scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Horizontal Inequalities and Ethnonationalist Civil War: A Global Comparison

01 Aug 2011-American Political Science Review (Cambridge University Press)-Vol. 105, Iss: 3, pp 478-495
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors argue that horizontal inequalities between politically relevant ethnic groups and states at large can promote ethnonationalist conflict, and they introduce a new spatial method that combines their newly geocoded data on ethnic groups' settlement areas with spatial wealth estimates.
Abstract: Contemporary research on civil war has largely dismissed the role of political and economic grievances, focusing instead on opportunities for conflict. However, these strong claims rest on questionable theoretical and empirical grounds. Whereas scholars have examined primarily the relationship between individual inequality and conflict, we argue that horizontal inequalities between politically relevant ethnic groups and states at large can promote ethnonationalist conflict. Extending the empirical scope to the entire world, this article introduces a new spatial method that combines our newly geocoded data on ethnic groups’ settlement areas with spatial wealth estimates. Based on these methodological advances, we find that, in highly unequal societies, both rich and poor groups fight more often than those groups whose wealth lies closer to the country average. Our results remain robust to a number of alternative sample definitions and specifications.

Summary (3 min read)

A Global Comparison

  • LARS-ERIK CEDERMAN ETH Zürich NILS B. WEIDMANN Yale University KRISTIAN SKREDE GLEDITSCH.
  • Indeed, inequality continues to occupy a prominent place in the qualitative literature on civil wars and has repeatedly been linked to conflict processes (Sambanis 2005, 323; Stewart 2008b; Wood 2003).
  • Relative deprivation theory remains perhaps the most prominent explanation that connects grievances with conflict, but has a very mixed record as regards empirical evidence (Brush 1996; Oberschall 1978).
  • Noting that there is a major discrepancy between the quantitative nonfinding and the repeated references to inequality in the case studies, Sambanis (2005, 324) considers a number of explanations, including problems relating to interpretation and sampling of case evidence, as well as the fundamental issue of aggregation level:.

THEORIZING HORIZONTAL INEQUALITIES

  • The authors now turn to their own account of inequality and conflict.
  • The authors follow Stewart in treating the distribution of power and of wealth as conceptually separate components.
  • Building on their previous work, the authors view HIs as structural asymmetries that make ethnonationalist civil war more likely and adopt an indirect research strategy that explains the effect of inequality by postulating a set of causal mechanisms.
  • Second, the authors argue that such grievances trigger violent collective action through a process of group mobilization.

From Horizontal Inequalities to Grievances

  • As opposed to objective conditions such as horizontal inequalities, grievances are intersubjectively perceived phenomena.
  • As the authors have noted earlier in the text, this makes them very hard to measure, but they can draw on an extensive experimentally supported literature 4.
  • In agreement with Petersen (2002), the authors postulate that resentment based on intergroup comparisons involving HIs often 6.
  • It should be noted that the presence of HIs presupposes the existence of well-defined groups (Stewart 2000), which is not a trivial precondition (e.g., Kalyvas 2006).
  • Yet, because their goal is to evaluate the conflict-inducing effect of HIs, the authors join Horowitz (1985), Gurr (1993; 2000b) and others in adopting a self-consciously group-based framework, although restricting their substantive focus to groups defined through ethnic categorization rather than through other cleavages.

From Grievances to Collective Action

  • Clearly, emotions do not automatically trigger violent behavior.
  • Yet most governmental incumbents will only reluctantly abandon their advantaged positions by sharing power or letting minorities secede.
  • As convincingly argued by Kalyvas and Kocher (2007), the existence of a dilemma hinges on the questionable assumption that participation in combat is costlier than nonparticipation.
  • Moreover, a number of studies show that collective identities, such as those constituting ethnic groups, facilitate collective action (e.g., Gates 2002; Simpson and Macy 2004).
  • Thus, rather than classifying inequality as a pure “grievance” factor, the authors view its impact as a mobilizational resource.

ON HORIZONTAL INEQUALITIES AND CIVIL WAR

  • Having postulated their causal mechanisms, the authors now return to the macro-level to perform the actual empirical analysis.
  • The authors second hypothesis summarizes these theoretical expectations: H2.
  • Economic and political HIs both increase the likelihood of civil war.
  • Poorer groups, especially those residing in backward and peripheral regions, often desire to break away from the cores of their countries regardless of the cost, because they perceive themselves to be systematically disadvantaged compared to their wealthier compatriots in terms of economic development and distribution of public goods.

GLOBAL DATA ON HORIZONTAL INEQUALITIES AND OTHER DIMENSIONS

  • The authors theoretical expectations must now be confronted with empirical evidence.
  • In sum, survey data may be helpful for many purposes, but the DHS data do not provide a plausible alternative for evaluating the role of horizontal inequalities on a global basis.
  • In fact, the only broadly available cross-national data source on variation in wealth within countries is the G-Econ data, developed by Nordhaus (2006; see also Nordhaus and Chen 2009).
  • The authors therefore rely on the recently completed GeoEPR dataset, a comprehensive geocoded version of the EPR groups (Wucherpfennig et al. n.d.).

