scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Comparing early warning systems for banking crises

01 Jun 2008-Journal of Financial Stability (Brunel University)-Vol. 4, Iss: 2, pp 89-120
TL;DR: In this article, the authors assess the logit and signal extraction EWS for banking crises on a comprehensive common dataset and suggest that logit is the most appropriate approach for global EWS and signal extractor for country-specific EWS.
About: This article is published in Journal of Financial Stability.The article was published on 2008-06-01 and is currently open access. It has received 472 citations till now. The article focuses on the topics: Warning system.

Summary (3 min read)

1 Theoretical overview of banking crises.

  • This section briefly indicates why the indicators used in EWS models such as Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (1998) (who use the logit method) are associated with banking crises.
  • This may link to asymmetric information as if one significant bank fails, a systemic crisis may develop because the presence of such asymmetric information means depositors are unable to evaluate prospects for similar banks in terms of balance-sheet exposure to economy wide systemic risks (Kaufman and Scott, 2003).
  • Accordingly, macroeconomic movements that crystallise risks particular to banking systems, namely interest rate, credit, liquidity and market risk have been the key determinants of banking crises in the last twenty years (Ergungor and Thompson, 2005).
  • Alternatively, excessive market risk may be borne during boom phases, as over-optimism may concentrate portfolios in assets whose prices move procyclically, e.g. real estate (Gonzalez-Hermosillo, 1999, Craig et al 2005).
  • Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (1998) include this variable because it indicates governments reluctance to restructure fragile banking systems and because high deficits prevent successful financial liberalisation.

2 Data, variables and specifications

  • The most commonly-cited problem with EWS developed to date is the inconsistency in the banking crisis dependent variable, which is necessarily defined with a degree of subjectivity (Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999; Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache 1998, Eichengreen and Arteta, 2000).
  • The problem lies in the fact that banking crisis is an event, so proxies for banking crises would not necessarily be perfectly correlated with banking crises themselves.
  • Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) note that crises can also be dated too early, since the worst of the crisis could unfold after the subjective start date.

2.2 The Data Sample

  • The dataset of independent variables mimics the Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (1998) approach, utilising most of their variables but for a wider selection of countries and for a longer time span.
  • The authors have used the same data source they cite: IFS and World Bank Development Indicators to obtain annual data; full data sources are obtainable in DemirgucKunt and Detragiache (1998).
  • Under the DD05 dating this yields 72 systemic crisis episodes; under the less stringent CK03 definitions this yields 102 systemic crisis episodes.
  • As explained in Part 1, the explanatory variables chosen are macroeconomic, financial and financial liberalisation indicators of crisis.
  • 16 They find the results do not change significantly either way.

3.3 Improving the Model Further: Investigating Dynamics.

  • To model the dynamics of banking crises, the authors now introduce further lags and several interaction variables so that they use the data to mimic the procyclical build up of risk.
  • The authors banking crisis story unfolds as follows: credit booms are more likely to occur in an environment which allows imprudent lending, such as following the adoption of deposit insurance.
  • This may be tempered if agents are not so reliant on bank intermediation for funds when deposit insurance is installed.
  • The results in table 7 clearly show the procyclical behaviour of credit growth.
  • From three years prior to crisis, a cyclical downturn 24 seems to occur with the coefficient sign switching so that credit rationing increases the likelihood of crisis.

3.3 In Sample Predictive Ability

  • The authors now turn to see the relative performances of the different specifications in terms of their ability to accurately call crises and non-crises episodes.
  • The authors initially set their threshold much higher than Demirguc-Kunt and Detragiache (1998) who set their cut off probability at 0.0519.
  • In contrast the authors set their threshold at 0.5, arguing that from the policy maker s perspective, costly intervention on the basis of a crude EWS should be avoided unless the model seriously calls a crisis (table 8a).
  • Their models out-perform the DD05 models in terms of crisis prediction (apart from regressions 1 and 2).the authors.
  • This may be due to the wider definitions of crisis that CK03 use so that the CK03 dummy is associated with a reduced ability to call non-crisis periods correctly and therefore a higher chance of Type II errors.

