scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Bundling and pricing of product with after-sale services

02 Jun 2009-International Journal of Operational Research (Inderscience Publishers)-Vol. 6, Iss: 1, pp 92-109
TL;DR: In this article, the problem of bundling and pricing of a complex durable product with the after-sales repair and maintenance services is considered for two product market structures: monopoly and duopoly.
Abstract: Bundling is the sale of two or more products in combination as a package. In this paper, we consider the bundling and pricing of a complex durable product with the after-sales repair and maintenance services. The product and service are two different, but related markets for this scenario. The problem of bundling and pricing are considered for two product market structures: monopoly and duopoly. In the monopoly case, the decision framework is an optimisation problem, whereas for the duopoly, the strategic interactions of the two firms are modelled as a two stage non-cooperative game. These decision frameworks enable the manufacturing firms to decide upon the product-service bundling and pricing.

Summary (3 min read)

1 Introduction

  • Integration of service with product is considered as one of the innovative supply chain initiatives of the next decade (Anderson and Delattre, 2002).
  • Study by Cohen (Cohen et al., 1997) indicate that manufacturers in electronics/computing industry are acting aggressively for service revenue (through maintenance contracts) after relatively short warranty periods.
  • The decision making framework for the monopoly situation is considered in Section 4 and the duopoly game model is solved in Section 5.
  • The model assumes that consumers valuation for the product is deterministically known to the manufacturers.

2 Integration of Manufacturing and Service

  • The service industry is difficult to define because it includes many diverse activities.
  • Many manufacturing firms are increasing the proportion of their turnover earned from selling services by bundling, as a single package or as add-ons to products at different times.
  • In (Viswanadham et al., 2005), manufacturing and service were integrated in a single network to investigate the impact of manufacturing and service phases on each other, when product-service bundles are being offered.
  • The conditions under which bundling is an optimal strategy was investigated in (McAfee et al., 1989) for a multiproduct monopolist.
  • This leads to the use of game theory as the decision tool.

3.1 Product and Service Markets

  • The product P is not identified by its brand or model but by its type, which explains its usage.
  • In any city, one can find several electrical equipment service centers for repairing refrigerators and air conditioners of various brands and models.
  • Let w be the total cost a consumer is willing to pay for servicing the product during its lifetime.
  • This is because the independent service providers do not service the product for its entire lifetime for a previously agreed upon cost.
  • A consumer can thus choose to buy the service from the manufacturer or can avail it across different independent service providers during the lifetime.

3.2 Manufacturing Firm and the Consumers

  • Let the constant marginal cost of providing the lifetime service for the firm be cS ∈ [W,W ].
  • If the firm provides the lifetime service for price β, then all the consumers with WTP w ≥ β will buy the service from the manufacturer for the entire product lifetime.
  • Since the money value would change during the lifetime of the product, they are assumed to be suitably discounted using a common discounting factor for both the manufacturer and consumers.
  • The offering P & PS means that the firm can sell the product alone and also as a bundle with the service.
  • Given the above setup, the authors consider two scenarios in the product market: monopoly and duopoly.

4 Monopoly in Product Market

  • The firm faces no competition and hence the decision making is an optimization problem with the objective of maximizing the payoff.
  • The payoff πj for the offering j depends on the price of the offering.
  • Hence the optimal price α∗ = v and the total payoff to the firm is πP = v − cP (2) The firm, being a monopoly, is best off by charging the maximum price and the consumers are worse off in this scenario.
  • The other consumers (with w < β) will buy the service from the independent service providers at their respective w.
  • A consumer can buy only the bundle.

5 Duopoly in the Product Market

  • In this section the authors consider the duopoly in the product market.
  • The authors focus here is similar as the whether the firms that manufacture P should bundle along with it the S. Consider two firms 1 and 2, which manufacture the same product and the valuation for the products manufactured by these two firms are the same v for the consumers.
  • Both the firms are aware of the advantages of entering the service market.
  • These games are played sequentially by the same players, and the total payoffs from the sequence of games will be evaluated using the sequence of outcomes in the games that were played.
  • Both firms choose the price simultaneously without the knowledge of the price chosen by the competing firm.

