scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Holdup and hiring discrimination with search friction

TL;DR: In this paper, a holdup problem on workers' skill investment can arise when employers adopt discriminatory hiring norm to extract higher than socially optimal profit, when hiring priority is determined by both productivity-dependent (skill level) and -independent characteristics (discrimination).
Abstract: A holdup problem on workers' skill investment can arise when employers adopt discriminatory hiring norm to extract higher than socially optimal profit. When hiring priority is determined by both productivity-dependent (skill level) and -independent characteristics (discrimination), skill investment decision becomes strategic between the discriminated and favored group. We consider frictional markets with either posted or bargained wage (fixed sharing rule). With posted wage, depending on market tightness there may be equilibrium or multiple equilibria on skill investment. With discriminatory hiring, if in equilibrium both groups stay high skilled, both are worse off and firms better off; In any equilibrium where one group underinvest, the other group remain high skilled and are better off, while firms are worse off with discrimination. With bargained wage, similar equilibrium where the favored group underinvest exists, and firms incur cost for an intermediate range of bargaining power when they discriminate.

Summary (4 min read)

1 Introduction

  • A holdup problem arises when some investment is sunk ex ante by one party, and the payo is shared with that one party's trading partner.
  • Since cost has no other use once sunk, that trading partner will have every incentive to squeeze the pro t at the ex post stage.
  • On one hand, there is ranking by productivity-dependent type identity: workers are either high skilled (type H) or low skilled (type L); high skilled have priority to low skilled simply because such ranking gives rms higher pro t.

1.1 Relation to the literature

  • Job search process is an important channel through which discrimination keeps functioning in the labor market.
  • Search frictions are derived endogenously through agents' sequential strategic interactions.
  • While the setup of wage bargaining (no information of level of wage before matching) is more prevalent, it neglects an important trade-o that the workers make to some extent in their search for jobs: the wage and the probability of obtaining it.
  • Rosen (1997) is an exception and shows that discrimination can result even if there are no di erences across groups.

2 The model without discrimination

  • The authors start with a context without hiring discrimination.
  • Consider an economy populated by two kinds of agents, the workers and the rms.
  • Firms observe skills of job seekers, and announce the wage (wL, wH), also known as Stage 1.
  • 5Incompleteness of contract is the source of ine ciency for the holdup problem.
  • See Acemoglu and Shimer (1999) for related literature.

2.1 Speci cation of the Strategies, matching probabilities, and payo functions

  • This section provides a quick summary for the general understanding of the context.
  • The authors should distinguish two terms: (1) each job seeker's expected payo from application, and (2) her expected market payo .
  • By doing so, the authors are able to abstract from some equilibrium which only arises under theoretical rigor but at the same time yields insights to a limited extent and induces unnecessary complexity in analysis.
  • Ut, solving wt from the constraint, substituting it into the objective function, and maximizing with respect to qt, the authors can obtain an optimal functional relationship between q ∗ t and Ut.

2.2 Decentralized Market Equilibrium without discrimination under Notion 2

  • Firms' wage o ers are conditioned on job seekers' skill levels, so the authors rst consider the skill investment decision of job seekers at rst stage.
  • Some invest in high skill, while the remaining in low skill.
  • The authors now show that the rivalry between the 8The program could also be understood as a deviating rm's pro t maximization, taking all the other rms' best response as given.
  • There is no incentive for them to deviate, and the output is highest among all the equilibria.
  • When the value of yH−yLEH−EL is moderate, there exists an equilibrium where job seekers are indi erent from being high skilled or low skills; all rms nd it optimal to attract both skill types; the output is lower compared to the previous equilibrium.

2.2.1 Decentralized Market Equilibrium without discrimination under Notion 1

  • Under Notion 1, there is only one skill type present in the market.
  • It turns out that the threshold which makes workers indi erent is the same as β̂ established under Notion 2.

2.3 Constrained e cient allocations

  • The objective of this section is to nd the e cient allocations in the centralized market, and evaluate whether the decentralized market attains its e ciency.
  • More precisely, the social planner chooses the fraction of workers to be high-skilled, divides rms into di erent groups to attract distinct compositions of workers, and assigns workers to match with a certain group of rms.
  • If αp ∈ (0, 1), there are both high and low skilled job seekers and it is optimal for the planner to assign all rms to post wages for both the high and low skilled (shown in Shi (2006)).
  • The above objective includes all cases with di erent values of α.
  • The equilibrium labor allocation and skill investment choice are socially optimal.

3 The model with hiring discrimination

  • Consider an economy where workers can be partitioned into two groups, group a and group b, according to certain trait which is irrelevant to productivity.
  • The two group of workers are ex ante identical in all other aspects.
  • The parts 1−e −qa qa and 1−e −qb qb capture the within group competition, while the remaining parts with x capture the between group competition.
  • Then the employment probability of workers from the preferred group (group a) is higher under discrimination than that in the case without discrimination.
  • The closer x approaches to the extremes of the interval [0, 1], the more intensive the hiring discrimination is.

