scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Going from Bad to Worse: Adaptation to Poor Health, Health Spending, Longevity, and the Value of Life

TL;DR: This paper sets up a a life cycle model in which individuals are subject to physiological aging, calibrate it with data from gerontology, and compare behavior and outcomes of adapting and non-adapting individuals.
Abstract: Aging humans adapt to their worsening state of health and old people are usually happier than estimated by young individuals. In this paper we investigate how adaptation to a deteriorating state of health affects health spending, life expectancy, and the value of life. We set up a a life cycle model in which individuals are subject to physiological aging, calibrate it with data from gerontology, and compare behavior and outcomes of adapting and non-adapting individuals. While adaptation generally increases the value of life (by about 2 to 5 percent), its impact on health behavior and longevity depends crucially on whether individuals are aware of their adaptive behavior.

Summary (1 min read)

1. Introduction

  • From the gerontological viewpoint, the human life cycle can be characterized as the continuous deterioration of physiological fitness.
  • The authors set up a life cycle model of human aging, in which deliberate health investments reduce the speed of aging and thus the age of death, calibrate the model with gerontological data, and compare behavior and outcomes for adapting and non-adapting individuals.
  • The authors explain the economic intuition behind these results.
  • Most importantly, health capital is a latent variable, unknown to doctors and medical scientists, a fact that confounds any serious calibration of the model.

2. The Basic Model

  • Consider an individual who derives utility from consumption and from being in good health.
  • Additionally, the optimal solution fulfils the terminal condition H(T ) = 0 and the solution for sophisticated types fulfils the terminal condition λ.
  • The table shows for naive and sophisticated types the deviation of the solution from non-adaptive types in percent.
  • Results are shown for discounted life time health expenditure, the length of life, and the value of life.
  • Naive types spend 12 percent more on health and live almost one percent longer than non-adaptive types while sophisticated types spend 28 percent less on health and their live expectancy declines by more than 2 percent.

3. Model Extensions

  • The authors next consider robustness of results with respect to extending the model to uncertain survival.
  • This approach implies that individuals assess their health and its implications for survival correctly, the only potential mistake that they make regards life time utility due to failed anticipation of adaptation to deteriorating health.
  • All other parameters are kept from the simple model.

4. Conclusion

  • Life expectancy, and the value of life.the authors.
  • While the health behavior of naive and sophisticated types differs drastically and has significant impact on their life expectancy, the authors find, perhaps surprisingly, only small differences for the experienced value of life.
  • Both naive and sophisticated types experience an about two percent higher VOL compared to non-adapting types (for which the VOL at age 20 is estimated to be $ 6.5 million).
  • Under the assumption that the retirement decision is, among other things, determined by the subjectively perceived health status, the authors would expect that adaptation to poor health leads to later retirement for sophisticated agents but not necessarily for naive agents who may actually aim at an early retirement.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Schünemann, Johannes; Strulik, Holger; Trimborn, Timo
Working Paper
Going from bad to worse: Adaptation to poor health,
health spending, longevity, and the value of life
cege Discussion Papers, No. 268
Provided in Cooperation with:
Georg August University of Göttingen, cege - Center for European, Governance and Economic
Development Research
Suggested Citation: Schünemann, Johannes; Strulik, Holger; Trimborn, Timo (2015) : Going
from bad to worse: Adaptation to poor health, health spending, longevity, and the value of life,
cege Discussion Papers, No. 268, University of Göttingen, Center for European, Governance
and Economic Development Research (cege), Göttingen
This Version is available at:
http://hdl.handle.net/10419/123284
Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.
Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
Terms of use:
Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
personal and scholarly purposes.
You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
If the documents have been made available under an Open
Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.