DERIVING OPERATIONAL MEASURES

  • The G-Econ data allow deriving ethnic group–specific measures of wealth by overlaying polygons indicating group settlement areas with the cells in the Nordhaus data.
  • Compared to the other parts of the country, Serbia shows up as a generally poor region.
  • Figure 2 shows horizontal inequality for Yugoslavia, measured as the ratio of the group’s GDP per capita estimate to the average value for the entire country, depicting wealthier groups in darker shades and poorer ones in brighter shades.
  • In addition, the authors measure the group’s demographic power balance with the ethnic group(s) in power (EGIP) as its share of the dyadic population.

EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

  • Given the limited temporal availability of inequality data, the authors restrict the sample to group years after the Cold War, from 1991 through 2005.
  • The result is both substantively and statistically significant, suggesting that groups with wealth levels far from the country average are indeed more likely to experience civil war.
  • The authors spatial method becomes unreliable for small population sizes, primarily because of the low resolution of the G-Econ data and the limited precision of the population estimates for tiny groups.
  • 26 Consequently, the group-size restriction almost triples the inequality coefficient reported in Model 2 without affecting the size of the standard error.

SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS

  • Because the number of onsets is quite limited, their findings need to be treated with some caution.
  • Extending the sample of Model 3 to the entire post-WWII period, Model 7 reveals that the main inequality result holds in this case as well.30 Because the Nordhaus data represent a temporal snapshot, there are also reasons to be concerned that endogeneity could have distorted the results.
  • The results of this 29 A simple test (not shown) based on a dummy variable that indicates whether the group’s settlement area intersects with oil fields also fails to make any substantial difference in the effect of the inequality variables (see data at http://www.prio.no/CSCW/Datasets).
  • The authors also ran models controlling for world regions, which further confirm the robustness of their findings.

CONCLUSION

  • Building on the pioneering efforts of Gurr (1993; 2000b) and his team, who have also collected extensive data on social and cultural HIs, such information would help disentangle the process at lower levels of aggregation and help us establish whether the causal imputations remain robust to such scrutiny.
  • Their spatial method is limited to territorially segregated groups, and therefore cannot measure nonspatial, economic HI, as in the case of the Hutu and Tutsi in Rwanda.
  • One key implication is that the authors have not derived the falsifiable predictions that distinguish between material and nonmaterial theoretical accounts.
  • Rejecting “messy” factors, such as grievances and inequalities, may lead to more elegant models that can be more easily tested, but the fact remains that some of the most intractable and damaging conflict processes in the contemporary world, such as the conflicts afflicting the Sudan or the former Yugoslavia, are to a large extent about political and economic injustice.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

ETH Library
Horizontal Inequalities and
Ethnonationalist Civil War
A Global Comparison
Journal Article
Author(s):
Cederman, Lars-Erik; Weidmann, Nils B.; Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede
Publication date:
2011-08
Permanent link:
https://doi.org/10.3929/ethz-b-000160115
Rights / license:
In Copyright - Non-Commercial Use Permitted
Originally published in:
American Political Science Review 105(3), https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055411000207
This page was generated automatically upon download from the ETH Zurich Research Collection.
For more information, please consult the Terms of use.