5.1 The Two-stage Game

  • Following are the assumptions of the two stage game: 1. Both the firms have the same constant marginal cost of producing the product cP and the same constant marginal cost of providing the service (for the lifetime) cS .
  • The second assumption is more of a realistic constraint where a firm need not provide service to its competing product.
  • This may also be due to the technological constraints.
  • The firms 1 and 2 are capable of producing the product P and providing the service S. In the first stage, both the firms choose the offering.
  • There are nine possible pricing games, one for each of the nine possible outcomes of the stage 1.

5.2 Pricing Subgames

  • Stage 2 has nine pricing subgames, but due to the symmetry of the firms in terms of costs and offerings, only six distinct games need to be examined.
  • The Nash equilibrium of each of them are determined in the following.
  • The proof is based on the lines of Bertrand Duopoly (Varian, 1992) situation.
  • If both firms can cooperate, then they both can charge the highest possible price and share the profits equally, leaving the consumers worse-off.

5.6 Offerings Game

  • The row strategies are for firm 1 and the column strategies are for firm 2.
  • Note that these ordered pair entries are NE outcomes of the corresponding pricing games of stage 2.
  • Thus is can be easily seen that the NE strategies are (P, PS) and (PS, P ), both earning nonzero profits to both the firms.
  • Without loss of generality, let firm 1 enter the market first, followed by firm 2.

6 Heterogeneous Preferences for the Product Market

  • It can be easily seen that Proposition 1 holds true with the above assumption.
  • In the following, the authors graphically analyze the the three symmetric pricing subgames.
  • The horizontal and vertical axes in figures 2-4 are for the product and service, respectively.

7 Conclusions

  • Integration of service with product is considered as one of the innovative supply chain initiatives of the next decade.
  • A consumer’s WTP for the lifetime service was assumed to be uniformly distributed.
  • The firms were assumed to be non-cooperative and hence the interactions were modeled as a two stage non-cooperative game.
  • It is worth investigating the model where both the firms have different production and service costs.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Bundling and Pricing of Product with After-sale Services
S. Kameshwaran
N. Viswanadham
Centre for Global Logistics and Manufacturing Strategies,
Indian School of Business,
Gachibowli, Hyderabad 500032
Email: Kameshwaran S@isb.edu, N Viswanadham@isb.edu
Corresponding Author
Vijay Desai
Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research,
Columbia University,
NY 10027-6699.
Email: vvd2101@columbia.edu
Abstract: Bundling is the sale of two or more products in combination as a package.
In this paper we consider the bundling and pricing of a complex durable product with the
after-sales repair and maintenance services. The product and service are two different, but
related markets for this scenario. The problem of bundling and pricing are considered for
two pro duct market structures: monopoly and duopoly. In the monopoly case, the decision
framework is an optimization problem, whereas for the duopoly, the strategic interactions of
the two firms are modeled as a two stage non-cooperative game. These decision frameworks
enable the manufacturing firms to decide upon the product-se rvice bundling and pricing.
Keywords: manufacturing service integration, product bundling, non-cooperative game,
sub-game perfect equilibrium
Biographical Notes: S. Kameshwaran is currently a senior researcher at the Indian School
of Business. Prior to this, he worked as a Research Engineer in The Logistics Institute-Asia
Pacific, Singapore and as a post doctoral fellow in INRIA Lorraine, France. He received
his Ph.D in Computer Science from the Indian Institute of Science, Bangalore in 2004. His
research interests are in the areas of algorithmic operations research, discrete optimization,
and game theory with applications in supply chain management and e-commerce.
Professor N. Viswanadham is the Executive Director of Centre of Excellence for Global
Logistics and Manufacturing Strategies at the Indian School of Business. Prior to this, he
was the Deputy Executive Director of The Logistics Institute-Asia Pacific and also Professor
in the Department of Mechanical and Production Engineering at the National University of
Singap ore. He is the recipient of the IBM Faculty Award for 2006. He was a GE Research
Fellow and Tata Chemicals Chair Professor at the Indian Institute of Science, Bangalore and
was also a faculty member at the Indian Institute of Science till 1998. Professor Viswanadham
is a Fellow of a number of professional societies and academies such as the IEEE, INSA, IASc,
INAE, and the TWAS. He is the author of three textbooks, six edited volumes, over eighty
journal articles and more than hundred conference papers on automation.
Vijay De sai is currently a PhD student at Dept. of IEOR in Columbia University. He holds
a Bachelors degree from Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay and Masters degree from
Singap ore- MIT Alliance. He has worked as a research engineer at The Logistics Institute -
Asia Pacific. His research interests are in the area of revenue management and optimization.
1

