scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Is Fiscal Adjustment More Durable When The IMF is Involved? 1

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this paper, the authors investigated the impact of IMF conditionality on 112 countries during the 1990s and found that, while the overall fiscal balance improved in most of them, the composition of this improvement differed.
Abstract
This paper investigates fiscal developments in 112 countries during the 1990s. It finds that while the overall fiscal balance improved in most of them, the composition of this improvement differed. In countries without IMF-supported programmes, revenues increased modestly and expenditure declined sharply, while in programme countries both post-programme revenue and expenditure declined. However, in countries with programmes that included fiscal structural conditions, the adjustment was effected primarily through sharp expenditure compression. No evidence of a statistically significant impact of IMF conditionality was found. Moreover, fiscal developments were influenced by cyclical factors and by the general stance of macroeconomic policies.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Is Fiscal Adjustment More Durable When
The IMF is Involved?
1
ALES
ˇ
BULI
´
R
ˇ
1
& SOOJIN MOON
2
1
International Monetary Fund. E-mail: abulir@imf.org;
2
Department of Economics, University of California, Los Angeles, CA, USA.
E-mail: sjmoon@ucla.edu
This paper investigates fiscal developments in 112 countries during the 1990s. It
finds that while the overall fiscal balance improved in most of them, the
composition of this improvement differed. In countries without IMF-supported
programmes, revenues increased modestly and expenditure declined sharply, while
in programme countries both post-programme revenue and expenditure declined.
However, in countries with programmes that included fiscal structural conditions,
the adjustment was effected primarily through sharp expenditure compression. No
evidence of a statistically significant impact of IMF conditionality was found.
Moreover, fiscal developments were influenced by cyclical factors and by the general
stance of macroeconomic policies.
Comparative Economic Studies (2004) 46, 373–399. doi:10.1057/palgrave.ces.8100051
Keywords: IMF-supported programmes, conditionality, fiscal policy, general
evaluation estimator
JEL Classifications: F33, H30
INTRODUCTION
What determines the composition of fiscal adjustment and does it differ
between countries with IMF-supported programmes and those without such
arrangements? Moreover, how effective is IMF structural conditionality for
post-programme fiscal developments? This paper attempts to answer these
1
The authors are indebted to Tim Lane and Alex Mourmouras for extensive discussions. We are
also grateful for helpful comments from George Anayiotos, Martin C
ˇ
iha
´
k, Christina Daseking, Kamil
Dybczak, Gervan Fearon, Rex Ghosh, Sanjeev Gupta, Javier Hamann, Eduardo Ley, Paolo Mauro,
Alex Segura Ubiergo, Kater
ˇ
ina S
ˇ
´
dkova
´
, Alun Thomas, Jaroslaw Wieczorek and two anonymous
referees as well as participants at the 2002 Atlantic Economic Society conference, 2002 Czech
Economic Society conference, 2003 International Institute of Public Finance conference, and seminar
participants at the International Monetary Fund. Anna Ivanova kindly shared some data with us.
Comparative Economic Studies, 2004, 46, (373–399)
r 2004 ACES. All rights reserved. 0888-7233/04 $30.00
www.palgrave-journals.com/ces