American Political Science Review Vol. 105, No. 3 August 2011
doi:10.1017/S0003055411000207
Horizontal Inequalities and Ethnonationalist Civil War:
A Global Comparison
LARS-ERIK CEDERMAN ETH Z
¨
urich
NILS B. WEIDMANN Yale University
KRISTIAN SKREDE GLEDITSCH University of Essex
C
ontemporary research on civil war has largely dismissed the role of political and economic
grievances, focusing instead on opportunities for conflict. However, these strong claims rest on
questionable theoretical and empirical grounds. Whereas scholars have examined primarily the
relationship between individual inequality and conflict, we argue that horizontal inequalities between
politically relevant ethnic groups and states at large can promote ethnonationalist conflict. Extending
the empirical scope to the entire world, this article introduces a new spatial method that combines our
newly geocoded data on ethnic groups’ settlement areas with spatial wealth estimates. Based on these
methodological advances, we find that, in highly unequal societies, both rich and poor groups fight more
often than those groups whose wealth lies closer to the country average. Our results remain robust to a
number of alternative sample definitions and specifications.
A
lthough logistical and power-related
conditionssuch as low state-level per capita
income, weak state institutions, and peripheral
and inaccessible territoryenjoy near-consensus sup-
port as explanations of civil war onset, most of the
contemporary literature regards explanations rooted
in political and economic grievances with suspicion
(Blattman and Miguel 2010). In fact, the debate over
the status of grievances in such explanations dates
back at least to the 1960s, with the introduction of
relative deprivation theory. Inspired by psychological
theories of conflict, Gurr (1970) and his colleagues
argued that economic and other types of inequality
increase the risk of internal strife through frustrated
expectations. In contrast, today’s most influential
quantitative studies of civil war give short shrift
Lars-Erik Cederman is Professor, Center for Comparative and In-
ternational Studies, Swiss Federal Institute of Technology (ETH)
Z
¨
urich, IFW D 49.2, 8092 Z
¨
urich, Switzerland (lcederman@ethz.ch).
Nils B. Weidmann is Postdoctoral Fellow, Jackson Institute for
Global Affairs, Yale University, P.O. Box 208206, New Haven, CT
06520 (nils.weidmann@yale.edu).
Kristian Skrede Gleditsch is Professor, Department of Govern-
ment, University of Essex, Wivenhoe Park, Colchester, Essex, UK
CO4 3SQ (ksg@essex.ac.uk).
All authors are also affiliated with Centre for the Study of Civil
War, PRIO, Oslo, Norway.
We thank the coeditors of the APSR, the anonymous reviewers,
Carles Boix, David Cunningham, Kathleen Cunningham, Erik Me-
lander, and Gudrun Østby for helpful comments and discussions, as
well as participants in seminars at the Centre for the Study of Civil
War, PRIO; the University of Arizona, the University of Z
¨
urich;
the Center of Comparative and International Studies, Z
¨
urich; the
University of Maryland; Yale University; and the 7th SGIR Pan-
European International Relations Conference, Stockholm. Christa
Deiwiks, Luc Girardin, and Julian Wucherpfennig offered crucial
research support. Cederman acknowledges support from the Eu-
ropean Science Foundation (06_ECRP_FP004) through the Swiss
National Science Foundation (105511-116795). Weidmann acknowl-
edges support from the Air Force Office of Scientific Research
(Grant FA9550-09-1-0314). Gleditsch acknowledges the support of
the European Science Foundation (06_ECRP_FP004) through the
Economic and Social Research Council (RES-062-23-0259) and the
Research Council of Norway (180441/V10).
to grievance-based accounts, based on reports that
unequal individual wealth distributions have no
statistically distinguishable relationship to internal
conflict (e.g., Collier and Hoeffler 2004; Fearon and
Laitin 2003).
Yet, despite these alleged nonfindings, the debate
over grievances is far from dead. Indeed, inequality
continues to occupy a prominent place in the qual-
itative literature on civil wars and has repeatedly
been linked to conflict processes (Sambanis 2005, 323;
Stewart 2008b; Wood 2003). Moreover, in the last few
years, some quantitative studies have started to appear
that argue that the current literature’s failure to con-
nect distributional asymmetries with conflict behavior
may actually be due to inappropriate conceptualization
and imperfect measurements, rather than reflecting a
fundamental absence of any causal effect (Østby 2008b;
see also Stewart 2008b).
Also relying on quantitative evidence, we join these
recent contributions in shifting the explanatory focus
from individualist to group-level accounts of inequal-
ity and conflict. Because formidable problems of data
availability associated with the uneven coverage and
comparability of surveys have stood in the way of
assessing such “horizontal inequalities” (HIs), most
scholars have had to content themselves with selective
case studies or statistical samples restricted to particu-
lar world regions.
To overcome these difficulties, we combine our
newly geocoded data on politically relevant ethnic
groups’ settlement areas with Nordhaus’s (2006) spa-
tial wealth measures, both with global coverage. Based
on this novel strategy, we present the first truly world-
wide comparison of horizontal inequality and ethnona-
tionalist civil wars. Controlling for political power ac-
cess, we show that both advanced and backward ethnic
groups are more likely to experience such conflict than
groups whose wealth lies closer to the national average.
Moreover, in agreement with a broad conception of
horizontal inequalities, we find that both political and
economic inequalities contribute to civil war. Extensive
478
https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055411000207
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 14:23:50, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at