ISSN: 1439-2305
Number 268 – November 2015
GOING FROM BAD TO WORSE:
ADAPTATION TO POOR HEALTH,
HEALTH SPENDING, LONGEVITY, AND
THE VALUE OF LIFE
Johannes Schünemann
Holger Strulik
Timo Trimborn

Going from Bad to Worse: Adaptation to Poor Health,
Health Spending, Longevity, and the Value of Life
Johannes Sch¨unemann
, Holger Strulik
and Timo Trimborn
§
November 2015.
Abstract. Aging humans adapt to their worsening state of health and old pe opl e
are usually happier than estimated by young individuals. In this paper we investi-
gate how adaptati on to a deteriorating state of health affects health spending, life
expectancy, and the value of life. We set up a a life cycle model in which individu -
als are subject to physiological aging, calibrate it with data from gerontology, and
compare behavior and outcomes of adapti ng and non-adapting individuals. While
adaptation generally increases the value of life (by about 2 to 5 percent), it s impact
on health behavior and longevity depends crucially on whether individuals are aware
of the ir adaptive behavior.
Keywords: Health, Adaption, Aging, Longevity, Health Care Demand.
JEL: D 91, J17, J26, I12.
We would like to thank Carl-Johan Da lg a a rd , Volker Grossmann, Casper Hansen, Kla u s Prettner, and
Asger Wing en d e r for discussion and helpful comments.
University of Goettingen, Department of Economics, Platz der Goettinger Sieben 3, 37073 Goettingen,
Germany; email:
University of Goettingen, Department of Economics, Platz der Goettinger Sieben 3, 37073 Goettingen,
Germany; email: holger.strulik@wiwi. u n i- g oettingen.de.
§
University of Goettingen, Department of Economics, Platz der Goettinger Sieben 3, 37073 Goettingen,
Germany; email:

1. Introduction
From the gerontological viewpoint, the hum an life cycle can be characterized as the continu ous
deterioration of physiological fitness. Most human functions and capabilit i es are in decline
from early adulthood onwards (Case and Deaton, 2005; Skirbekk, 2004; Nai r, 2005). Human
aging, u nd er st ood as “t he intrinsic, cumulative, progressive, and deleterious loss of function that
eventually culminates in death” (Arking, 2006), has a deep foundation in evolutionary biology
(Fries, 1980; Gavrilov and Gavrilova, 1991; Robson and Kaplan, 2007) and, at the current state
of medical technology, it can at best be delayed, but not avoided. So it seems to be fortunate
that aging humans are capable to adapt to this sad state of affair s. However, at closer inspection,
doubts may arise. Couldn’t it be that quick adaptation to worsening health induces us to invest
less in health maintenance and repair and thus to live a shorter and perhaps overall unhap pi e r
life than we could without adaptation?
Assessing the impact of adap tat i on on health beh avior, longevity, and happiness with the
means of lab or field e xperiments, i s potentially hard if not impossible because of the missing
counterfactual. With the help of economic theory and the design of an appropriate computa-
tional experiment an assessment is r el at ively straightforward. In this paper we p r opose such a
computational experime nt. We set up a life cycle model of human aging, in which del i berate
health investments reduce the spee d of aging and thus the age of death, c ali b rat e the model
with gerontological data, and compare behavior and outcomes for adapting and non-adapting
individuals. We distinguish between individuals who are aware of their adaptive behavior (so
called sophi st i cat ed types) and those who are not (naive types). Thi s labeling of types follows
Strotz (1955), see also Rabin (1998). We find, pe rh ap s surprisingly, that naive adaptation is
conducive to a healthier and longer l i fe . Sophisticated types, on the other hand, spend less on
health and live shorter than otherwise identical non-adapting types. We use these results and
compute the implied value of life. We find , again perhaps surprisingly, that both naive and
sophisticated types experience about the same value of life and that bot h types experience a
significantly higher value of life t h an non-adapting types. We explain the econ omi c intuition
behind these results.
Since the seminal study of Brickman e t al. (1978), comparing happin ess of paraplegics and
lottery winners, t h e medical and economics literatu re has provided ample evidence that humans
adapt to health problems an d rate their happiness or quality of li fe much higher than predicted
1

