scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Intergenerational Persistence in Income and Social Class: The Impact of Within-Group Inequality

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this article, the authors derive a formal framework which relates mobility as measured by family income or earnings to mobility as defined by social class and test several alternative hypotheses to explain the difference between the trends.
Abstract
Family income is found to be more closely related to sons' earnings for a cohort born in 1970 compared with a cohort born in 1958. This result is in stark contrast with the finding on the basis of social class; intergenerational mobility for this outcome is found to be unchanged. Our aim here is to explore the reason for this divergence. We derive a formal framework which relates mobility as measured by family income or earnings to mobility as measured by social class. Building on this framework we then test several alternative hypotheses to explain the difference between the trends. We find evidence of an increase in the intergenerational persistence of the permanent component of income that is unrelated to social class. We reject the hypothesis that the observed decline in income mobility is a consequence of the poor measurement of permanent family income in the 1958 cohort.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

1
Intergenerational Persistence in Income and Social Class:
The Impact of Within-Group Inequality
Jo Blanden*, Paul Gregg** and Lindsey Macmillan**
March 2012
* Department of Economics, University of Surrey and Centre for Economic
Performance, London School of Economics
** Department of Economics, University of Bristol and Centre for Market and
Public Organisation, University of Bristol
Abstract
Family income is found to be more closely related to sons’ earnings for a cohort born in 1970
compared to one born in 1958. This result is in stark contrast to the finding on the basis of
social class; intergenerational mobility for this outcome is found to be unchanged. Our aim
here is to explore the reason for this divergence. We derive a formal framework which relates
mobility as measured by family income/earnings to mobility as measured by social class.
Building on this framework we then test a number of alternative hypotheses to explain the
difference between the trends. We find evidence of an increase in the intergenerational
persistence of the permanent component of income that is unrelated to social class. We reject
the hypothesis that the observed decline in income mobility is a consequence of the poor
measurement of permanent family income in the 1958 cohort.
JEL codes: J13, J31, Z13
Keywords: Intergenerational income mobility, social class fluidity, income inequality.
Acknowledgements:
We would like to thank Anders Björklund, Stephen Machin, Sandra McNally, Elizabeth
Washbrook, Christian Dustmann, Patrick Sturgis, Robert Erikson and John Goldthorpe for
their helpful comments. We also appreciate the comments of the editors and referees who
have helped to substantially improve the paper.

2
1. Introduction
Both economists and sociologists measure the intergenerational persistence of socio-
economic status, with economists tending to use income or earnings as the measure of status
(for surveys see Solon, 1999, Black and Devereux, 2010) while sociologists use fathers’
social class (Erikson and Goldthorpe, 1992) or an index of occupational status (Blau and
Duncan, 1967). To ascertain whether the measured extent of mobility is high or low, both
literatures have asked: i) how does mobility compare across nations? ii) has mobility
increased or decreased across time? For both of these comparisons the findings of economists
and sociologists contrast sharply for the UK.
International comparisons of income mobility place the UK as a country with low
mobility (Corak, 2006) whereas those using the measure of social class/occupational status
tend to rank it closer to the middle (Erikson and Goldthorpe 1992, Breen, 2004). Cross-
country rankings across the two approaches are very weakly correlated with each other
(Blanden, 2011). Similar ambiguity exists when comparing trends in intergenerational
mobility across time. Blanden, Goodman, Gregg and Machin (2004) find that
intergenerational income mobility decreases for a cohort born in 1970 (British Cohort Study)
compared to a cohort born in 1958 (National Child Development Study) while Goldthorpe
and Jackson (2007) find no change in social class mobility for the same datasets. Our aim in
this research is to analyse the factors responsible for the difference in the measured trends in
mobility. Our interest in trends is driven, in part, by wide acceptance of the finding of falling
mobility among politicians and commentators and its contribution to the sense that Britain
has a ‘mobility problem’ (Goldthorpe and Jackson, 2007, Blanden, 2010 and Saunders,
2010). It is therefore crucial to examine the robustness of this result given the contrary results
emanating from the literature that uses social class as the relevant measure.
In addition, we aim to draw out the conceptual links between mobility as measured by
economists and sociologists and therefore offer a fresh perspective on both literatures. The
divergent results may simply reflect underlying conceptual differences. Economists are
aiming to measure economic resources whereas class reflects workplace autonomy and
broader social capital (Goldthorpe, 2000). However, the view we adopt here is that both
approaches are trying to assess long-term or permanent socio-economic status but measure it
in different ways. In principle there are advantages and disadvantages to both measurement
approaches. Erikson and Goldthorpe use a seven-category class schema, and might therefore
only capture a limited amount of the potential variation in permanent economic status
between families (see critiques by Grusky and Weeden 2001 and McIntosh and Munk 2009).