American Political Science Review Vol. 105, No. 3
sensitivity analysis confirms that our findings are robust
to various model specifications, alternative inequality
measures, and sample definitions.
We proceed as follows: First, we review the extensive
literature on inequality and conflict before narrowing
down the scope to our own theoretical framework,
which connects HIs with collective violence through
grievance-based mechanisms. Based on this approach,
we derive our main hypotheses on the effect of HIs
on civil war onset. To test the hypotheses, we then
introduce the datasets and describe our spatial method
of wealth estimation in detail, including how to use
the contours of the ethnic groups’ settlement areas as
“cookie cutters,” which allows us to extract the rel-
evant wealth estimates from the spatial wealth map.
After specifying the variables used in our empirical
analysis, we then expose the hypotheses to systematic
tests in the main models, followed by another section
that assesses the robustness of our findings. Finally,
concluding at least tentatively that both economic and
political inequality at the group level increase the risk
of ethnonationalist civil war, we argue that the civil
war literature’s tendency to downplay the importance
of grievances as a source of internal conflict is both
premature and misguided.
INEQUALITY IN THE CIVIL WAR
LITERATURE
Intimately related to issues of power and wealth dis-
tribution in society, inequality plays a central role in
classical theories of conflict. In an influential article,
Davies (1962) argued that revolutions were motivated
by frustration resulting from an evolving gap between
individual aspirations and actual economic status. Also
adopting an explicitly psychological perspective, Gurr’s
(1970) well-known theory of relative deprivation char-
acterizes various types of collective violence as reac-
tions to frustrations stemming from unfulfilled aspira-
tions, usually related to material well-being (see review
in Brush 1996). Such a perspective differs radically
from earlier sociological theories of mob behavior that
explained collective violence as a societal pathology
(e.g., Le Bon 1913). Instead, relative deprivation theo-
rists argue that individuals’ widespread discontent with
their social situation triggers conflict, especially where
modernization fuels a “revolution of rising expecta-
tions” (Davies 1962).
Although related indirectly to inequality through
this psychological mechanism, relative deprivation the-
ory does not explicitly focus on interpersonal or inter-
group wealth comparisons (Hogg and Abrams 1988;
Regan and Norton 2005; cf. Gurr and Duvall 1973).
Other theories adopt a structural perspective, linking
various types of inequality explicitly to structural im-
balances in society, such as uneven income or land dis-
tribution (Acemo
˘
glu and Robinson 2005; Muller 1985;
Muller and Seligson 1987; Russett 1964). Partly un-
der the inspiration of Marxist principles, the literature
on peasant rebellions explains violent collective action
as a response to unequal wealth allocation (Moore
1966; Scott 1976). Frustrated with their lot, the peasant
masses and other underprivileged groups are expected
to take up arms as a way to seize power and redistribute
wealth in their favor.
Relative deprivation theory remains perhaps the
most prominent explanation that connects grievances
with conflict, but has a very mixed record as regards em-
pirical evidence (Brush 1996; Oberschall 1978). Early
on, the theory attracted criticism from Snyder and
Tilly (1972), who argued that opportunity-based mobi-
lization rather than grievances causes internal conflict
and revolutions. Contending that all societies contain
a number of aggrieved and frustrated individuals, they
did not think “there is any general connection between
collective violence and hardship such that an observer
could predict one from the other” (Tilly 1972, 520; see
also Skocpol 1979; Tilly 1978). Along similar lines, a
series of studies challenged the results pertaining to
income inequality, which was usually seen as closely
connected to the notion of relative deprivation (see,
e.g., Weede 1987). By the end of the 1980s, the de-
bate remained unresolved, with virtually all possible
causal connectionsnegative, positive, curvilinear, or
nonebeing represented in the literature (Lichbach
1989).
As the end of the Cold War brought with it a new
wave of conflict, most of which was ethnonationally
motivated, Gurr (1993, 2000a, 2000b) extended his
previous theory and began to study ethnic minorities’
reactions to state-imposed disadvantages and discrim-
ination. In agreement with Horowitz’ (1985) seminal
study of ethnic groups in conflict, Gurr found that
ethnic grievances contributed indirectly to collective
violence through ethnic mobilization.
In contrast, the contemporary civil war literature has
been pioneered by scholars who take issue with such
reasoning. Positioning themselves explicitly against
grievance-based theories in political science and sociol-
ogy, Collier and Hoeffler (2004) follow in the footsteps
of earlier critics of relative deprivation (although with-
out referring to them explicitly). Very much as Snyder
and Tilly had done three decades earlier, Collier and
Hoeffler (2004, 564) point to the ubiquity of frustra-
tion around the world, asserting that this fact deprives
the theory of explanatory value: “Misperceptions of
grievances may be very common: All societies may
have groups with exaggerated grievances. In this case,
as with greed-rebellion, motive would not explain the
incidence of rebellion.” Explicitly classifying inequali-
ties as grievance-related indicators, these authors rely
on the Gini coefficient to measure the income distri-
bution among individuals. Having found no statistical
effect for this and other hardship proxies, Collier and
Hoeffler feel vindicated in their wholesale rejection of
grievances and inequality as causes of civil war. In his
best-selling book The Bottom Billion, Collier (2007, 18)
confirms these doubts:
So what causes civil war? Rebel movements themselves
justify their actions in terms of a catalogue of grievances:
repression, exploitation, exclusion. Politically motivated
academics have piled in with their own hobbyhorses, which
479
https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055411000207
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 14:23:50, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at