3.5 Furthering the Signal Extraction Approach: Composite Indicators

  • Borio and Lothe authors (2002) developed the Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999) procedure by constructing composite indicators22 to extract signals of banking crisis.
  • In their case, the authors set stronger criteria; they first construct a composite indicator using variables that have a noise to signal ratio of 0.5 or less and then they construct composites using variables where the ratio is 0.75 or less.
  • For the 0.75 cut-off the authors construct two composites based on the general and country specific approaches.
  • The composite method therefore appears to improve crisis prediction whether a country specific or general threshold approach is used but this occurs at the cost of higher Type II errors.
  • Conversely, the specific threshold approach which already yields low Type I errors benefits from the composite method so that the composite specific threshold approach lowers the NTSR below that of virtually all the univariate indicators with the same methodology.

3.6 Comparison of the Signal Extraction and Multivariate Logit Models.

  • On the basis of in-sample predictive ability, the multivariate logit model outperforms the signal extraction approach in terms of the percentage of crises correctly predicted.
  • With the signal extraction approach, every indicator misses a substantial number of crises.
  • If the NTSR jumps at different threshold for different countries, then using cross-country data to derive a common threshold may not be fruitful; the threshold that minimises the NTSR will fall on either side of the individual optimal thresholds for most countries.
  • An alternative approach to ours would be the Borio and Lothe authors (2002) methodology where individual variable thresholds are jointly evaluated.
  • Composite indicator ability to predict crises is more comparable to the multivariate logit model than the univariate signal extraction procedure so the two procedures could be compared on the same dataset.

4 Conclusion

  • A comparison of the multinomial logit and signal extraction procedures shows that real GDP growth and terms of trade are robust leading indicators of banking crisis for their comprehensive sample.
  • Creating composite indicators may further improve crisis prediction.
  • Systemic Banking Crises , Policy Discussion Papers, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Number 9, February 2005.
  • Finance and Development, Volume 36, Number 2, IMF Publications, Washington.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Citations
More filters
Book
01 Jan 2009

8,216 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The recent financial crisis has highlighted the need to go beyond a purely micro approach to financial regulation and supervision and the number of policy speeches, research papers and conferences that discuss a macro perspective on financial regulation has grown considerably.
Abstract: The recent financial crisis has highlighted the need to go beyond a purely micro approach to financial regulation and supervision. As a consequence, the number of policy speeches, research papers and conferences that discuss a macro perspective on financial regulation has grown considerably. The policy debate is focusing in particular on macroprudential tools and their usage, their relationship with monetary policy, their implementation and their effectiveness. Macroprudential policy has recently also attracted considerable attention among researchers. This paper provides an overview of research on this topic. We also identify important future research questions that emerge from both the literature and the current policy debate.

732 citations


Cites background from "Comparing early warning systems for..."

  • ...Hutchinson and McDill, 1999; Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999; Bell and Pain, 2000; Demirguç-Kunt and Detriagache, 2005; Davis and Karim, 2008; Dell’Arricia et al., 2008; Von Hagen and Ho, 2007. The large body of studies on early warning indicators of currency crises (e.g. Kaminsky et al, 1998) is beyond the scope of this paper. 18 Surveys of the macro stress testing literature are provided by Sorge (2004) and Drehmann (2009). 19 Recent work by Aikman et al (2009) is an important exception....

    [...]

  • ...See, for example, Hutchinson and McDill (1999), Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999), Bell and Pain (2000), Demirguç-Kunt and Detriagache (2005), Davis and Karim (2008), Dell’Arricia et al. (2008) and Von Hagen and Ho (2007)....

    [...]

