scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Fiscal policy and default risk in emerging markets

01 Apr 2010-Review of Economic Dynamics (Academic Press)-Vol. 13, Iss: 2, pp 452-469
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors developed a quantitative dynamic stochastic small open economy model with incomplete markets, endogenous fiscal policy and sovereign default where public expenditures and tax rates are optimally procyclical.
About: This article is published in Review of Economic Dynamics.The article was published on 2010-04-01 and is currently open access. It has received 127 citations till now. The article focuses on the topics: Fiscal policy & Sovereign default.

Summary (4 min read)

1. Introduction

  • The authors study theoretically and quantitatively the links and cyclical behavior of fiscal variables, sovereign interest rate spreads and default risk in emerging market economies.
  • A procyclical fiscal policy implies public spending and tax rates in good (bad) times.
  • Sovereign debt crises usually take place in bad times, when output growth is low or even negative.
  • Section 6 discusses the robustness of the benchmark results to different assumptions regarding the economic environment.
  • The impact of the private sector’s access to international credit markets on the behavior of fiscal variables is studied in Section 7, where the authors develop and compute a finite horizon model where both the government and the private sector have access to foreign financing.

3. The Benchmark Model

  • The authors consider a small open economy model with three agents: households, government and foreign lenders.
  • Households have preferences over private consumption, public 4See Peter (2002) for a survey of econometric studies on the probability of sovereign default.
  • They work and consume, taking as given the actions of the government.
  • Goods are produced using labor and the production function has constant returns to scale and is subject to technology shocks.
  • Foreign lenders charge a premium to account for the probability of not being paid back by the government.

3.1. Households

  • There is a representative household with preferences given by the present value of the sum of instantaneous utility functions: E0 ∞X t=0 βtU(Ct, Gt, 1− lt) (3.1).
  • The per period utility is concave, strictly increasing and twice differentiable.
  • Gt public spending and lt the amount of time allocated to produce goods.
  • Output is produced using labor 5Most external debt in developing countries represents government debt.
  • From households’ first order conditions the authors get the following equation, describing optimal behavior of the private sector.

3.2. Government

  • The benevolent government maximizes the utility of the households in the economy and can borrow and lend in international credit markets.
  • When the government borrows, it sells bonds to foreign lenders, so it receives q(B0, A)B0 units of consumption goods from foreign creditors on the current period and promises to pay B0 units next period conditional on not defaulting.
  • When the government has access to credit markets it chooses the tax rate, public expenditures and foreign assets in order to maximize households’ utility, taking into account how the private sector will respond to these policies.
  • The productivity factor 7The assumption that default reduces output can be rationalized by the fact that after a default episode there is a disruption in foreign trade, Rose (2005), which induces an output loss.
  • A0).

3.3. Foreign Lenders

  • There is a large number of identical, infinitely lived foreign creditors.
  • Each lender can borrow or lend at the risk free rate rf and participates in a perfectly competitive market to lend to the small open economy.
  • Next period the lenders may receive the face value of the bond depending on whether the government defaults or not.
  • Policy functions for government’s default decision D, optimal asset holdings B0, optimal government expenditures G, Gd and optimal tax rates T , Td, 4.
  • Given the government policies and the bond price function, the household policies for consumption and labor solve the household’s problem, 2.

4.2. First Order Conditions from Government’s Problem

  • This condition can be interpreted in terms of marginal benefits and marginal costs of changing the tax rate.
  • If households react working less hours when the government implements a higher tax rate, then the amount of resources that can be assigned to public expenditures would be reduced.
  • The marginal benefits and costs can be described as follows:.
  • In terms of effects on current welfare, for each unit of additional borrowing the government could increase the level of public spending by q+B0 ∂q∂B0 − TAFl(l ∗) (1+T ) ∂l ∂B0 units.
  • Next period, the government would have to repay its debt, which reduces future government consumption.

5. Quantitative Analysis

  • The benchmark model is solved numerically and the parameters are based on existing data.
  • Given the availability of time series of data, Mexico is used as a benchmark and their period of study is 1980-2007.
  • Many of the business cycles features observed in Mexico are shared by other emerging market economies.

5.1. Data

  • The data are seasonally adjusted quarterly real series obtained from Banco de Mexico.
  • Output, private consumption and public consumption are in logs and the trade balance is presented as a percentage of GDP.
  • An effective tax rate was computed for the consumption tax using the methodology of Mendoza, Razin and Tesar (1994).
  • The interest rate spreads corresponds to the EMBI for 1994-2007.
  • All series are filtered with the Hodrick-Prescott filter.