1 Introduction
Integration of service with pro duct is considered as one of the innovative supply chain initiatives
of the next decade (Anderson and Delattre, 2002). At the outset, it can be seen as the merging
of the old economy (manufacturing) with the new economy of service industries. However, the
manufactured products are linked to services via the competitive strategies of individual firms
(Marceau and Martinez, 2002). The service can be linked to the product at various stages in
the supply chain. In this paper, we consider the linking at the final stage of distribution and
marketing. In particular, the focus is on the packaging of a complex durable product with its
after-sales repair and maintenance services as a single bundle.
Manufacturing has traditionally meant the production of tangible goods, but for today’s
customers it is the bundling of the tangible product with an array of intangible services that
makes for the most desirable service-enhanced product (Lester, 1998). With more customers
seeking solutions instead of spe cific products or brands, a growing number of products are
becoming commodities. Thus the emphasis of customer satisfaction is on total cost of ownership,
which is determined not only by the product but also by the after-sales service. Companies
can provide good quality after-sales service to make product usage as hassle free as possible.
Towards this end, offering product-service bundles would be attractive to both customers and
manufacturers. The customers are freed from the burden of looking after upkeep of product and
has more control over the total cost of ownership. The manufacturers on the other hand, will
earn additional revenue with the sale of every product in terms of after-sales service. Numerous
studies (Alexander et al., 2002; Dennis and Kambil, 2003) s how that service tends to be a high
margin activity and bundling of products and services can be a good strategy for entering the
service market.
There is an interdependence between product and service sales, and decis ion making should
focus on the profitability from both sale of products and after-sales services, rather than on
per-transaction or per-p eriod profitability. For example, an article in San Jose Mercury News
(Nauman, 1994) reported that new car sales represented 59.9% of dealers revenue but only
1% of profit, while the se rvice and parts department generated 14.7% of their total revenue
and two-thirds of their total profits. Manufacturers such as Epson and Hewlett-Packard sell
their printers at loss to secure continuing profits from the sale of toner cartridges. Study by
Cohen (Cohen et al., 1997) indicate that manufacturers in electronics/computing industry are
acting aggressively for service revenue (through maintenance contracts) after relatively short
warranty periods. Thus across various industries, companies are beginning to regard initial
product sales primarily as positioning opportunities for pull through sales and service. In this
context, product-service bundle pricing becomes an important problem.
In this paper, we adopt a strategic framework to analyze the problem of product-service
bundling and pricing between two competing firms. The product and after-sales service are
two different markets with various players. A product manufacturer who intends to enter the
after-sales service market should take into account the strategic behavior of the players in both
the markets. In particular, the manufacturer should make the following decisions: (1) should he
enter the after-sales service market?, (2) if so, should he bundle it with the product?, and (3) at
what prices to offer the product and service?. Our focus is on complex durable products that
are economically attractive to maintain and service rather than replace . The product could be
an automobile, a farm equipment, or an elevator. It may be noticed that all of these products
require after sales support for preventive maintenance, spare parts for repair and emergency
breakdown servicing. We analyze this problem in a representative setting of monopoly and
duopoly product markets. The decision making in the monopoly market is an optimization
problem. The duopoly market has strategic competitors and the decision making is modeled as
a two stage non-cooperative sequential game. The subgame-perfect Nash equilibrium in pure
strategies is used as the solution concept. A preliminary version of this work was presented in
(Kameshwaran et al., 2007).
2