  • ...Hutchinson and McDill, 1999; Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999; Bell and Pain, 2000; Demirguç-Kunt and Detriagache, 2005; Davis and Karim, 2008; Dell’Arricia et al., 2008; Von Hagen and Ho, 2007. The large body of studies on early warning indicators of currency crises (e.g. Kaminsky et al, 1998) is beyond the scope of this paper. 18 Surveys of the macro stress testing literature are provided by Sorge (2004) and Drehmann (2009)....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the out-of-sample performance of leading indicators of banking system distress, developed in previous work, also extended to incorporate explicitly property prices, was investigated and found that they are fairly successful in providing a signal for several banking systems currently in distress, including that of the United States.
Abstract: Historically, unusually strong increases in credit and asset prices have tended to precede banking crises. Could the current crisis have been anticipated by exploiting this relationship? We explore this question by assessing the out-of-sample performance of leading indicators of banking system distress developed in previous work, also extended to incorporate explicitly property prices. We find that they are fairly successful in providing a signal for several banking systems currently in distress, including that of the United States. We also consider the complications that arise in calibrating the indicators as a result of cross-border exposures, so prominent in the current episode.

546 citations


Cites background from "Comparing early warning systems for..."

  • ...For recent surveys, see Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache (2005) and Davis and Karim (2008a). Davis and Karim (2008b) examine whether different early warning indicators developed by them could have predicted the current crises but find them not to be successful. Alessi and Detken (2008) propose real-time indicators for costly asset price booms and find that some specifications would have issued persistent warning signals prior to the current crisis....

    [...]

  • ...For recent surveys, see Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache (2005) and Davis and Karim (2008a). Davis and Karim (2008b) examine whether different early warning indicators developed by them could have predicted the current crises but find them not to be successful....

    [...]

  • ...For recent surveys, see Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache (2005) and Davis and Karim (2008a)....

    [...]

  • ...Davis and Karim (2008b) examine whether different early warning indicators developed by them could have predicted the current crises but find them not to be successful....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors investigate whether leading indicators can help explain the cross-country incidence of the 2008-09 financial crisis. But they find that indicators found to be useful predictors in one round of crises are typically not useful to predict the next round.

422 citations


Cites background from "Comparing early warning systems for..."

  • ...Bruggemann and Linne (1999), and Osband and Rijckeghem (2000); and Goldfajn and Valdes (1998), Esquivel and Larrain (1998), Apoteker and Barthelemy (2000), and Rose and Spiegel (forthcoming); Rose and Spiegel, 2010, 2011)....

    [...]

  • ...5Includes Berg et al. (2005); Manasse and Roubini (2009), Shimpalee and Boucher Breuer (2006), Davis and Karim (2008), Berkmen et al. (2009), Obstfeld et al. (2009), Rose and Spiegel (forthcoming)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors found that higher capital adequacy and liquidity ratios have a marked effect on the crisis probabilities, implying long-run benefits to offset some of the costs that such regulations may impose.
Abstract: Early warning systems (EWS) for banking crises generally omit bank capital, bank liquidity and property prices. Most work on EWS has been for global samples dominated by emerging market crises where time series data on bank capital adequacy and property prices are typically absent. We estimate logit crisis models for OECD countries, finding strong effects from capital adequacy and liquidity ratios as well as property prices, and can exclude traditional variables. Higher capital adequacy and liquidity ratios have a marked effect on the crisis probabilities, implying long-run benefits to offset some of the costs that such regulations may impose.

321 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors discuss the problem of estimating the sampling distribution of a pre-specified random variable R(X, F) on the basis of the observed data x.
Abstract: We discuss the following problem given a random sample X = (X 1, X 2,…, X n) from an unknown probability distribution F, estimate the sampling distribution of some prespecified random variable R(X, F), on the basis of the observed data x. (Standard jackknife theory gives an approximate mean and variance in the case R(X, F) = \(\theta \left( {\hat F} \right) - \theta \left( F \right)\), θ some parameter of interest.) A general method, called the “bootstrap”, is introduced, and shown to work satisfactorily on a variety of estimation problems. The jackknife is shown to be a linear approximation method for the bootstrap. The exposition proceeds by a series of examples: variance of the sample median, error rates in a linear discriminant analysis, ratio estimation, estimating regression parameters, etc.