5.2. Calibration

  • The calibration involves choosing the functional forms and the parameter values.
  • The household’s labor supply depends on the productivity factor, the tax rate and the parameter Ψ of the per period utility.
  • Some of the parameter values that are used are standard for business cycles models in emerging markets.
  • The parameter σ, the coefficient of relative risk aversion, is set equal to 2, a standard value (see Aguiar and Gopinath 2006).
  • This value implies that a defaulting country will return to financial markets in about 10 quarters after defaulting on its foreign debt.

5.3. Results

  • This section presents the simulation results and the statistical properties of the benchmark model.
  • Figure 1 plots the discount bond price schedule as a function of assets for two values of the productivity shock.
  • Therefore, in the middle of a recession, a highly indebted govern- 26 ment losses access to credit markets and it has to finance its expenditures with taxes.
  • When the amount of foreign debt is low and the government always pays back its debt, the country faces the risk free interest rate and the optimal tax rate increases with A.
  • Therefore, in this region the economy borrows more in recessions and less in expansions as in standard insurance models with borrowing constraints a la Hugget (1993).

6. Discussion

  • In this section the authors conduct a robustness check of the benchmark results.
  • The authors first analyze the role of default in the model.
  • Now, the optimal cyclical pattern for borrowing and tax rates, imply a slightly positive correlation of these variables with GDP.
  • As the numbers in the table show, the qualitative results stand and overall results do not change significantly.
  • As the goods become more complements the government tends to implement a larger tax to redistribute the resources according to the optimal allocation between C and G.

7. The Model with private foreign borrowing

  • The assumption that households cannot borrow directly from credit markets is in conflict with the increased participation of the private sector’s debt in the overall bond issuance by emerging markets documented by the IMF (IMF Financial Stability Report (2007), Copelman (1996)).
  • At the same time, the aggregate figures on private foreign borrowing conceal a significant cross country heterogeneity: while private foreign borrowing in countries like Estonia or Thailand is significant relative to public foreign borrowing, for a large number of developing countries it is almost exclusively the government that has access to international credit markets.
  • Lahiri, Singh and Vegh (2007) observe that in general, access to asset markets is limited to a fraction of the population, and even in the US the degree of segmentation in asset markets is remarkably high.
  • They point out that as of 1989, almost 60% of US households did not hold any interest bearing assets (defined as money market accounts, certificates of deposit, bonds, mutual funds, and equities) and 25% did not even have a checking account.
  • This stylized fact is analyzed in numerous empirical studies such as Durbin and Ng (2005), Borensztein, Cowan and Valenzuela (2007) and Peter and Grandes (2005) among others.

7.1. Results

  • The government does not have commitment to long-run plans and chooses taxes (τ), debt (B) and default (D) before the private sector decides on debt (b), and default (d).
  • Therefore, the authors first present the last period problem.
  • Likewise, suppose in the second period the government decided to default on its debt and to set taxes at τ .
  • Additionally, the term I(d=0)qg(b,B, y)B0 indicates that in case of default in the private sector, the government is also excluded from credit markets.
  • The policy functions used in the simulations below are those that solve the first period problem.

7.2. Simulations

  • The value for the common parameters, stochastic processes and functional forms are taken from the benchmark model.
  • Different values of the parameters determining the output loss after default must be considered.
  • To follow the concept of “sovereign credit ceiling” observed in the data, the authors set λp slightly higher than λg.13 Last, if both sectors default, they assume the punishment is harder, λb = 0.97.
  • In the last column, the correlations were computed from time series simulated using the policy functions defined above.
  • At the same time, since the cost of private borrowing also increases in recessions due to countercyclical credit risk, the private sector also faces procyclical borrowing and is constrained in bad times, so private debt is not a good instrument to smooth consumption.