Horizontal Inequalities and Civil War August 2011
usually cast rebels as heroes. I have come to distrust this
discourse of grievances as self-serving.
1
In another influential study that stresses political
and institutional causes of civil war, Fearon and Laitin
(2003) present findings that cast doubt on ethnic and
political grievances as explanations of conflict onset.
Like Collier and Hoeffler, Fearon and Laitin rely on
a series of individual-level statistical proxies, includ-
ing the Gini coefficient, which provide no evidence
of economic inequality increasing the risk of conflict.
Summing up these and other studies, Laitin (2007, 23)
concludes that
ethnic grievances are commonly felt and latent; the factors
that make these grievances vital and manifest differentiate
the violent from the nonviolent cases. Ex ante measures of
grievance levels are not good predictors of the transforma-
tion of latent grievances into manifest ones. And it is the
factors that turn latent grievances into violent action that
should be considered as explanatory for that violence.
Despite these negative findings, a number of schol-
ars find the rejection of grievances and inequalities
premature. Although the poor quality of distributional
economic data within and across countries should per-
haps be reason for pause by itself,
2
the main reason
that grievance-based arguments cannot be so easily re-
jected is that these studies largely miss their theoretical
target. Insisting that conflict-inducing inequality can-
not be reduced to household-level measures of income
distribution such as the Gini coefficient, Cramer (2003)
calls for an alternative that is explicitly relational and
theoretically grounded.
3
In the concluding chapter of a
two-volume compilation of case studies testing Collier
and Hoeffler’s (2004) model, Sambanis (2005) draws
the same inference. Noting that there is a major dis-
crepancy between the quantitative nonfinding and the
repeated references to inequality in the case studies,
Sambanis (2005, 324) considers a number of explana-
tions, including problems relating to interpretation and
sampling of case evidence, as well as the fundamental
issue of aggregation level:
There may exist a relationship between inequality and
popular revolutions or class conflict, which is another rea-
son to consider disaggregating the cases of civil war. But
ethnic or secessionist wars should, in theory, be driven
more by group-based inequality . . . than by interpersonal
inequality.
A more promising way to capture the link between
uneven wealth distributions and conflict has been pro-
posed by Stewart (2008b) and her colleagues, who
1
In more recent research, Collier, Hoeffler, and Rohner (2009)
maintain that civil wars are caused by factors associated with “feasi-
bility” rather than by grievances and other types of motivations.
2
Using a different conceptualization of vertical inequality condi-
tioned on factor mobility, Boix (2008) reports a strong effect on
internal conflict.
3
Likewise arguing against misplaced individualism, Cederman and
Girardin (2007) criticize the use of the ethnolinguistic fractionaliza-
tion index as a general proxy for ethnonationalist frustration.
contrast vertical, or individual-level inequalities, with
horizontal inequalities. Defining the latter as “inequal-
ities in economic, social or political dimensions or cul-
tural status between culturally defined groups,” Stew-
art (2008a, 3) argues that to a large extent, scholars
have failed to find evidence of inequality’s war-causing
effect because of their reliance on individualist, rather
than group-based, measures of income and power dif-
ferences:
But the majority of internal conflicts are organized group
conflictsthey are neither exclusively nor primarily a mat-
ter of individuals committing acts of violence against oth-
ers. What is most often involved is group mobilization of
people with particular shared identities or goals to attack
others in the name of the group. (Stewart 2008a, 11)
Following the lead of Horowitz and Gurr, Stewart
(2008a) conceptualizes horizontal inequality broadly
by considering political, economic, social, and cultural
dimensions explicitly. Political HIs entail blocked or
limited access to central decision-making authority
within the state. The economic dimension taps the dis-
tribution of wealth among households. Social HI mea-
sures primarily groups’ uneven social access, for exam-
ple, in terms of education and societal status. Finally,
the cultural aspect captures group-level inequalities
with respect to cultural policies and symbols, including
national holidays and religious rights.
Recognizing the difficulties of measuring HIs, Stew-
art’s team has so far primarily relied on case stud-
ies rather than large-N comparisons. The picture that
emerges from this research suggests that both disad-
vantaged and advanced groups have a higher likeli-
hood of getting involved in internal conflict than groups
closer to the country average (Stewart 2008b). Yet
some quantitative researchers have attempted to gen-
eralize from the case studies to a larger set of countries.
In a pioneering statistical test, Barrows (1976) detected
an influence of group-level differences on conflict in
sub-Saharan Africa. Relying on household surveys
conducted in 39 developing countries, Østby (2008b)
finds evidence that social horizontal inequality causes
civil war, although the economic dimension appears
to be weaker (see also Østby 2008a). In a follow-up
study based on geocoded conflict and survey data from
sub-Saharan Africa, Østby, Nord
˚
as, and Rød (2009)
reach firmer conclusions, showing that both economic
and social group-level differences are likely drivers of
conflict behavior.
THEORIZING HORIZONTAL INEQUALITIES
We now turn to our own account of inequality and
conflict. The starting point of our approach to ethnona-
tionalist warfare is the realization that ethnic groups
find themselves in radically different situations for var-
ious historical reasons. Whereas some ethnic groups
came out on top of the geopolitical game, others were
conquered early on, and therefore lost out in the com-
petition for wealth and influence. Moreover, the un-
even spread of nationalism delayed mass-level political
480
https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055411000207
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 14:23:50, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at