questions by investigating the fiscal developments in 112 countries during the
1990s, some with and some without IMF-supported programmes.
A central objective of IMF-supported programmes has been to reduce
external imbalances (International Monetary Fund, 1998). This often requires
bringing the budget under control: first, fiscal profligacy often causes current
account deficits and, second, even if the initial budgetary position is
sustainable, additional fiscal tightening may be needed if the domestic
currency comes under pressure (Ghosh et al., 2002). This adjustment has
been part of broader medium–term macroeconomic programmes that also
encompass supply side structural reforms relevant for external stability.
This paper examines post-programme fiscal developments in countries
with and without an IMF-supported programme. It finds significant diff-
erences in the composition of adjustment between programme and non-
programme countries as well as large differences among programme
countries. In nonprogramme countries, revenue increased modestly and
expenditure declined sharply, while in programme countries both revenue
and expenditure declined during the post-programme period. Moreover, in
IMF-supported programmes that included structural conditions, the adjust-
ment was effected primarily through sharp expenditure compression in order
to offset revenue declines. We did not find any evidence that fiscal structural
conditions improved revenue performance after the end of the programme.
Fiscal developments were strongly affected by the business cycle and, to
some extent, by the general stance of macroeconomic policies.
This paper is organised as follows. First, we review the stylised facts and
define the sample. Second, we describe the techniques used in our estima-
tions. Third, we present and discuss our results. The final section concludes.
IMF PROGRAMMES AND FISCAL DEVELOPMENTS
How to measure the impact of IMF-supported programmes?
What is the impact of IMF-supported programmes on fiscal adjustment? In the
literature, three different influences have been construed. One view is that
these programmes provide external resources beyond the financing provided
by the IMF itself to the extent that they have a catalytic effect; thus,
adjustments take place at lower costs than in the absence of such an arrange
ment (Cottarelli and Curzio, 2002). Hence, IMF-supported programmes can
be associated with either smaller or larger fiscal deficits, depending on the
nature of the shock and the design of the programme. This description is close
to the official IMF view of its role (Dhonte, 1997; Haque and Khan, 1998; Bird,
2002; Bird and Rowland, 2002). A second view is that these programmes
A Bulı
´
r
ˇ
& S Moon
Fiscal Adjustment and the IMF
374
Comparative Economic Studies

prescribe excessively fast adjustment, by uniformly requiring monetary tightening,
expenditure cuts, and higher taxes, hurting both the poor and businesses in the
process. A third view is that IMF-supported programmes delay fundamental
reforms by merely treating the symptoms of financing needs by repeated
lending to crisis-prone and structurally unstable countries (Bird, 1996).
Which view is the closest to reality? Empirical assessments of the impact
of IMF-supported programmes are notoriously complex. Countries’ macro-
economic performance is influenced by secular forces, external shocks,
structural reforms, and temporary availability of IMF-linked financing. The
initial conditions and exogenous shocks need to be separated from the effects
of IMF-supported arrangements, because countries that do not undertake
such programmes are not an appropriate control group for IMF-programme
countries (Krueger, 1998). An appropriate technique is the general evaluation
estimator (GEE), due to Goldstein and Montiel (1986), which constructs
counterfactual economic policies first and then tests the importance of
IMF-supported programmes. This approach was successfully tested, inter
alia, by Khan (1990), Conway (1994), and Dicks-Mireaux et al. (2000).
The question asked is two-fold. First, what are the factors that lead to IMF-
supported programmes? The answer to this question is well known: economic
variables, such as the current account balance, inflation, international
reserves, debt service, GDP per capita, and so on, together with participation
in previous programmes explain reasonably well the approval of an IMF-
supported arrangement (Conway, 1994; Knight and Santaella, 1997; Bird et al.,
2000). Knight and Santaella (1997) found that policy commitments made by
recipient governments matter for the programme approval as well; if the
authorities promise stronger adjustment, the Fund is more likely to approve a
bigger loan. Barro and Lee (2002) added to the list of variables a bigger IMF
quota, more IMF professional staff of that country origin, and a closer
political/economic connection to the major shareholders of the IMF. The last
variable is intuitive ‘better connected countries are likely to get more money
with fewer strings attached (Bird, 2002). In contrast, the literature found no
relationship between political economy variables (political institutions, quality
of bureaucracy, and so on) and the participation in an IMF-supported
programme. In other words, public sector policies are essentially the same in
democracies and nondemocracies (Mulligan et al., 2003).
Second, and this is the question we are interested in, what are the
macroeconomic effects of IMF-supported programmes? This strand of the
literature has a few well-established stylised facts as well. IMF-supported
programmes were found to be associated with an improved post-programme
current account balance. Inflation slowed down and real growth recovered,
however, typically by less than what was projected under the programme
A Bulı
´
r
ˇ
&SMoon
Fiscal Adjustment and the IMF
375
Comparative Economic Studies