8. Conclusions

  • In this paper the authors help rationalize the observed procyclicality of fiscal policy in emerging economies as the outcome of optimal public policy.
  • The results are also consistent with other key stylized facts present in emerging market 14 In computing those correlations, each point y was weighted by the measure of y in the stationary distribution of income.
  • Since non-contingent debt is not a good instrument for consumption smoothing, public expenditures fluctuate.
  • When the economy faces a fall in output but the government does not default, it has the option to borrow from abroad but at a high interest rate.
  • Therefore, complementing the previous literature that focused on the loss of market access, the authors find that the possibility of sovereign default and the associated risk premium play an important role in inducing the procyclical fiscal policy observed in emerging economies.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors build a dataset on tax rates for 62 countries for the period 1960-2013 that comprises corporate income, personal income, and value-added tax rates and find that tax policy is a cyclical in industrial countries but mostly procyclical in developing countries.
Abstract: It is well known by now that government spending has typically been procyclical in developing economies but a cyclical or countercyclical in industrial countries. Little, if any, is known, however, about the cyclical behavior of tax rates (as opposed to tax revenues, which are endogenous to the business cycle and hence cannot shed light on the cyclicality of tax policy). The authors build a novel dataset on tax rates for 62 countries for the period 1960-2013 that comprises corporate income, personal income, and value-added tax rates. The authors find that, by and large, tax policy is a cyclical in industrial countries but mostly procyclical in developing countries. Further, tax policy in countries with better institutions and or more integrated with world capital markets tends to be less procyclical or more countercyclical.

142 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors extend the model used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default, allowing policymakers of different types to stochastically alternate in power, and show that a default episode may be triggered by a change in the type of policymaker in office, and that such a default is likely to occur only if there is enough political stability and if policymakers encounter poor economic conditions.
Abstract: We extend the model used in recent quantitative studies of sovereign default, allowing policymakers of different types to stochastically alternate in power. We show that a default episode may be triggered by a change in the type of policymaker in office, and that such a default is likely to occur only if there is enough political stability and if policymakers encounter poor economic conditions. Under high political stability, political turnover enables the model to generate a weaker correlation between economic conditions and default decisions, a higher and more volatile spread, and lower borrowing levels after a default episode.

132 citations

Book ChapterDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors identify critical flaws in the traditional approach to evaluate debt sustainability, and examine three alternative approaches that provide useful econometric and model-simulation tools to analyze debt sustainability.
Abstract: The question of what is a sustainable public debt is paramount in the macroeconomic analysis of fiscal policy. This question is usually formulated as asking whether the outstanding public debt and its projected path are consistent with those of the government's revenues and expenditures (ie, whether fiscal solvency conditions hold). We identify critical flaws in the traditional approach to evaluate debt sustainability, and examine three alternative approaches that provide useful econometric and model-simulation tools to analyze debt sustainability. The first approach is Bohn's nonstructural empirical framework based on a fiscal reaction function that characterizes the dynamics of sustainable debt and primary balances. The second is a structural approach based on a calibrated dynamic general equilibrium framework with a fully specified fiscal sector, which we use to quantify the positive and normative effects of fiscal policies aimed at restoring fiscal solvency in response to changes in debt. The third approach deviates from the others in assuming that governments cannot commit to repay their domestic debt and can thus optimally decide to default even if debt is sustainable in terms of fiscal solvency. We use these three approaches to analyze debt sustainability in the United States and Europe after the sharp increases in public debt following the 2008 crisis, and find that all three raise serious questions about the prospects of fiscal adjustment and its consequences.

110 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors study the sovereign default model that has been used to account for the cyclical behavior of interest rates in emerging market economies and show that this method necessitates a large number of grid points to avoid generating spurious interestrate movements.
Abstract: We study the sovereign default model that has been used to account for the cyclical behavior of interest rates in emerging market economies. This model is often solved using the discrete state space technique with evenly spaced grid points. We show that this method necessitates a large number of grid points to avoid generating spurious interestrate movements. This makes the discrete state technique significantly more inefficient than using Chebyshev polynomials or cubic spline interpolation to approximate the value functions. We show that the inefficiency of the discrete state space technique is more severe for parameterizations that feature a high sensitivity of the bond price to the borrowing level for the borrowing levels that are observed more frequently in the simulations. In addition, we find that the efficiency of the discrete state space technique can be greatly improved by (i) finding the equilibrium as the limit of the equilibrium of the finite-horizon version of the model, instead of iterating separately on the value and bond price functions and (ii) concentrating grid points in asset levels at which the bond price is more sensitive to the borrowing level and in levels that are observed more often in the model simulations. Our analysis is also relevant for the study of other credit markets.