3
In addition, mobility measures based on fathers’ social class or fathers’ earnings will ignore
the contribution of mothers. Recently economists have moved to using measures of parental
income in the first generation to account for this increasingly important contribution (Lee and
Solon, 2009, Aaronson and Mazumder, 2008). However, social class measures are sometimes
argued to be better at measuring the most important aspects of the permanent status of the
family (see Goldthorpe and McKnight, 2006). A particular difficulty with the income data
that we use from the cohort studies is that it is measured based on a single interview where
families are asked about their current income. Erikson and Goldthorpe (2010) and Saunders
(2010) suggest that social class is a more reliable measure than current income and that the
differing results between the two approaches are explicable by the poor measurement of
family income in the 1958 cohort.
We begin our analysis by formulating a framework to examine the relationship
between permanent income, social class and current income. This framework is then explored
empirically using the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS). We find that there is a
substantial portion of permanent income which is unrelated to social class. Conceptually, this
component can account for the divergent results. Section 3 of the paper outlines the main
results concerning the trend in mobility over the British cohorts using both economic and
sociological methodologies and addresses the main issues concerning data and measurement.
We focus on a number of specific measurement issues in the National Child Development
Study (NCDS) which might explain our result that income mobility is greater in the earlier
cohort compared with the later British Cohort Study (BCS). We find no evidence to support
the hypothesis that data quality or differential measurement is generating the observed
decline in mobility.
In Section 4 we detail other potential mechanisms that could generate different trends
in measured income and social class mobility. To do this we show that current income can be
decomposed into a number of different components. As mentioned above, the permanent
component can be split into the part associated with social class, and the residual part, which
we refer to as within-class permanent income. In addition current measured income will
include transitory error (the difference between current and permanent income) and finally
any mismeasurement. We then establish four alternative testable hypotheses that could
account for the diverging trends in mobility. In brief they are as follows: (1) the link between
fathers social class and family income within generations has changed, perhaps due to the
increasing role of women in accounting for family socio-economic position; (2) the

4
divergence is due to differential measurement error across the cohorts; (3) within-class
permanent income has become more important in determining children’s outcomes; and (4)
differences can be explained by a decline in the transitory component of parental income.
We find no evidence that a change in the mapping from father’s social class to income
affects our results; instead we find that a substantial part of the increased persistence across
generations can be predicted by observable short and long-run income proxies. Indeed, it is
possible to plausibly account for the full rise in income persistence through the increased
persistence of within-class permanent income. This is fully consistent with the data
examination which finds no evidence that the differential results could be explained by
measurement problems. In summary, it appears that explanation (3) above, is the most likely.
2. Measuring permanent income
2.1 The components of income
Here we set out a framework which demonstrates the relationships between permanent family
income, income at a point in time and fathers’ social class. This provides clear foundations
for our examination of the reasons behind the divergent results regarding intergenerational
mobility as measured by income or social class.
For economists, the intergenerational relationship of interest is the relationship
between parents’ permanent income and the child’s permanent income. y* represents the log
of permanent income with subscripts p and s referring to the parents and child
(son).Intergenerational mobility can be summarised by
ˆ
,
the estimate of the coefficient
from the following equation:
**
si pi i
y y u

(1)
The focus on sons here simplifies the analysis so that we are focusing on male social class in
both generations and to reduce the issues resulting from endogenous labour market
participation (a lot more important for women). Note that we are considering an asymmetric
relationship, relating combined parental income to the sons’ own earnings. We take care to
reflect this asymmetry in the rest of the paper and we explicitly consider the role of mothers
earnings as part of our first hypothesis in Section 4 below.
The intergenerational correlation, r, is also of interest in cross-cohort studies as this
adjusts
for any changes in variance that occur across cohorts.
ˆ
r
is calculated by adjusting
ˆ
by the sample standard deviations of parental income and child’s income. Björklund and