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly explains and reviews
the literature in the integration of manufacturing and service. The model for the product market
and the service market, with the consumers’ preferences are explained in Section 3. The decision
making framework for the monopoly situation is considered in Section 4 and the duopoly game
model is solved in Section 5. The model assumes that consumers valuation for the product is
deterministically known to the manufacturers. This assumption is relaxed with the valuation to
be uniformly distributed in Section 6. In Section 7, we conclude the pap e r with the promising
avenues for future research.
2 Integration of Manufacturing and Service
The service industry is difficult to define because it includes many diverse activities. Although
there is no consensus on the definition of a service industry, there is a broad agreement about
the attributes of its outputs: they are not tangible; they are consumed at the same time they
are produced; they have intangible value added; they are labor intensive (Karaomerlioglu and
Carlsson, 1999). However, these attributes do not necessarily apply all at once to all service
industries. Services also serve different markets: consumer markets, interme diate (producer)
markets, and state or public service markets, and involve different production proc es se s, includ-
ing the transformation of the state of physical objects, people or codified information (Miles,
1994). The services that are commonly incorporated within manufacturing include assembly,
testing, system integration, material purchasing, design, labelling, distribution, repair and main-
tenance. The after-sales repair and maintenance accounts for much apparent consumer spending
on services (Marceau and Martinez, 2002). In (Howells, 2000), the trend within manufacturing
industry firms towards bundling together their physical products and associated services is de-
scribed. Many manufacturing firms are increasing the proportion of their turnover earned from
selling services by bundling, as a single package or as add-ons to products at different times.
There are three major strategies used by firms in product-service packaging (Marceau and
Martinez, 2002):
Product-service integration: Service in incorporated through the different stages of the
production process.
Product-service bundling: Service is packaged with the product at or after the point of
sale.
Service enterprises: These are firms that package products produced by others with a raft
of services.
In product-service integration, s ervice comp onents are added during the production pro-
cess, influencing the characteristics and/or physical composition of the product itself. Such
service components may involve extra input of R&D, design, technical or engineering services
from clients in the downstream of the supply chain. Many of these are knowledge intensive. In
contrast, less knowledge intensive se rvices are bundled at the point of sale with the product. The
financial services and the after-sales repair and maintenance services belong to this category.
Some firms adopt both product-service integration and bundling strategies. In (Viswanadham
et al., 2005), manufacturing and service were integrated in a single network to investigate the
impact of manufacturing and service phases on each other, when product-service bundles are
being offered. Service enterprises do not manufacture products but provide after-sales services
to products manufactured by other firms. For example, there are engineering service enterprises
that provide repair and maintenance service for home appliances, manufactured by different
firms, as authorized service providers. In addition to the warranty provided by the manufactur-
ers, these enterprises provides extended warranty by collecting a premium from the consumer.
This is equivalent to selling of service but there is no bundling involved. In this paper, we focus
on the selling of product-service bundles by the manufacturing firm.
3

Bundling is the sale of two or more products in combination as a package. The bun-
dled products are assumed to have separate markets so that at least some consumers buy or
want to buy the products separately. Bundling has been studied from various perspectives in
the literature: consumer evaluation of bundles (Herrmann et al., 1999; Johnson et al., 1999;
Soman and Gourville, 2001; Yadav, 1994); optimality of bundling (Eppen et al., 1991; Guilti-
nan, 1987); pricing of bundles (Hanson and Martin, 1990; Ansari et al., 1996); optimality of
bundling for monopolists (Adams and Yellen, 1976; Schmalensee, 1982); and equilibrium theory
of bundling (Chen, 1997). Bundling was suggested as an alternative technique for price discrimi-
nation for monopolists (Stigler, 1968), which was further analyzed in (Adams and Yellen, 1976).
It was shown with stylized examples that a multiproduct monopolist can gain by selling the
different products in bundles, when the reservation values are negatively correlated. Bundling
was shown to be profitable even if the reservation values are uncorrelated or positively corre-
lated (Schmalensee, 1984). It reduced the effective dispersion of reservation values and thereby
the seller can extract a greater fraction of the p ote ntial surplus. The conditions under which
bundling is an optimal strategy was investigated in (McAfee et al., 1989) for a multiproduct
monopolist. A graphical analysis of bundling in (Salinger, 1995) showed the interaction between
the cost effects and demand effects, which in turn can be used to predict the conditions under
which bundling is profitable. Bundling has also been studied with varying assumptions on mar-
ket structure of the bundled products. In (Schmalensee, 1982), market of the first product is
assumed to be a monopoly and that of the second product to be in perfect comp etition. It was
shown that in such a scenario, the monopolist can never gain by bundling the product from the
first market with that from the second market. In (Whinston, 1990), the second market had
an oligopoly structure and the result showed that the bundling can be profitable because of the
strategic effect in the second market.
The focus of bundling can be product bundling or price bundling or both (Stremersch
and Tellis, 2002). Price bundling is the sale of two or more separate products in a package at
a discount, without any integration of the products. As there is no integration of products,
bundling itself does not create added value to consumers, and thus a discount must be offered
to motivate at least some consume rs to buy the bundle. This kind of bundling is usually used
to sell unpopular pro ducts along with the product ones and for also introducing a new pro duct
in the market, which is bundled initially with a popular product.
Product bundling is the integration and sale of two or more separate products at any
price. This integration provides at least some consumers with added value. Thus product
bundling is more of a long-term differentiation strategy than price bundling, which is a short-
term promotional tool. In this paper, our focus is on bundling of a complex durable product
with after-sales repair and maintenance services. Clearly, the product and the service are two
different products, as there exist different markets for each of them and consumers can buy
them separately. Further, this is product bundling as there is integration between the product
and the after-sales service that is provided by the product manufacturer. In general, after-sales
service market has numerous players (service providers), due to the relatively less entry barriers
in terms of technology and cost than that of the manufacturing sector. It is not uncommon for
the manufacturer to have a service station, thus acting as a common player in both the markets.
Thus the decision of bundling the service with the product for a given manufacturer should
take into account the comp e tition he faces from both the markets (the other manufacturers and
the se rvice providers). The markets are populated with non-cooperative players, who try to
maximize their individual profits. This leads to the use of game theory as the decision tool. In
the next section, we describe the model mathem atically.
4