by unaffected person s anticipating negative health events (e.g. Wu, 2001; Albrecht and Devlieger,
1999; Riis et al., 2005). T hi s seems to be true for (mild) nuisances like acne (Baron et al. 2003)
as well as for severe disability (Oswald and Powdthavee, 2008). Adaptati on after a severe health
shock is gradual and perhaps complete. Oswald and Powdthavee (2008) estimate approximately
30 percent ( 50 percent) hedonic adaptation 3 years after the on se t of severe ( m odest) disability
and they could not reject the hypothesis of complete adaptation after 6 years. Using a very
large German panel of individuals observed from 1984 t o 2006, Pagan-Rodri gu ez (2010) finds
also gradual adaptation to disability and cannot reject the hypothesis of complete adaptation
after 7 years.
The observations that healthy persons under es t im at e the happiness of sick persons an d that
sick persons believe they would be happier if they had n ever been sick (Boyd et al., 1990; Riis et
al., 2005) indicates that people are not fully aware of there adaptive behavior. It indicates naive
rather than sophisticated adaptation. The available evidence suggests also that adaptation to
bad healt h is “genuine” and not driven by an overoptimistic assessment of one’s health and
survival probabilit ie s (Wu, 2001) and that the mi s pr ed i ct i on of healt hy people of their adaptive
capabilities is har d to explain by focussing illusion (Ubel et al., 2001; Baron et al., 2003).
While most studies focus on adaptation after severe health s hocks, we are here mostly (but
not exclusively) interested in th e gradual and progressive decl i ne of health that comes with age.
While many stu di e s document that aggregate measures of happiness or wellbeing do not dec li n e
(by much) over the life cycle (e.g. Costa et al., 1987; Die ne r and Suh, 1998; Deaton, 2007),
a particular interesting study in the present context is provided by Lacey et al. (2006) who
asked 30 and 70 years old persons to rate their own happiness as well as t o estimate happiness of
average 30 and 70 years old persons. They found that both, young and old individuals, estimated
happiness of the young group to be higher while actually it was the other way round. The authors
conclude that people displ ay a “remarkable inab il i ty to recognize their own adaptation”.
The model that we set up below in order to discuss the effects of adaptation to deteriorat-
ing health is particularly suitable f or this purpose since it is based on the notion of aging as
progressive health deficit accumulation. It is easy to see that the alternative paradigm, the
Grossman (1972) model, is less suitable. It is based on health capital accumulation and the
assumption that health capital depreciates at a given (potential age-specific) rate d(t) such that
individuals with health capital H(t) lose health d(t)H(t) through health depreciation. It t hus
2

Citations
More filters
Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors developed a life cycle model featuring an optimal retirement decision in the presence of physiological aging, which can account for the evolution of age of retirement and longevity across cohorts born between 1850 and 1940 in the US.
Abstract: We develop a life cycle model featuring an optimal retirement decision in the presence of physiological aging. In modeling the aging process we draw on recent advances within the fields of biology and medicine. In the model individuals decide on optimal consumption during life, the age of retirement, and (via health investments) the timing of their death. Accordingly, "years in retirement" is fully endogenously determined. Using the model we can account for the evolution of age of retirement and longevity across cohorts born between 1850 and 1940 in the US. Our analysis indicates that 2/3 of the observed increase in longevity can be accounted for by wage growth, whereas the driver behind the observed rising age of retirement appears to have been technological change in health care. Both technology and income contribute to the rise in years in retirement, but the contribution from income is slightly greater.

33 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this article, the authors construct a unified objective measure of health status: the frailty index, defined as the cumulative sum of all adverse health indicators observed for an individual, and estimate a stochastic process for frailty dynamics over the life cycle.
Abstract: We construct a unified objective measure of health status: the frailty index, defined as the cumulative sum of all adverse health indicators observed for an individual. First, we show that the frailty index has several advantages over self-reported health status, particularly when studying health dynamics. Then we estimate a stochastic process for frailty dynamics over the life cycle. We find that the autocovariance structure of frailty in panel data strongly supports a process that allows the conditional variance of frailty shocks to increase with age. Our frailty measure and dynamic process can be used by researchers to study the evolution of health over the life cycle and its economic implications.