(Conway, 1994; Schadler et al., 1995; Bird, 2002; Ghosh et al., 2002). In
contrast, Barro and Lee (2002) reported opposite results–participation in
IMF-supported programme was found to lower growth and investment.
Unfortunately, Barro and Lee controlled neither for the repeated use of Fund
loans nor for country’s adherence to the policies agreed in the programme. At
the same time, limited work has been done on longer-term fiscal effects of
IMF-supported programmes.
The macroeconomic effects of IMF-supported programmes depended, on
the one hand, on borrowing countries’ domestic political economy (Ivanova
et al., 2003, Khan and Sharma, 2001; Boughton and Mourmouras, 2002) and,
on the other hand, on the technical design of the programme (conditionality)
or the amount of money borrowed (Schadler et al., 1995). Regarding the
former, strong special interests, political instability, inefficient bureaucracies,
lack of political cohesion, and ethno-linguistic divisions weakened pro-
gramme implementation. Adjustment programmes were more successful in
countries where they augmented home-grown reforms than in countries
where the Fund and/or other donors tried to impose them on unwilling
authorities. Regarding the latter, it seems that the impact of Fund
conditionality was governed by a ‘Laffer-curve’ relationship, whereby a
few, well-targeted conditions had a positive impact on economic perfor-
mance, but too many or too intrusive conditions hindered such performance
(Collier et al., 1997; Dollar and Svensson, 2000; Goldstein, 2000; Bird, 2001).
To this end, we will use the IMF’s Monitoring of Fund Arrangements
Database (MONA) that collects information on conditionality under IMF-
supported programmes and which was first utilised in International Monetary
Fund (2001). Surprisingly, assessments of structural conditionality have been
rare and this paper is a first empirical exercise to address its role in
macroeconomic adjustment in a systematic fashion.
What is IMF conditionality?
Conditionality is an explicit link between the approval (or continuation) of the
Fund’s financing and the implementation of certain aspects of the authorities’
policy programme (Guitia
´
n, 1981). The conditions may be either quantitative
(say, a limit on reserve money growth) or structural (say, the introduction of a
value-added tax).
2
In general, conditionality is designed to encompass policy
measures that are critical to programme objectives or key internal data targets
that sound warning bells if policies veer off track. Whereas in the mid-1980s
structural conditionality in IMF-supported arrangements was rare, by the mid-1990s
2
IMF-supported programmes typically do not stipulate quantitative fiscal conditions in terms
of, say, the primary fiscal balance or domestic fiscal revenue.
A Bulı
´
r
ˇ
& S Moon
Fiscal Adjustment and the IMF
376
Comparative Economic Studies