105 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors extend the traditional sovereign default framework to incorporate bankers that lend to both the government and the corporate sector, and show that when these bankers are highly exposed to government debt, a default triggers a banking crisis which leads to a corporate credit collapse and subsequently to an output decline.

93 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, a public debt theory is constructed in which the Ricardian invariance theorem is valid as a first-order proposition but where the dependence excess burden on the timing of taxation implies an optimal time path of debt issue.
Abstract: A public debt theory is constructed in which the Ricardian invariance theorem is valid as a first-order proposition but where the dependence excess burden on the timing of taxation implies an optimal time path of debt issue. A central proposition is that deficits are varied in order to maintain expected constancy in tax rates. This behavior implies a positive effect on debt issue of temporary increases in government spending (as in wartime), a countercyclical response of debt to temporary income movements, and a one-to-one effect of expected inflation on nominal debt growth. Debt issue would be invariant with the outstanding debt-income ratio and, except for a mirror effect, with the level of government spending. Hypotheses are tested on U.S. data since World War I. Results are basically in accord with the theory. It also turns out that a small set of explanatory variables can account for the principal movements in interest-bearing federal debt since the 1920s.

3,112 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, a quantitative comparison of five alternative models for the small open economy model with incomplete asset markets is presented, and the main finding of the comparison is that all models deliver virtually identical dynamics at business cycle frequencies, as measured by unconditional second moments and impulse response functions.

1,690 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors analyze an economy that lacks a strong legal-political institutional infrastructure and is populated by multiple powerful groups, and they show that a dilution in the concentration of power leads to faster growth and a less procyclical response to shocks.
Abstract: We analyze an economy that lacks a strong legal-political institutional infrastructure and is populated by multiple powerful groups. Powerful groups dynamically interact via a fiscal process that effectively allows open access to the aggregate capital stock. In equilibrium, this leads to slow economic growth and a “voracity effect,” by which a shock, such as a terms of trade windfall, perversely generates a more-than-proportionate increase in fiscal redistribution and reduces growth. We also show that a dilution in the concentration of power leads to faster growth and a less procyclical response to shocks. (JEL F43, O10, O23, O40)

1,426 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors construct an economy where agents experience uninsurable idiosyncratic endowment shocks and smooth consumption by holding a risk-free asset, and calibrate the economy and characterize equilibria computationally.

1,293 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (15)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Fiscal policy and default risk in emerging markets∗" ?

In this paper the authors develop a quantitative dynamic stochastic small open economy model with incomplete markets, endogenous fiscal policy and sovereign default where public expenditures and tax rates are optimally procyclical. 

Therefore, complementing the previous literature that focused on the loss of market access, the authors find that the possibility of sovereign default and the associated risk premium play an important role in inducing the procyclical fiscal policy observed in emerging economies. 

In low income states, borrowing is relatively expensive so the government is constrained and tax rates are raised, thus consumption decreases similarly to output and the trade balance tends to be positive. 

With incomplete markets the government is less able to smooth its consumption and the correlation between output and public consumption becomes positive. 

In terms of effects on today’s utility, a marginal increase in the tax rate affects private consumption, public spending and labor effort. 

In the presence of a series of adverse shocks, the cost of rolling over debt and financing public expenditures increases and it becomes optimal to increase consumption taxes. 

The assumption that default reduces output can be rationalized by the fact that after a default episode there is a disruption in foreign trade, Rose (2005), which induces an output loss. 

A key feature of the model to understand why the government relies more on taxes in recessions is the asset structure of the model that makes default more tempting in recessions. 

When it defaults, creditors get 0 units of the consumption good, where λ(B0, A) is the endogenous probability that the government defaults on its sovereign debt. 

Figure 5 shows the borrowing policy function B0(B,A) conditional on not defaulting, as a function of B for two values of the productivity shock. 

The parameters λb, λg, and λp represent the punishment if both default, if only the government defaults, and if only the private sector defaults, respectively. 

This value implies that a defaulting country will return to financial markets in about 10 quarters after defaulting on its foreign debt. 

Notice that V 2(b,B, y) is useful because this is the function used in the first period to compute the effect of borrowing on the utility in the second period. 

Since the private sector may borrow somewhat from abroad, it might avoid an otherwise even more drastic fall in consumption, making it less costly to tax for the government. 

The economy is excluded from credit markets in the current period but in the next one the country may regain access to external markets with an exogenous probability μ.