American Political Science Review Vol. 105, No. 3
mobilization in many parts of the world, thus creating
differences in both economic and political develop-
ment that were often exploited by alien rulers (Gellner
1964). As argued by Tilly (1999), nationalism can be
thought of as a case of “categorical inequality” because
it asserts and creates paired and unequal categories, either
(a) rival aspirants to nationhood or (b) members of the
authentic nation versus others. It involves claims to prior
control over a state, hence to the exclusion of others from
that priority. It authorizes agents of the nation to subor-
dinate, segregate, stigmatize, expel, or even exterminate
others in the nation’s name. (172)
Adopting Stewart’s definition of HI, we focus on the
political and economic dimensions of HI.
4
Although
these two types of inequality are often likely to be
related, we follow Stewart in treating the distribu-
tion of power and of wealth as conceptually separate
components. Previous quantitative research has exam-
ined the role of political exclusion of ethnic groups on
the risk of civil war, but has not considered explicitly
the economic aspect of exclusion and the relationship
between the two (see e.g., Cederman, Buhaug, and
Rød 2009; Cederman and Girardin 2007; Cederman,
Wimmer, and Min 2010; though see Gurr 1993, 2000b).
By contrast, some critics of the role of ethnicity, such
as Woodward (1995), argue that alleged ethnic conflicts
are really driven by underlying economic inequalities
that lead ethnic identities to become politicized. A
strong version of this argument would hold that ethnic
political inequalities are irrelevant in the absence of
economic inequalities.
Building on our previous work, we view HIs as struc-
tural asymmetries that make ethnonationalist civil war
more likely and adopt an indirect research strategy that
explains the effect of inequality by postulating a set of
causal mechanisms. To close the gap between the struc-
tural background conditions and behavioral patterns,
we propose intermediate analytical steps.
5
First, we
postulate that objective political and economic asym-
metries can be transformed into grievances through a
process of group comparison driven by collective emo-
tions. Second, we argue that such grievances trigger
violent collective action through a process of group
mobilization.
From Horizontal Inequalities to Grievances
As opposed to objective conditions such as horizontal
inequalities, grievances are intersubjectively perceived
phenomena. As we have noted earlier in the text, this
makes them very hard to measure, but we can draw
on an extensive experimentally supported literature
4
As we have seen, HIs also involve social and cultural policies (see
Stewart 2008a). We acknowledge that these aspects may be linked to
conflict, but these conflict mechanisms fall outside the scope of this
article.
5
See Gurr (2000b, Chap. 3) for a similar theory based on four
conditions, namely the salience of ethnocultural identity, collective
incentives for action, collective-action capacity, and environmental
opportunities.
in social psychology as a way to construct plausible
mechanisms connecting structural asymmetries with
collective violence. Obviously, it may be possible to find
ways to connect HIs with conflict through causal mech-
anisms that do not feature grievances, but we leave this
possibility to other researchers to explore.
6
Before grievances can be acted upon, they need to
be cognitively linked to social identities through self-
categorization (Hogg and Abrams 1988, 21). Clearly
the salience of ethnic distinctions varies over time and
from case to case (Gurr 2000b), but once group iden-
tities become salient, members of the involved groups
are prone to make social comparisons that hinge on the
distinction between in-group and out-group categories
(Turner 1981). According to “realistic conflict theory,”
conflicting claims to scarce resources, including power,
prestige, and wealth, are likely to produce ethnocen-
tric and antagonistic intergroup relations (Tajfel and
Turner 1979). In stratified social systems, social compar-
ison reflecting superiority or inferiority should be es-
pecially likely to trigger conflict (see Horowitz 1985).
7
These processes of social comparison and intergroup
evaluation are far from emotionally neutral. As argued
by Kalyvas (2006) and Petersen (2002), attempts to
reduce the violent excesses of civil wars to entirely
calculative and cognitive processes fly in the face of
countless testimonies of the emotional escalation pro-
cesses leading to the outbreak of collective violence.
8
In particular, violations of norms of justice and equal-
ity will typically arouse feelings of anger and resent-
ment among members of the disadvantaged group.
9
As observed in a pioneering study by T. H. Marshall,
such emotional responses are present in class systems,
which “are based structurally on chronic asymmetries
of power and reward” (Barbalet 1992, 153).
What is true for cases of class resentment also ap-
plies to inequalities among ethnic groups. In agreement
with Petersen (2002), we postulate that resentment
based on intergroup comparisons involving HIs often
6
It should be noted that the presence of HIs presupposes the ex-
istence of well-defined groups (Stewart 2000), which is not a trivial
precondition (e.g., Kalyvas 2006). Although it is undoubtedly true
that modern politics is to a large extent group-based, and social life
hinges on social categories (Gellner 1964; Hogg and Abrams 1988),
we argue that the extent to which cohesive groups can actually be
said to exist is ultimately a matter of empirical analysis. Yet, be-
cause our goal is to evaluate the conflict-inducing effect of HIs, we
join Horowitz (1985), Gurr (1993; 2000b) and others in adopting
a self-consciously group-based framework, although restricting our
substantive focus to groups defined through ethnic categorization
rather than through other cleavages.
7
In addition to such direct consequences of objective differences,
“social identity theory” tells us that mere awareness of social out-
groups may be sufficient to provoke competitive behavior even in the
absence of objective issues of contention (Tajfel and Turner 1979).
8
Indeed, although social identity theorists stress the cognitive com-
ponent of group behavior, they allow for an important element of
emotional engagement, as group membership is assumed to be inti-
mately associated with self-esteem (Hogg and Abrams 1988).
9
Modern sociological theories of emotions tell us that, contrary to
the views of early crowd theorists, and contrary to lingering popular
belief, emotions are not irrational, but serve distinctly goal-directed
purposes in social and political life (e.g., Emirbayer and Goldberg
2005; Petersen 2002).
481
https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055411000207
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. University of Basel Library, on 30 May 2017 at 14:23:50, subject to the Cambridge Core terms of use, available at

Citations
More filters
Book
01 Jan 1985

1,861 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Why Men Rebel was first published in 1970 on the heels of a decade of political violence and protest not only in remote corners of Africa and Southeast Asia, but also at home in the United States as discussed by the authors.
Abstract: Why Men Rebel was first published in 1970 on the heels of a decade of political violence and protest not only in remote corners of Africa and Southeast Asia, but also at home in the United States. Forty years later, the world is riveted on uprisings in the Middle East, and the United States has been overtaken by a focus on international terrorism and a fascination with citizen movements at home and abroad. Do the arguments of 1970 apply today? Why Men Rebel lends new insight into contemporary challenges of transnational recruitment and organization, multimedia mobilization, and terrorism.