3 The Model
3.1 Product and Service Markets
We consider a complex durable product P , which is economically attractive to maintain and
service, than to replace. The product P is not identified by its brand or model but by its type,
which explains its usage. For example, an automobile can be categorized as luxury or sports or
utility vehicle. We consider a particular category, which defines the product P and assume that
all consumers value the P at v = V . This simple assumption of deterministic reservation value
is later relaxed in Section 6, where the valuation v is assumed to be uniformly distributed in
range [V , V ].
The intention of bundling the after-sale services with the product is to offer the entire
package as a c ommodity. Thus for the manufacturer, entering the se rvice market is not just
opening a service center, but providing the service for a designated lifetime of the product,
for a previously agreed upon cost. The lifetime can be just considered as a fixed p e riod of
time, until which the consumer would definitely use the product. Currently, for many durable
products, the service market is populated with small independent service providers. In any
city, one can find several electrical equipment service centers for repairing refrigerators and
air conditioners of various brands and models. Similarly there are several service centers for
handling automobiles from different manufacturers. The cost and the quality of the service vary
across such service centers and consumers choose the ones that meet their s ervice requirements
and budget constraints. We model our service market similar to the above scenario. The service
market for the P has s everal small independent s ervice providers, who provide the service at a
cost that depends on the quality of the service. At any given point of time, a consumer would
choose a service provider who meets her service requirements and cost constraint.
Let w be the total cost a consumer is willing to pay for servicing the product during
its lifetime. We model the variation in consumer’s willing to pay for the service by assuming
w to be uniformly distributed in range [W , W ]. The w denotes a consumer’s willingness to
pay (WTP) for the lifetime service. This total spend for the service is distributed across the
lifetime of the product and possibly across many service providers. The service providers service
similar products produced by different manufacturers. We do not assume the independent
service providers to be strategic players in the market. This is because the independent service
providers do not service the product for its entire lifetime for a previously agreed up on cost. Thus
a manufacturer need not take into account the cost of service of the independent service providers
for making his strategic decisions. However, the presence of such independent service providers
ensures that a consumer will always be able to avail the service for her WTP w [W , W ] for
the lifetime. A consumer can thus choose to buy the service from the manufacturer or can avail
it across different independent service providers during the lifetime.
3.2 Manufacturing Firm and the Consumers
The marginal c ost of producing the product is assumed to be a c onstant c
P
. For a manufac-
turing firm (henceforth referred simply as firm) to survive in such a market, the cost c
P
v
and the price of the product α should be such that c
P
α v. Let the constant marginal cost
of providing the lifetime service for the firm be c
S
[W , W ]. If the firm provides the lifetime
service for price β, then all the consumers with WTP w β will buy the service from the
manufacturer for the entire product lifetime. This is b e cause the quality of service provided by
the manufacturer can be assumed to be higher than any of the independent service provider and
hence the consumers with w β would prefer the service from the manufacturer directly. The
WTP w and the price β are money values for the service that is provided during the lifetime of
the product. Since the money value would change during the lifetime of the product, they are
assumed to be suitably discounted using a common discounting factor for both the manufacturer
and consumers. This assumption of common discount factor for both manufacturers and con-
5