about half of all programmes included structural conditions. The average
number of structural conditions per programme year increased from two in 1987
to more than 16 in 1997 (International Monetary Fund, 2001; Boughton, 2001).
These developments were the result of several forces. First, the IMF
gradually placed more emphasis on supply-side reforms as compared to demand
management. Second, the IMF’s involvement in low-income and transition
countries was focused on the alleviation of structural imbalances and rigidities
prevalent in these economies (Mercer-Blackman and Unigovskaya, 2000).
Finally, the experience with monetary and fiscal policies indicated that their
success depends critically on structural conditions. Indeed, most structural con-
ditions were in the core area of IMF expertise (International Monetary Fund, 2001).
In this paper, we focus on three main types of structural conditions
tabulated in the MONA database: (i) prior actions, which are stipulated as
preconditions to the approval of an IMF-supported programme, (ii) structural
performance criteria, fulfilment of which is a formal precondition for
programme continuation, and (iii) structural benchmarks, which are agreed
with the authorities and monitored by the IMF staff, but are not a formal
precondition for programme continuation. The majority of conditions were
structural benchmarks, while structural performance criteria were the least
numerous conditions. The extent of structural conditionality was in part
determined endogenously countries with a large reform agenda or history of
poor reform performance tended to get more conditions, although no clear-cut
answers as to why some countries have many more conditions than others are
available (International Monetary Fund, 2001). If anything, distribution of
structural conditions was correlated regionally and with the length of the
programmes (quite predictably, 12-months IMF-supported programmes tend
to have fewer supply side conditions than 3-year programmes).
All but two IMF-supported programmes with structural conditionality in
our sample (33 countries during 1993–1999) contained at least one fiscal
condition.
3
Indeed, fiscal structural conditionality was the most common area
of structural conditionality, comprising about 50 percent of all conditions.
While most fiscal conditions were designed as neutral vis-a
`
-vis the overall
fiscal balance, some conditions were geared towards either higher revenue or
lower expenditure. We classify all those measures according to their expected
revenue or expenditure impact and present their summary in Table 1.
4
Based
3
Throughout the paper, we used a sample of 112 countries, of which 48 countries did not have
a programme during the sample period, and 31 and 33 countries had programmes without and with
structural conditions, respectively. See the fourth section for the list of countries.
4
For example, we classified the ‘introduction of ad valorem excise duties’ as a revenue-
increasing condition; a ‘reduction in civil service positions’ as an expenditure-lowering condition;
and the ‘adoption of accounting system of the Treasury’ as a neutral condition.
A Bulı
´
r
ˇ
&SMoon
Fiscal Adjustment and the IMF
377
Comparative Economic Studies

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Global Horse Trading: IMF loans for votes in the United Nations Security Council

TL;DR: The authors investigated whether temporary members of the United Nations Security Council receive favorable treatment from the International Monetary Fund (IMF) using panel data for 197 countries over the period from 1951 to 2004.
Journal ArticleDOI

IMF conditionality and development policy space, 1985–2014

TL;DR: The authors revisited two long-standing controversies: Has the policy content of IMF programs evolved to allow for more policy space? Do these programmes now allow for the protection of labour and social policies?
Journal ArticleDOI

IMF conditionality: theory and evidence

TL;DR: The authors analyzes whether and to what extent reliance on conditionality is appropriate to guarantee the revolving character of the resources of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and presents theoretical arguments in favor of conditionality, and those against the use of conditions.
Book

The Political Economy of the United Nations Security Council: Money and Influence

TL;DR: A theory of trading Security Council votes for aid was proposed in this article, where punishments, threats, and rewards were used to punish, threaten, and reward members of the Security Council.
Journal ArticleDOI

Politics and IMF Conditionality

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors propose to measure political importance using temporary membership on the United Nations Security Council and analyze a newly available dataset on the level of conditionality attached to (a maximum of) 314 IMF arrangements with 101 countries over the 1992 to 2008 period.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The Generalized War of Attrition

TL;DR: In this article, the authors model a war of attrition with N + K firms competing for N prizes and show that the K − 1 lowest-value firms drop out instantaneously, even though each firm's value is private information to itself.
Journal ArticleDOI

Evaluating Fund Stabilization Programs with Multicountry Data: Some Methodological Pitfalls (Evaluation des programmes de stabilisation du Fonds à partir de données sur divers pays: quelques écueils méthodologiques) (La evaluación de los programas de estabilización del Fondo con los datos de diversos países: algunas dificultades metodológicas)

TL;DR: This paper showed that unless the program group is randomly selected, observed outcomes in the control group may be systematically different from what would have happened in the program-country group in the absence of programs.
Journal ArticleDOI

Evaluating the effect of IMF lending to low-income countries

TL;DR: In this paper, a modified control-group methodology is used to measure the effect of IMF support on three key variables, including output growth, inflation, and the external debt rservice ratio.
Journal ArticleDOI

Do IMF programmes have a catalytic effect on other international capital flows

TL;DR: In this paper, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) plays an important catalysing role in mobilizing international capital for developing countries and countries in transition, but the interaction between current institutional arrangements and international capital markets has yet to be answered.
Posted Content

Whither the World Bank and the IMF

TL;DR: The authors assesses the possible future directions and roles of the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank and concludes that both institutions played valuable roles earlier on, but for both institutions, the world has changed, and the questions as to their future are important.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (13)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Is fiscal adjustment more durable when the imf is involved?" ?