14,483 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors showed that bank deposit contracts can provide allocations superior to those of exchange markets, offering an explanation of how banks subject to runs can attract deposits, and showed that there are circumstances when government provision of deposit insurance can produce superior contracts.
Abstract: This paper shows that bank deposit contracts can provide allocations superior to those of exchange markets, offering an explanation of how banks subject to runs can attract deposits. Investors face privately observed risks which lead to a demand for liquidity. Traditional demand deposit contracts which provide liquidity have multiple equilibria, one of which is a bank run. Bank runs in the model cause real economic damage, rather than simply reflecting other problems. Contracts which can prevent runs are studied, and the analysis shows that there are circumstances when government provision of deposit insurance can produce superior contracts.

9,099 citations


"Comparing early warning systems for..." refers background in this paper

  • ...In the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model, liquidity risk drives idiosyncratic bank runs. Liquidity risk also links to adverse information models of banking crises (Santos, 2000). Chari and Jagannathan (1988) modify the Diamond and Dybvig model to show that when depositors assimilate adverse information (e.g. signals of recession or asset market collapses) they anticipate that bank profitability will suffer. Resulting bank runs generate systemic liquidity problems. These runs are distinct from the Diamond and Dybvig model where runs on solvent banks occur even when depositors have no legitimate evidence to suspect insolvency. Rather, in this case, depositors are more likely to run on genuinely insolvent banks. Hence Gorton’s (1988) observation that panics are associated with recessions and Jacklin and Bhattacharya’s (1988) suggestion that the release of information indicating low asset values or poor performance of a bank can generate liquidity risk....

    [...]

  • ...Diamond and Dybvig (1983) emphasised the role of confidence in precipitating runs and that arbitrary shifts in investors risk expectations explain seemingly irrational behaviour of consumers running on banks; a bank s underlying financial position is almost irrelevant once panic ensues....

    [...]

  • ...In the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model, liquidity risk drives idiosyncratic bank runs....

    [...]

  • ...Diamond and Dybvig (1983) emphasised the role of confidence in precipitating runs and that arbitrary shifts in investors’ risk expectations explain seemingly irrational behaviour of consumers running on banks; a bank’s underlying financial position is almost irrelevant once panic ensues....

    [...]

  • ...In the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model, liquidity risk drives idiosyncratic bank runs. Liquidity risk also links to adverse information models of banking crises (Santos, 2000). Chari and Jagannathan (1988) modify the Diamond and Dybvig model to show that when depositors assimilate adverse information (e....

    [...]

Book
01 Jan 2009

8,216 citations


"Comparing early warning systems for..." refers background in this paper

  • ...To directly compare the individual contributions of each variable to crisis, their marginal effects can be computed for their mean values (Greene, 2000) or at a specific year before a crisis unfolds....

    [...]

Book
01 Jan 1973
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a theory of economic development very different from the "stages of growth" hypothesis or strategies emphasizing foreign aid, trade, or regional association, focusing on the use of domestic capital markets to stimulate economic performance.
Abstract: This books presents a theory of economic development very different from the "stages of growth" hypothesis or strategies emphasizing foreign aid, trade, or regional association. Leaving these aside, the author breaks new ground by focusing on the use of domestic capital markets to stimulate economic performance. He suggests a "bootstrap" approach in which successful development would depend largely on policy choices made by national authorities in the developing countries themselves.Central to his theory is the freeing of domestic financial markets to allow interest rates to reflect the true scarcity of capital in a developing economy. His analysis leads to a critique of prevailing monetary theory and to a new view of the relation between money and physical capitala view with policy implications for governments striving to overcome the vicious circle of inflation and stagnation. Examining the performance of South Korea, Taiwan, Brazil, and other countries, the author suggests that their success or failure has depended primarily on steps taken in the monetary sector. He concludes that monetary reform should take precedence over other development measures, such as tariff and tax reform or the encouragement of foreign capital investment. In addition to challenging much of the conventional wisdom of development, the author's revision of accepted monetary theory may be relevant for mature economies that face monetary problems."