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a systematic literature review is conducted related to understanding implementation of Product-Service Systems business models and five sets of tactical practices, including contracts, marketing, networks, product and service design, and sustainability operational practices.

613 citations

Book
01 Jan 1992

222 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors explore the interaction of these two after-sales services assuming two customer segments, and find that aftersales service plans that are determined to maximize profits do not match optimal after-Sales service levels that can satisfy customers the most.

133 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A multi-objective genetic algorithm has been applied to simultaneously optimize service period and product EOL decisions and a case study of a notebook market is provided to show the applications of the model.
Abstract: Sustainable product service system (S-PSS) regarded as an evolution of existing product development approaches which incorporates services as well as products for achieving sustainable development. Therefore, several IT manufacturers around the world have developed plans for fulfilling consumer's needs by providing a combination of product and services and also management of product at the end of its life (EOL). Hence, it is essential to develop an analytical model that can help manufacturers to analyze their S-PSS plans. We model both optimization of environmental and economical impacts of the product during consumption and end of life phase from point of view of the consumer and manufacturer. A multi-objective genetic algorithm has been applied to simultaneously optimize service period and product EOL decisions. Finally, a case study of a notebook market is provided to show the applications of the model.

56 citations


Cites background from "Bundling and pricing of product wit..."

  • ...Kameshwaran et al. (2009) analyzed the product-service integration....

    [...]

  • ...…Thurston (2002) Reliability indicator Producer Mathematical Warranty /EOL Zhao et al. (2010) Reliability indicator Producer Mathematical Warranty /EOL Kameshwaran et al. (2009) Producer Game theory Product/services price Hanafiah et al. (2003) Producer Simulation Consumption Problem definition and…...

    [...]

References
More filters
Book ChapterDOI
TL;DR: In this article, it was shown that the set of equilibrium points of a two-person zero-sum game can be defined as a set of all pairs of opposing "good" strategies.
Abstract: we would call cooperative. This theory is based on an analysis of the interrelationships of the various coalitions which can be formed by the players of the game. Our theory, in contradistinction, is based on the absence of coalitions in that it is assumed that each participant acts independently, without collaboration or communication with any of the others. The notion of an equilibrium point is the basic ingredient in our theory. This notion yields a generalization of the concept of the solution of a two-person zerosum game. It turns out that the set of equilibrium points of a two-person zerosum game is simply the set of all pairs of opposing "good strategies." In the immediately following sections we shall define equilibrium points and prove that a finite non-cooperative game always has at least one equilibrium point. We shall also introduce the notions of solvability and strong solvability of a non-cooperative game and prove a theorem on the geometrical structure of the set of equilibrium points of a solvable game. As an example of the application of our theory we include a solution of a

6,577 citations


"Bundling and pricing of product wit..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Such an equilibrium is a pair of strategies that constitutes a Nash equilibrium (NE) (Nash, 1951) in each pricing game as well as in the full game....

    [...]

Book
01 Jan 1983
TL;DR: Stigler's "The Organization of Industry" as mentioned in this paper collects essays written over two decades, previously unpublished material, and reprinted articles drawn from numerous sources, many which include additional commentary by the author.
Abstract: "The Organization of Industry" collects essays written over two decades-pieces prepared especially for this volume, previously unpublished material, and reprinted articles drawn from numerous sources, many which include additional commentary by the author. The essays are unified by George J. Stigler's careful analysis and by his clear and witty style. In part one, Stigler examines the nature of competition and monopoly. In part two he discusses the forces that determine the size structure of industry, including barriers to entry, economics of scale, and mergers. Part three contains articles on a wide range of topics, such as profitability, delivered price systems, block booking, the economics of information, and the kinky oligopoly demand curve and rigid price. Part four offers a discussion of antitrust policy and includes Stigler's recommendations for future policy as well as an examination of the effects of past policies. "Stigler's writings might well be subtitled 'The Joys of Doing Economics.' He, more than any other contemporary American economist, dispels the gloom surrounding economic theory. It is impossible to confront the subject treated with such humor and verve and come away still believing that economics is the dismal science."-Shirley B. Johnson, "American Scholar "