3.1 The case of strong discrimination: x = 1

  • These assumptions help introduce some heterogeneity which is not related to productivity among the labor pool.
  • Firms are not allowed to post wages which are dependent on the group identity, also known as Assumption 1.
  • The authors denote in this section the expected market payo of high skilled job seekers from group a and group b as UaH and UbH respectively.
  • The above assumptions imply UaH = FaH (qaH , qbH)×.
  • In the next section, the authors review the results from LMD (2005), where they study the case with discrimination but no di erence in workers' skill levels (or productivity).

3.2 Existing results revisited and reinterpreted

  • In a context where there are two groups of workers with identical productivity (skill level) and rms strongly prefer group a to group b. LMD (2005) show that any subgame-perfect competitive equilibrium (SPCE) is separating.
  • LMD (2005) show that there is no wage to which both groups of job seekers apply.
  • That is, there are some rms posting a higher level of wage attracting only the preferred group a, whereas the rest of rms o ering a lower wage which is applied only by the discriminated group b (see Proposition 2 in LMD (2005)).
  • Following are several noteworthy properties of such an equilibrium.
  • The authors enter more detailed discussions in the following section.

3.3 Analysis under our context

  • In the last section, the authors interpreted the equilibrium of the wage posting subgame given that all workers choose to be high skilled.
  • Whenever they contemplate to lower skill investment, they understand that they will be ranked behind the high skilled group b; then the term e−qbH which captures the competition from bH will appear in their payo s.
  • The results on the equilibrium are summarized as follows: Proposition 3: Under the above assumptions, there exist two thresholds β̂2 and β̂1 with 0 < β̂2 < β̂1 < β̂, such that (1) When 0 < β < β̂2, there exists a unique equilibrium in which both group a and group b invest in high skill, (aH, bH).
  • Since qP1aH does not depend on yH and yL, there exists always a pair of yL and yH such that this condition is satis ed. 17 Documents de travail du Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne - 2016.02 rms turn out to earn lower expected pro ts compared to the case without discrimination.

4 Comparison with xed sharing rule (Wage Bargaining)

  • The authors shut down the channel through which rms use wages to in uence workers' choices on applications, and examine whether the ine ciency can be alleviated.
  • If the authors denote the bargaining power for all workers as ψ, then from the output yt, workers receive ψyt, and rms receive (1− ψ) yt.
  • The authors focus on the case where ψ is the same for both skill levels, otherwise there is too much degree of freedom.
  • Each group of workers invest in skills simultaneously.
  • Their simple result suggest that rms are simply better o not discriminating when wages are principally bargained, since the loss in pro t from discriminating in the high skilled sector may surpass the gain from discriminating in the low skilled sector.

5 Discussion

  • LMD (2005) have shown that their economy under discrimination with workers' identical in productivity can be generalized to take into account rms' free entry.
  • Then rms which earn expected non-positive pro ts after the reduction of capital cost would simply not enter into the market.
  • Shi (2006) shows that in such a model with multiple skill levels free of discrimination, the result that rms always rank the high skilled workers in priority to the workers with lower skills can be generalized.
  • The di culty under the context with discrimination, as just stated, is on the extent of the game.

6 Conclusion

  • The authors study a holdup problem where rms can use discriminatory hiring norms to extract higher than socially optimal pro ts.
  • In case wages are posted, the authors suggest that depending on the market tightness there may be equilibrium or multiple equilibria on skill investment; in some equilibrium the discriminated group can obtain higher expected payo compared to the case without discrimination12 and rms can be worse o .
  • The authors also consider xed sharing rule (bargained wage) and make a comparison.
  • Firms' pro ts are piecewise monotone because the skill composition hence the average productivity of the market improves discretely with respect to the bargaining power, and pro t loss may be incurred with discrimination within an intermediate range of bargaining power.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

HAL Id: halshs-01277548
https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01277548
Submitted on 23 Feb 2016
HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access
archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci-
entic research documents, whether they are pub-
lished or not. The documents may come from
teaching and research institutions in France or
abroad, or from public or private research centers.
L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est
destinée au dépôt et à la diusion de documents
scientiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non,
émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de
recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires
publics ou privés.
Holdup and hiring discrimination with search friction
Sheng Bi, Yuanyuan Li
To cite this version:
Sheng Bi, Yuanyuan Li. Holdup and hiring discrimination with search friction. 2016. �halshs-
01277548�

Documents de Travail du
Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne
Holdup and hiring discrimination with search friction
Sheng BI, Yuanyuan LI
2016.02
Maison des Sciences Économiques, 106-112 boulevard de L'Hôpital, 75647 Paris Cedex 13
http://centredeconomiesorbonne.univ-paris1.fr/
ISSN : 1955-611X