1,412 citations

Book
26 Aug 2013
TL;DR: Cederman et al. as mentioned in this paper argue that political and economic inequalities following group lines generate grievances that in turn can motivate civil war, and develop new indicators of political exclusion at the group level, and show that these exert strong effects on the risk of civil war.
Abstract: This book argues that political and economic inequalities following group lines generate grievances that in turn can motivate civil war. Lars-Erik Cederman, Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, and Halvard Buhaug offer a theoretical approach that highlights ethnonationalism and how the relationship between group identities and inequalities are fundamental for successful mobilization to resort to violence. Although previous research highlighted grievances as a key motivation for political violence, contemporary research on civil war has largely dismissed grievances as irrelevant, emphasizing instead the role of opportunities. This book shows that the alleged non-results for grievances in previous research stemmed primarily from atheoretical measures, typically based on individual data. The authors develop new indicators of political and economic exclusion at the group level, and show that these exert strong effects on the risk of civil war. They provide new analyses of the effects of transnational ethnic links and the duration of civil wars, and extended case discussions illustrating causal mechanisms.

397 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors investigated how population growth affects patterns of public unrest in urban centers within the context of crucial intervening factors like democracy, poverty, economic shocks, and ongoing civil conflict.
Abstract: For the first time in history, the majority of the world population now lives in cities. Global urbanization will continue at high speed; the world's urban population is projected to increase by more than 3 billion people between 2010 and 2050. Some of this increase will be the result of high urban fertility rates and reclassification of rural land into urban areas, but a significant portion of future urbanization will be caused by rural-to-urban migration. This migration is expected to be particularly prevalent in countries and regions most affected by the changing climate. While urban populations generally enjoy a higher quality of life, many cities in the developing world have large slums with populations that are largely excluded from access to resources, jobs, and public services. In the environmental security literature, great rural resource scarcity, causing rural to urban migration, is seen as an important source of violent conflict. This study investigates how population growth affects patterns of public unrest in urban centers within the context of crucial intervening factors like democracy, poverty, economic shocks. It utilizes a newly collected event dataset of urban social disturbance covering 55 major cities in Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa since 1960. The empirical analysis provides little support for the notion that high and increasing urban population pressure leads to a higher risk or frequency of social disorder. Instead, we find that urban disorder is primarily associated with a lack of consistent political institutions, economic shocks, and ongoing civil conflict.

385 citations


Cites background from "Horizontal Inequalities and Ethnona..."

  • ...…in and importance of economic privileges between individuals and groups, thus raising levels of dissatisfaction and grievances to the extent that it could spur violent reactions (Brennan-Galvin, 2002; Gizewski and Homer-Dixon, 1995; see Cederman et al., 2011; Østby, 2008 for empirical research)....

    [...]

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This article showed that the current prevalence of internal war is mainly the result of a steady accumulation of protracted conflicts since the 1950s and 1960s rather than a sudden change associated with a new, post-Cold War international system.
Abstract: An influential conventional wisdom holds that civil wars proliferated rapidly with the end of the Cold War and that the root cause of many or most of these has been ethnic and religious antagonisms. We show that the current prevalence of internal war is mainly the result of a steady accumulation of protracted conflicts since the 1950s and 1960s rather than a sudden change associated with a new, post-Cold War international system. We also find that after controlling for per capita income, more ethnically or religiously diverse countries have been no more likely to experience significant civil violence in this period. We argue for understanding civil war in this period in terms of insurgency or rural guerrilla warfare, a particular form of military practice that can be harnessed to diverse political agendas. The factors that explain which countries have been at risk for civil war are not their ethnic or religious characteristics but rather the conditions that favor insurgency. These include poverty—which marks financially and bureaucratically weak states and also favors rebel recruitment—political instability, rough terrain, and large populations.We wish to thank the many people who provided comments on earlier versions of this paper in a series of seminar presentations. The authors also gratefully acknowledge the support of the National Science Foundation (Grants SES-9876477 and SES-9876530); support from the Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences with funds from the William and Flora Hewlett Foundation; valuable research assistance from Ebru Erdem, Nikolay Marinov, Quinn Mecham, David Patel, and TQ Shang; sharing of data by Paul Collier.

5,994 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: Collier and Hoeffler as discussed by the authors compare two contrasting motivations for rebellion: greed and grievance, and show that many rebellions are linked to the capture of resources (such as diamonds in Angola and Sierra Leone, drugs in Colombia, and timber in Cambodia).
Abstract: Of the 27 major armed conflicts that occurred in 1999, all but two took place within national boundaries. As an impediment to development, internal rebellion especially hurts the world's poorest countries. What motivates civil wars? Greed or grievance? Collier and Hoeffler compare two contrasting motivations for rebellion: greed and grievance. Most rebellions are ostensibly in pursuit of a cause, supported by a narrative of grievance. But since grievance assuagement through rebellion is a public good that a government will not supply, economists predict such rebellions would be rare. Empirically, many rebellions appear to be linked to the capture of resources (such as diamonds in Angola and Sierra Leone, drugs in Colombia, and timber in Cambodia). Collier and Hoeffler set up a simple rational choice model of greed-rebellion and contrast its predictions with those of a simple grievance model. Some countries return to conflict repeatedly. Are they conflict-prone or is there a feedback effect whereby conflict generates grievance, which in turn generates further conflict? The authors show why such a feedback effect might be present in both greed-motivated and grievance rebellions. The authors' results contrast with conventional beliefs about the causes of conflict. A stylized version of conventional beliefs would be that grievance begets conflict, which begets grievance, which begets further conflict. With such a model, the only point at which to intervene is to reduce the level of objective grievance. Collier and Hoeffler's model suggests that what actually happens is that opportunities for predation (controlling primary commodity exports) cause conflict and the grievances this generates induce dias-poras to finance further conflict. The point of policy intervention here is to reduce the absolute and relative attraction of primary commodity predation and to reduce the ability of diasporas to fund rebel movements. This paper - a product of the Development Research Group - is part of a larger effort in the group to study civil war and criminal violence. For more on this effort, go to www.worldbank.org/research/conflict. Paul Collier may be contacted at pcollier@worldbank.org.