5,494 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors analyzes the links between banking and currency crises and finds that problems in the banking sector typically precede a currency crisis, activating a vicious spiral; financial liberalization often precedes banking crises.
Abstract: In the wake of the Mexican and Asian currency turmoil, the subject of financial crises has come to the forefront of academic and policy discussions. This paper analyzes the links between banking and currency crises. We find that: problems in the banking sector typically precede a currency crisis--the currency crisis deepens the banking crisis, activating a vicious spiral; financial liberalization often precedes banking crises. The anatomy of these episodes suggests that crises occur as the economy enters a recession, following a prolonged boom in economic activity that was fueled by credit, capital inflows and accompanied by an overvalued currency.

4,442 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (16)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Comparing early warning systems for banking crisis" ?

In this context, the authors assess the logit and signal extraction EWS for banking crises on a comprehensive common dataset. The authors suggest that logit is the most appropriate approach for global EWS and signal extraction for country specific EWS. Furthermore it is important to consider the policy maker’s objectives when designing predictive models and setting related thresholds since there is a sharp trade-off between correctly calling crises and false alarms. 

4. Since these two approaches have been shown to favour Type I and Type II errors differently, the authors wish to see if this behaviour persists when they construct composites. 

Macroeconomic shocks which could trigger cyclical downturns thereby increasing NPLs include adverse movements in terms of trade and correspondingly currency depreciations, especially for small open economies. 

macroeconomic movements that crystallise risks particular to banking systems, namely interest rate, credit, liquidity and market risk have been the key determinants of banking crises in the last twenty years (Ergungor and Thompson, 2005). 

Because asymmetric information becomes disproportionately important for loan officers, lending spreads are artificially high and intermediaries hold excess capital and provisions. 

In liberalised markets, increased competition may erode bank charter values so that without adequate supervision and regulation, banks forgo prudent credit risk assessment in a bid to catch borrowers. 

For Kaminsky and Reinhart (1999), real interest rates are able to call 100% of crises correctly whilst domestic credit/ GDP is able to call 50% of crises correctly. 

Although banks enjoy advantages in screening and monitoring borrowers, both of which reduce credit risk, the high levels of NPLs associated with crises indicate risk assessment by banks deteriorates during pre-crisis periods. 

Asymmetric information does not restrict credit availability because bank managers succumb to euphoric and herding behaviour7, utilising biased information sets to make investment decisions. 

They stipulate that non-performing loans as a proportion of entire loans of the banking system must be in the range of 5 10% or less. 

during booms, banks may use low-cost deposit financing to invest heavily in particular sectors which appear profitable and where collateral values are high. 

Their banking crisis story unfolds as follows: credit booms are more likely to occur in an environment which allows imprudent lending, such as following the adoption of deposit insurance. 

Berg and Pattillo (1999) suggest this is because the signal extraction process assumes that a threshold for a variable is a discrete value and that whenever this is crossed, a crisis becomes impending. 

The fact that the interaction terms are significant (with credit growth alone insignificant) also demonstrates how moral hazard is more prevalent when deposit insurance exists so that credit booms generate considerable banking crisis risk. 

The safety net of deposit insurance significantly raises the likelihood of morally hazardous lending by banks, which adds to the crisis probability. 

Since credit risk is also procyclical, the link between the two risks becomes apparent when asset price collapses realise market risk and low collateral values realise credit risk.