Citations
More filters
Posted Content
TL;DR: This model can generate a positive correlation between firm size and wage without introducing any ex ante productivity differences or imposing any non-concave production function assumption.
Abstract: We consider the impact of job rotation in a directed search model in which firm sizes are endogenously determined and match quality is initially unknown. A large firm benefits from the opportunity of rotating workers so as to partially overcome loss of mismatch. As a result, in the unique symmetric equilibrium, large firms have higher labor productivity and lower separation rates. In contrast to the standard directed search model with multi-vacancy firms, this model can generate a positive correlation between firm size and wage without introducing any ex ante productivity differences or imposing any non-concave production function assumption.

4 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors corrects the matching function proposed by Albrecht et al. [Econ. Lett. 78 (2003) 67] and verifies that the limiting result given in that note is correct.

52 citations


"Holdup and hiring discrimination wi..." refers background in this paper

  • ...With Case (1) and Case (3), there exists only one skill level in the market, and since skills can be conditioned on wages, there is only one wage posted in equilibrium....

    [...]

  • ...(3) When β̂1 < β ≤ β̂, there exist multiple equilibria....

    [...]

  • ...However, the market with Case (2) features two skill levels....

    [...]

  • ...(3) The expected payo of group a and group b are such that U aH > U S bH ....

    [...]

  • ...There are three cases: Case (1). α∗ = 1....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: The authors used directed search to model the product market and the labor market and showed that large plants can pay higher wages to homogeneous workers and earn higher expected profit per worker than small plants, although plants are identical except size.
Abstract: Using directed search to model the product market and the labor market, I show that large plants can pay higher wages to homogeneous workers and earn higher expected profit per worker than small plants, although plants are identical except size. A large plant charges a higher price for its product and compensates buyers with a higher service probability. To capture this size-related benefit, large plants try to become larger by recruiting at high wages. This size-wage differential survives labor market competition because a high wage is harder to get than a low wage. Moreover, the size-wage differential increases with the product demand when demand is initially low and falls when demand is already high.

43 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper developed an equilibrium directed search model of the labor market where workers can simultaneously apply for multiple jobs and found that all equilibria exhibit wage dispersion despite the fact that workers and firms are homogeneous.
Abstract: We develop an equilibrium directed search model of the labor market where workers can simultaneously apply for multiple jobs. The main result is that all equilibria exhibit wage dispersion despite the fact that workers and firms are homogeneous. Wage dispersion is driven by the simultaneity of application choice. Risk-neutral workers apply for both "safe" and "risky" jobs. The former yield a high probability of a job offer, but for low pay, and act as a fallback option; the latter provide with higher potential payoff, but are harder to get. Furthermore, the density of posted wages is decreasing, consistent with stylized facts. Unlike most directed search models, the equilibria are not constrained efficient.

42 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a directed search model is proposed to explain the residual part of wage variation left over after the impact of education and other observable worker characteristics have been removed, and the model is used to provide a functional relationship that ties together the wage distribution and the wage-duration function.
Abstract: This paper provides a directed search model designed to explain the residual part of wage variation left over after the impact of education and other observable worker characteristics have been removed. Workers have private information about their characteristics at the time they apply for jobs. Firms value these characteristics differently and can observe them once workers apply. They hire the worker they most prefer. However, the characteristics are not contractible, so firms cannot condition their wages on them. This paper shows how to extend arguments from directed search to handle this, allowing for arbitrary distributions of worker and firm types. The model is used to provide a functional relationship that ties together the wage distribution and the wage-duration function. This relationship provides a testable implication of the model. This relationship suggests a common property of wage distributions that guarantees that workers who leave unemployment at the highest wages also have the shortest unemployment duration. This is in strict contrast to the usual (and somewhat implausible) directed search story in which high wages are always accompanied by higher probability of unemployment.

40 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
Shouyong Shi1
TL;DR: This article used directed search to model the product market and the labor market and showed that large plants can pay higher wages to homogeneous workers and earn higher expected profit per worker than small plants, although plants are identical except size.
Abstract: Using directed search to model the product market and the labor market, I show that large plants can pay higher wages to homogeneous workers and earn higher expected profit per worker than small plants, although plants are identical except size. A large plant charges a higher price for its product and compensates buyers with a higher service probability. To capture this sizerelated benefit, large plants try to become larger by recruiting at high wages. This size‐wage differential survives labor market competition because a high wage is harder to get than a low wage. Moreover, the size‐wage differential increases with the product demand when demand is initially low and falls when demand is already high.

34 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What are the contributions in "Holdup and hiring discrimination with search friction" ?

The authors consider frictional markets with either posted or bargained wage ( xed sharing rule ).