27 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: It is found that regional differences in aging follow a particular regularity, akin to the compensation effect of mortality, and health deficits converge for men and women and across American regions and suggest a life span of the American population of about 97 years.
Abstract: We study biological aging of elderly U.S. Americans born 1904-1966. We use thirteen waves of the Health and Retirement Study and construct a frailty index as the number of health deficits present in a person measured relative to the number of potential deficits. We find that, on average, Americans develop 5% more health deficits per year, that men age slightly faster than women, and that, at any age above 50, Caucasians display significantly fewer health deficits than African Americans. We also document a steady time trend of health improvements. For each year of later birth, health deficits decline on average by about 1%. This health trend is about the same across regions and for men and women, but significantly lower for African Americans compared to Caucasians. In non-linear regressions, we find that regional differences in aging follow a particular regularity, akin to the compensation effect of mortality. Health deficits converge for men and women and across American regions and suggest a life span of the American population of about 97 years.

20 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigate the interaction between health and retirement policy in order to quantitatively characterize the optimal joint design of the social insurance system today and in response to future medical progress, and its implications for health inequality.
Abstract: This paper integrates into public economics a biologically founded, stochastic process of individual ageing. The novel approach enables us to investigate the interaction between health and retirement policy in order to quantitatively characterize the optimal joint design of the social insurance system today and in response to future medical progress, and its implications for health inequality. Calibrating our model to Germany, we find that currently the public health and pension system is approximately optimal. Future progress in medical technology calls for a potentially drastic increase in health spending that typically shall be accompanied with a lower pension savings rate and a higher retirement age. Medical progress and higher health spending is predicted to lead to more health inequality.

14 citations

References
More filters
Book
01 Jan 1998

9,675 citations


"Going from Bad to Worse: Adaptation..." refers background in this paper

  • ...This value matches the health expenditure share of GDP in the U.S. in the year 2000 (World Bank, 2015)....

    [...]

Book ChapterDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a problem which has not heretofore been analysed and provide a theory to explain, under different circumstances, three related phenomena: (1) spendthriftiness; (2) the deliberate regimenting of one's future economic behaviour, even at a cost; and (3) thrift.
Abstract: This paper presents a problem which I believe has not heretofore been analysed2 and provides a theory to explain, under different circumstances, three related phenomena: (1) spendthriftiness; (2) the deliberate regimenting of one’s future economic behaviour— even at a cost; and (3) thrift. The senses in which we deal with these topics can probably not be very well understood, however, until after the paper has been read; but a few sentences at this point may shed some light on what we are up to.

3,427 citations


"Going from Bad to Worse: Adaptation..." refers background in this paper

  • ...This labeling of types follows Strotz (1955), see also Rabin (1998)....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a longer version of an essay under preparation for possible publication in the Journal of Economic Literature, which they refer to as their work on reference-dependent utility.
Abstract: UNTVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT BERKELEY Department of Economics Berkeley, CaHfornia 94720-3880 Working Paper No. 97-251 Psychology and Economics Matthew Rabin Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley January 1997 Key words: bounded rationality, decision making, fairness, framing effects, heuristics and biases, preferences, psychology, reciprocity, reference-dependent utility JEL Classification: A12, B49, D i l , D60, D81, D83, D91 This is a longer version of an essay under preparation for possible publication in the Journal of Economic Literature. I thank John Pencavel and anonymous referees for earlier comments on its structure and content. For comments on this draft, I thank Steven Blatt, Colin Camerer, Peter Diamond, Erik Eyster, Ernst Fehr, Danny Kahneman, George Loewenstein, Ted O'Donoghue, and John Pencavel. For helpful conversations over the past several years on topics covered in this essay, I thank George Akerlof, Gary Chamess, Eddie Dekel, Peter Diamond, David Laibson, David I. Levine, George Loewenstein, Rob MacCoun, James Montgomery, Vai-Lam Mui, Drazen Prelec, and especially Colin Camerer, Danny Kahneman, and Richard Thaler. Co-authors on research related to the topics of this essay include David Bowman, Deborah Minehart, Ted O'Donoghue, and Joel Schrag. Helpful research assistance was provided by Gadi Barlevy, Nikki Blasberg, Gail Brennan, Paul Ellickson, April Franco, Marcus Heng, Bruce Hsu, Jin Woo Jung, and especially Steven Blatt, Jimmy Chan, Erik Eyster, and Clara Wang. I am extremely grateful for financial support from the Russell Sage and Alfred P. Sloan Foundations.