1,922 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors analyzed the prevalence of commodity bundling as a marketing strategy and found that it can save cost savings in production, transactions, and information associated with bundling.
Abstract: Presents information on a study which analyzed the prevalence of commodity bundling as a marketing strategy. Cost savings in production, transactions and information associated with commodity bundling; Characteristics of commodity bundling; Problems associated with convention price discrimination that can overcome by commodity bundling; Conclusions. (Из Ebsco)

1,433 citations


"Bundling and pricing of product wit..." refers background or methods in this paper

  • ...Bundling was suggested as an alternative technique for price discrimination for monopolists (Stigler, 1968), which was further analyzed in (Adams and Yellen, 1976)....

    [...]

  • ..., 1996); optimality of bundling for monopolists (Adams and Yellen, 1976; Schmalensee, 1982); and equilibrium theory of bundling (Chen, 1997)....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: The Organization of Industry as discussed by the authors collects essays written over two decades by George J. Stigler, who examined the nature of competition and monopoly, and the forces that determine the size structure of industry, including barriers to entry, economics of scale and mergers.
Abstract: The Organization of Industry collects essays written over two decades—pieces prepared especially for this volume, previously unpublished material, and reprinted articles drawn from numerous sources, many which include additional commentary by the author. The essays are unified by George J. Stigler's careful analysis and by his clear and witty style. In part one, Stigler examines the nature of competition and monopoly. In part two he discusses the forces that determine the size structure of industry, including barriers to entry, economics of scale, and mergers. Part three contains articles on a wide range of topics, such as profitability, delivered price systems, block booking, the economics of information, and the kinky oligopoly demand curve and rigid price. Part four offers a discussion of antitrust policy and includes Stigler's recommendations for future policy as well as an examination of the effects of past policies. "Stigler's writings might well be subtitled 'The Joys of Doing Economics.' He, more than any other contemporary American economist, dispels the gloom surrounding economic theory. It is impossible to confront the subject treated with such humor and verve and come away still believing that economics is the dismal science."—Shirley B. Johnson, American Scholar

1,310 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, Adams and Yellen show that bundling can serve as a useful price discrimination device, even when all consumers' willingnesses to pay for each of the goods individually are unaffected by whether they are also consuming the other product.
Abstract: Through what selling strategy can a multiproduct monopolist maximize his profits when his knowledge about individual consumers' preferences is limited? One possibility, extensively studied in the context of a single-good monopoly, is to use quantity-dependent pricing as a means of discriminating among customers with differing tastes (see, for example, Oi [1971] and Maskin and Riley [1984]). An alternative technique for price discrimination, first suggested by Stigler [1968] and analyzed further by Adams and Yellen [1976], is for the monopolist to package two or more products in bundles rather than selling them separately.' Through a series of examples Adams and Yellen illustrate that bundling can serve as a useful price discrimination device, even when all consumers' willingnesses to pay for each of the goods individually are unaffected by whether they are also consuming the other product. A typical example is illustrated in Figure I (adapted from Figure IV in Adams and Yellen), where there are two goods, three consumers (AB,C) who consume at most one unit of each good (with reservation values for each good that are independent of whether the other good is consumed), and zero costs of production. There, a bundle offered at a price of 100 fully extracts all potential surplus, which would be impossible pricing the goods independently. Unfortunately, though, these authors do not provide any general characterization of the circumstances in which bundling is actually a multiproduct monopolist's optimal strategy. Their examples, however (such as Figure I), create the impression that the profitable use of bundling

866 citations


"Bundling and pricing of product wit..." refers background in this paper

  • ...The conditions under which bundling is an optimal strategy was investigated in (McAfee et al., 1989) for a multiproduct monopolist....

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Bundling and pricing of product with after-sale services" ?

In this paper the authors consider the bundling and pricing of a complex durable product with the after-sales repair and maintenance services.