This paper investigates fiscal developments in 112 countries during the 1990s. 

The findings in this paper are not definitive and the possibilities for further research are extensive. Second, the policy reaction function can be specified differently, reflecting, for example, policies that would stabilise the debt-to-GDP ratio or that would be based on ‘ fiscal rules ’. 

Regarding the former, strong special interests, political instability, inefficient bureaucracies, lack of political cohesion, and ethno-linguistic divisions weakened programme implementation. 

in IMF-supported programmes that included structural conditions, the adjustment was effected primarily through sharp expenditure compression in order to offset revenue declines. 

Fp rog ram me d u mm ya0 .01 3 8(0 .88 )0 .01 0 7(0 .67 )0 .01 8 0(0 .85 )Co n diti ona li tyva ri able sSt ruct u ral con d itio n alit y(d u mm y)b0 .04 0 7(3 .10 )0 .03 8 9(3 .19 )0 .03 6 8(3 .20 )0 .03 2 4(4 .01 )0 .06 2 0(4 .49 )0 .04 9 7(4 .12 )R 20 .45 40 .44 90 .50 50 .47 00 .31 90 .32 20 .37 10 .33 70 .44 80 .45 20 .53 40 .50 3Lo g -lik elih o o d1 7 6 .81 7 6 .31 8 2 .31 7 8 .41 6 6 .71 6 6 .91 7 1 .11 6 8 .21 4 4 .11 4 4 .61 5 2 .51 4 9 .3N u mb ero fo b serv atio n s1 1 21 1 21 1 21 1 21 0 91 0 91 0 91 0 99 79 79 79 7N o rmal ity test [w2 (2,2 )]1 6 .41 2 4 .12 9 .26 2 2 .82 2 6 .83 2 5 .54 2 3 .63 2 3 .22 2 1 .23 1 6 .34 1 8 .94 2 6 .62H eter o sced asti city test (F) 1 .36 1 .05 1 .02 1 .55 0 .52 0 .77 0 .64 0 .96 0 .72 1 .48 0 .92 0 .39 

The structural conditionality variables were negative and significant, suggesting relative expenditure compression in countries with a structural conditionality of 2 percentage points of GDP or more. 

The fiscal balance improved in two-thirds of all countries by an average of 2 percentage points of GDP between the pre-programme and post-programme periods or between 1993 and 1999 for the nonprogramme countries (Figure 1 and Table 2). 

post–programme fiscal performance in those countries was driven by accelerating expenditure compression, which may not be a bad thing, provided, for example, the pre–programme level of spending was wasteful or that a statist budget was replaced with a less intrusive one. 

An appropriate technique is the general evaluation estimator (GEE), due to Goldstein and Montiel (1986), which constructs counterfactual economic policies first and then tests the importance of IMF-supported programmes. 

15 Gupta et al. (2002) reported that the probability of a reversal in fiscal adjustment was as high as 70 percent at the end of the second post-programme year for low-income countries. 

Providing the macroeconomic programme remained on track, the missed condition would likely be waived, the likelihood of waivers being positively related to the political clout of individual countries (Bird, 2002). 

The magnitude of the post–programme fiscal improvement was not uniform, however, and nonprogramme countries improved their fiscal balances by more than programme countries: 3 and 12 of a percentage points of GDP, respectively. 

the nature of the initial disequilibrium differed across countries: in nonstructural programme countries, GDP declined more sharply prior to the programme and their rates of inflation and GDP per capita were higher (Table 3).