2,426 citations


"Going from Bad to Worse: Adaptation..." refers background in this paper

  • ...This labeling of types follows Strotz (1955), see also Rabin (1998)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Lottery winners were not happier than controls and took significantly less pleasure from a series of mundane events, and Paraplegics also demonstrated a contrast effect, not by enhancing minor pleasures but by idealizing their past, which did not help their present happiness.
Abstract: Adaptation level theory suggests that both contrast and habituation will operate to prevent the winning of a fortune from elevating happiness as much as might be expected. Contrast with the peak experience of winning should lessen the impact of ordinary pleasures, while habituation should eventually reduce the value of new pleasures made possible by winning. Study 1 compared a sample of 22 major lottery winners with 22 controls and also with a group of 29 paralyzed accident victims who had been interviewed previously. As predicted, lottery winners were not happier than controls and took significantly less pleasure from a series of mundane events. Study 2 indicated that these effects were not due to preexisting differences between people who buy or do not buy lottery tickets or between interviews that made or did not make the lottery salient. Paraplegics also demonstrated a contrast effect, not by enhancing minor pleasures but by idealizing their past, which did not help their present happiness.

2,015 citations


"Going from Bad to Worse: Adaptation..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Since the seminal study of Brickman et al. (1978), comparing happiness of paraplegics and lottery winners, the medical and economics literature has provided ample evidence that humans adapt to health problems and rate their happiness or quality of life much higher than predicted by unaffected…...

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The formula for estimating an individual's life span given the frailty index value is presented and it is proposed that it may be used as a proxy measure of aging.
Abstract: This paper develops a method for appraising health status in elderly people. A frailty index was defined as the proportion of accumulated deficits (symptoms, signs, functional impairments, and laboratory abnormalities). It serves as an individual state variable, reflecting severity of illness and proximity to death. In a representative database of elderly Canadians we found that deficits accumulated at 3% per year, and show a gamma distribution, typical for systems with redundant components that can be used in case of failure of a given subsystem. Of note, the slope of the index is insensitive to the individual nature of the deficits, and serves as an important prognostic factor for life expectancy. The formula for estimating an individual's life span given the frailty index value is presented. For different patterns of cognitive impairments the average within-group index value increases with the severity of the cognitive impairment, and the relative variability of the index is significantly reduced. Finally, the statistical distribution of the frailty index sharply differs between well groups (gamma distribution) and morbid groups (normal distribution). This pattern reflects an increase in uncompensated deficits in impaired organisms, which would lead to illness of various etiologies, and ultimately to increased mortality. The accumulation of deficits is as an example of a macroscopic variable, i.e., one that reflects general properties of aging at the level of the whole organism rather than any given functional deficiency. In consequence, we propose that it may be used as a proxy measure of aging.

1,900 citations


"Going from Bad to Worse: Adaptation..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Health expenditure is increasing with age and highest for the oldest individuals, 2According to Mitnitski et al. (2001) the standard deviation of most health deficits in the frailty index is around 0.4/µ̃, in which µ̃ is the mean of the particular deficit....

    [...]