identify risk preferences, information frictions, and hassle costs and study the implications of counterfactual insurance allocations.
Abstract: Traditional models of insurance choice are predicated on fully informed and rational consumers protecting themselves from exposure to financial risk. In practice, choosing an insurance plan is a complicated decision often made without full information. In this paper we combine new administrative data on health plan choices and claims with unique survey data on consumer information to identify risk preferences, information frictions, and hassle costs. Our additional friction measures are important predictors of choices and meaningfully impact risk preference estimates. We study the implications of counterfactual insurance allocations to illustrate the importance of distinguishing between these micro-foundations for welfare analysis.

249 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a struggling attempt to give structure to the statement: "Business in under-developed countries is difficult"; in particular, a structure is given for determining the economic costs of dishonesty.
Abstract: This paper relates quality and uncertainty. The existence of goods of many grades poses interesting and important problems for the theory of markets. On the one hand, the interaction of quality differences and uncertainty may explain important institutions of the labor market. On the other hand, this paper presents a struggling attempt to give structure to the statement: “Business in under-developed countries is difficult”; in particular, a structure is given for determining the economic costs of dishonesty. Additional applications of the theory include comments on the structure of money markets, on the notion of “insurability,” on the liquidity of durables, and on brand-name goods.

17,764 citations

Book
08 Apr 2008
TL;DR: In Nudge as discussed by the authors, Thaler and Sunstein argue that human beings are susceptible to various biases that can lead us to blunder and make bad decisions involving education, personal finance, health care, mortgages and credit cards, the family, and even the planet itself.
Abstract: A groundbreaking discussion of how we can apply the new science of choice architecture to nudge people toward decisions that will improve their lives by making them healthier, wealthier, and more free Every day, we make decisions on topics ranging from personal investments to schools for our children to the meals we eat to the causes we champion. Unfortunately, we often choose poorly. Nobel laureate Richard Thaler and legal scholar and bestselling author Cass Sunstein explain in this important exploration of choice architecture that, being human, we all are susceptible to various biases that can lead us to blunder. Our mistakes make us poorer and less healthy; we often make bad decisions involving education, personal finance, health care, mortgages and credit cards, the family, and even the planet itself. In Nudge, Thaler and Sunstein invite us to enter an alternative world, one that takes our humanness as a given. They show that by knowing how people think, we can design choice environments that make it easier for people to choose what is best for themselves, their families, and their society. Using colorful examples from the most important aspects of life, Thaler and Sunstein demonstrate how thoughtful "choice architecture" can be established to nudge us in beneficial directions without restricting freedom of choice. Nudge offers a unique new take-from neither the left nor the right-on many hot-button issues, for individuals and governments alike. This is one of the most engaging and provocative books to come along in many years.

7,772 citations


"Adverse Selection and Inertia in He..." refers background in this paper

  • ...A collection of research summarized by Thaler and Sunstein (2008) presents strong evidence that consumer decisions are heavily influenced by context and can systematically depart from those that would be made in a rational frictionless environment....

    [...]

Book
01 Jan 2003
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors describe the new generation of discrete choice methods, focusing on the many advances that are made possible by simulation, and compare simulation-assisted estimation procedures, including maximum simulated likelihood, method of simulated moments, and methods of simulated scores.
Abstract: This book describes the new generation of discrete choice methods, focusing on the many advances that are made possible by simulation. Researchers use these statistical methods to examine the choices that consumers, households, firms, and other agents make. Each of the major models is covered: logit, generalized extreme value, or GEV (including nested and cross-nested logits), probit, and mixed logit, plus a variety of specifications that build on these basics. Simulation-assisted estimation procedures are investigated and compared, including maximum simulated likelihood, method of simulated moments, and method of simulated scores. Procedures for drawing from densities are described, including variance reduction techniques such as anithetics and Halton draws. Recent advances in Bayesian procedures are explored, including the use of the Metropolis-Hastings algorithm and its variant Gibbs sampling. No other book incorporates all these fields, which have arisen in the past 20 years. The procedures are applicable in many fields, including energy, transportation, environmental studies, health, labor, and marketing.

7,768 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A series of decision-making experiments showed that individuals disproportionately stick with the status quo as mentioned in this paper, that is, doing nothing or maintaining one's current or previous decision, and that this bias is substantial in important real decisions.
Abstract: Most real decisions, unlike those of economics texts, have a status quo alternative—that is, doing nothing or maintaining one's current or previous decision. A series of decision-making experiments shows that individuals disproportionately stick with the status quo. Data on the selections of health plans and retirement programs by faculty members reveal that the status quo bias is substantial in important real decisions. Economics, psychology, and decision theory provide possible explanations for this bias. Applications are discussed ranging from marketing techniques, to industrial organization, to the advance of science.

4,817 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a menu of paired lottery choices is structured so that the crossover point to the high-risk lottery can be used to infer the degree of risk aversion, and a hybrid "power/expo" utility function with increasing relative and decreasing absolute risk aversion is presented.
Abstract: A menu of paired lottery choices is structured so that the crossover point to the high-risk lottery can be used to infer the degree of risk aversion With normal laboratory payoffs of several dollars, most subjects are risk averse and few are risk loving Scaling up all payoffs by factors of twenty, fifty, and ninety makes little difference when the high payoffs are hypothetical In contrast, subjects become sharply more risk averse when the high payoffs are actually paid in cash A hybrid "power/expo" utility function with increasing relative and decreasing absolute risk aversion nicely replicates the data patterns over this range of payoffs from several dollars to several hundred dollars

4,687 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Online appendix adverse selection and inertia in health insurance markets: when nudging hurts" ?

This online appendix provides supporting analysis for the primary manuscript ’ Adverse Selection and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets: When Nudging Hurts ’ published in the American Economic Review. The authors predict this distribution in a sophisticated manner that incorporates ( i ) past diagnostic information ( ICD-9 codes ) ( ii ) the Johns Hopkins ACG predictive medical software package ( iii ) a novel non-parametric model linking modeled health risk to total medical expenditures using observed cost data and ( iv ) a detailed division of medical claims and health plan characteristics to precisely map total medical expenditures to out-of-pocket expenses. In order to most precisely predict expenses, the authors categorize the universe of total medical claims into four mutually exclusive and exhaustive subdivisions of claims using the claims data. The authors divide claims into these four specific categories so that they can accurately characterize the plan-specific mappings from total claims to out-of-pocket expenditures since each of these categories maps to out-of-pocket expenditures in a different manner. The authors denote this four dimensional vector of claims Cit and any given element of that vector Cd, it where d ∈ D represents one of the four categories and i denotes an individual ( employee or dependent ). After describing how the authors predict this vector of claims for a given individual, they return to the question of how they determine out-of-pocket expenditures in plan j given Cit.