5
Jäntti (2009) urge the more widespread use of this statistic when making international
comparisons of mobility and the same arguments apply when considering trends over time.
)
ˆ
(
)
ˆ
(
ˆ
ˆ
*
*
s
p
y
y
r
(2)
Following Björklund and Jäntti (2000), permanent parental income can be
decomposed into the part that is associated with fathers social class (in our exposition social
class is denoted by a continuous variable
fi
SC
, but categorical variables are used in our
analysis; the subscript f represents father) and
.
p
v
is the parentspermanent income that is
uncorrelated with fathers’ social class.
*
pi p fi pi
y SC v

(3)
p
will reflect the relationships with fatherssocial class and of all the different components
which make up total income: fathers and mothers earnings and unearned income. This is a
point we shall return to later. The child’s permanent income can also be split into similar
components: the part that is related to the child’s own class and the part that is independent of
this.
*
si s si si
y SC v

(4)
Unfortunately, permanent income is generally not available for intergenerational research
(see Solon, 1992 for the first discussion of resulting biases) and the British cohort studies
suffer from this limitation. Measured current parental income is permanent income plus the
deviation between current measured income and permanent income (
pi
e
). Later in the
analysis we will explore the components that make up this term, but for now we consider it to
be anything which leads to a difference between measured and permanent income. Measures
of current income are related to these components as follows:
pipifippi
evSCy
(5)
sisisissi
evSCy
(6)
Under classical measurement error assumptions that the level of measured
i
y
is uncorrelated
with the size of the total error and that errors are uncorrelated across generations it is
straightforward to show that any error in measuring parental permanent income will lead to a

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Cross‐country rankings in intergenerational mobility: a comparison of approaches from economics and sociology

TL;DR: In this article, the relative level of intergenerational mobility, whether classified by income, education, or social class, is summarized and explanations for the differences in earnings and education persistence are presented.
Journal ArticleDOI

Education and Family Background: Mechanisms and Policies

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors summarize and evaluate recent empirical research on education and family background, focusing on two related but distinct motivations for this topic: equality of opportunity and the child development perspective.
Journal ArticleDOI

Measuring mortality and the burden of adult disease associated with adverse childhood experiences in England: a national survey

TL;DR: Radically different life-course trajectories are associated with exposure to increased ACEs, and interventions to prevent ACEs are available but rarely implemented at scale.

What Money Can't Buy: Family Income and Children's Life Chances

TL;DR: In this article, a book authored by Susan Mayer, Associate Professor of the Graduate School, University of Chicago, tries to entertain the idea at the same time confirm the reality of poverty it's immediate address and some erroneous approach for its alleviation.
Journal ArticleDOI

Parental education, class and income over early life course and children's achievement

TL;DR: The authors used three-level random effects linear regression models and decompose family-level variance of siblings' ISEI by each measure of parental status and found that the largest proportion of children's outcomes explained by these parental measures is shared and cannot be decomposed into independent effects.
References
More filters
Book ChapterDOI

Intergenerational Mobility in the Labor Market

TL;DR: The authors summarizes what has been learned from recent research on intergenerational transmission of earnings status, using a simple theoretical model to highlight several key concepts, and discusses the connections among three related empirical literatures: on sibling correlations in earnings, on the intragenerational elasticity of offspring's earnings with respect to parents' earnings or income, and on neighborhood effects.
Book

What Money Can't Buy: Family Income and Children's Life Chances

TL;DR: More evidence on the "true" effect of income trends in parents' income and children's outcomes was presented in this article. But, the authors did not consider the effect of factors such as the source of income, psychological well-being, and parent's stress.
Book ChapterDOI

Social mobility in Europe

TL;DR: In this paper, a key distinction is drawn between observed patterns of social mobility, sometimes referred to as "absolute mobility", and social fluidity, where mobility is understood simply as movement between class origins and class destinations.
Book

On Sociology: Numbers, Narratives, and the Integration of Research and Theory

TL;DR: On Sociology as discussed by the authors is a collection of essays from the last ten years by one of the best-known and influential British sociologist, John H. Goldthorpe.
Journal ArticleDOI

Life-cycle variation in the association between current and lifetime earnings

TL;DR: This article found that the relationship between current and lifetime earnings departs substantially from the textbook errors-in-variables model in ways that vary systematically over the life cycle, which can enable more appropriate analysis of, and correction for, errors in variance bias in any research that uses current earnings to proxy for lifetime earnings.
Related Papers (5)