5,349 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The recent fallecimiento del sociólogo e historiador Charles Tilly (Lombard, Illinois, 1929-Bronx, Nueva York, 2008) puede servir de pretexto for rememorar una trayectoria investigadora sin duda excepcional, plasmada a lo largo de medio siglo en más de 600 artículos and 51 libros and monografías, that le convirtieron en el más influyente especialista
Abstract: El reciente fallecimiento del sociólogo e historiador Charles Tilly (Lombard, Illinois, 1929-Bronx, Nueva York, 2008) puede servir de pretexto para rememorar una trayectoria investigadora sin duda excepcional, plasmada a lo largo de medio siglo en más de 600 artículos y 51 libros y monografías, que le convirtieron en el más influyente especialista en el análisis de la confrontación política en su relación con los grandes procesos de cambio social. Su audiencia mixta de historiadores interesados en sus métodos de análisis innovadores y de sociólogos que buscan modelos alternativos de acción colectiva y estrategias de investigación histórica que den respuesta a las cuestiones teóricas se explica en buena parte porque empleó un lenguaje ambivalente, pero razonablemente comprensible, y una metodología que siempre aspiró a situarse en el cruce entre la historia y la sociología. Su trayectoria intelectual puede ser contada como un dilatado tránsito desde el reduccionismo estructuralista de sus orígenes hacia lo que él mismo llamó “realismo relacional”: una nueva perspectiva de observación donde las transacciones, los vínculos sociales y las conversaciones se convertían en el tejido constitutivo de la vida social.

4,833 citations

Journal ArticleDOI

4,603 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (13)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "A global comparison" ?

This paper showed that ethnic groups both above and below the country average in terms of per capita income are overrepresented in civil conflict, thus confirming what previous studies have already found within a more limited scope based on case-study research, survey data, and other sources. 

Although there is plenty of room for further data refinement in future research, the authors believe that the results presented in this article are both of considerable theoretical importance and of direct policy relevance. Although survey-based information has limited scope, it could be used to extend and validate their measurements ( see Baldwin and Huber 2010 ). Although such explanations have partly fallen out of favor in recent civil war research, this finding will hopefully contribute to convincing scholars of civil war that the frustrations driving ethnonationalist mobilization and violence can not be separated easily from economic factors. Although their proposed causal mechanisms are potentially capable of closing this explanatory gap, the authors can not provide direct evidence of their operation in this article. 

There may exist a relationship between inequality and popular revolutions or class conflict, which is another reason to consider disaggregating the cases of civil war. 

Fine-grained temporal measurements could also help developing an explicitly endogenous account of HIs, which have been kept exogenous in this study. 

Because formidable problems of data availability associated with the uneven coverage and comparability of surveys have stood in the way of assessing such “horizontal inequalities” (HIs), most scholars have had to content themselves with selective case studies or statistical samples restricted to particular world regions. 

Their spatial method becomes unreliable for small population sizes, primarily because of the low resolution of the G-Econ data and the limited precision of the population estimates for tiny groups. 

For a full sample of rebel groups and their conflict involvement, the authors rely on the Non-State Actors dataset (Cunningham, Gleditsch, and Salehyan 2009) that identifies the fighting organizations involved in civil wars (according to the Uppsala/PRIO Armed Conflicts Data, see Gleditsch et al. 2002). 

To test the hypotheses, the authors then introduce the datasets and describe their spatial method of wealth estimation in detail, including how to use the contours of the ethnic groups’ settlement areas as “cookie cutters,” which allows us to extract the relevant wealth estimates from the spatial wealth map. 

In fact, the only broadly available cross-national data source on variation in wealth within countries is the G-Econ data, developed by Nordhaus (2006; see also Nordhaus and Chen 2009). 

concluding at least tentatively that both economic and political inequality at the group level increase the risk of ethnonationalist civil war, the authors argue that the civil war literature’s tendency to downplay the importance of grievances as a source of internal conflict is both premature and misguided. 

6Before grievances can be acted upon, they need to be cognitively linked to social identities through selfcategorization (Hogg and Abrams 1988, 21). 

A more promising way to capture the link between uneven wealth distributions and conflict has been proposed by Stewart (2008b) and her colleagues, who1 In more recent research, Collier, Hoeffler, and Rohner (2009) maintain that civil wars are caused by factors associated with “feasibility” rather than by grievances and other types of motivations. 

26 Consequently, the group-size restriction almost triples the inequality coefficient reported in Model 2 without affecting the size of the standard error.