scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Learning by Devaluating: A Supply-Side Effect of Competitive Devaluation

TL;DR: In this article, the learning by doing (LBD) effect has substantial, both quantitative and qualitative, consequences for the international transmission of monetary policy, and it is shown that LBD increases the harmful effect of competitive devaluation on foreign output by 85-125%.
Abstract: This study shows that the learning by doing (LBD) effect has substantial, both quantitative and qualitative, consequences for the international transmission of monetary policy. LDB implies that a country can increase its productivity-increasing skill level, at the expense of the neighbor, by competitive devaluation engineered through low interest rates. If measured by the cumulative change in output after 12 quarters, LBD increases the harmful effect of competitive devaluation on foreign output by 85–125%, when compared to the case without it. If LBD is sufficiently strong and the cross-country substitutability is high (low), it reverses the effect of monetary policy on foreign (domestic) welfare into negative (positive). Moreover, a combination of a high cross-country substitutability and a sufficiently strong LDB effect implies that competitive devaluation increases both domestic output and welfare, at the expense of foreign output and welfare.

Summary (3 min read)

1 Introduction

  • During the recent global financial crisis, the U.S. Federal Reserve implemented expansionary monetary policy by lowering the short-term nominal interest rate to the zero-lower bound.
  • Porter (1990) argues that depreciations can be harmful, because an overvalued exchange rate can be better for productivity growth, by forcing higher productivity growth in the tradedgoods sector.
  • Moreover, they find that faster productivity growth is partly driven by the LBD effect.
  • They emphasise that the empirical labour economics literature has shown the following results:.
  • The LBD mechanism also has a qualitative implication for the welfare effects of monetary policy where the cross-country substitutability is low.

2 Model

  • I lay out a two-country open economy model.
  • Its innovation is the introduction of LBD into the production function, following the idea of Chang et al. (2002).
  • The world consists of two countries: home and foreign.
  • In the presentation of the model, I discuss only domestic equations, if the equations are symmetric across countries.

2.1.1 Preferences

  • The term is the elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign goods, which is referred to as the cross-country substitutability.
  • These equations show that households allocate their total consumption between domestic and foreign goods, taking into account their relative prices and the cross-country substitutability.
  • All prices are expressed in local currency terms, although firms set their prices in the producer’s currency.
  • (5) The corresponding foreign indexes are defined in a similar way.
  • The purchasing power parity holds: *ttt PSP .

2.1.2 Budget Constraints

  • The foreign economy is identical to the domestic economy, with one notable exception: Foreign households can hold both domestic and foreign bonds; whereas domestic households can only hold domestic bond.
  • The use of the Taylor rule implies that the model must be stationary.
  • The log-linear version of UIP with a risk premium ( ) can be written as tttttt DSSEii ˆˆˆˆ) Equation (8) shows that the household has to pay a small cost if its bond holdings are not equal to their initial steady-state level (i.e., zero).
  • (12) Equations (9) and (10) are the Euler equations for optimal domestic and foreign consumption, respectively.

2.2 Monetary Policy

  • The central banks in both countries follow the log-linear Taylor rule with interest rate smoothing, as follows: titttt iyPi ,11321 ˆ)ˆ)(1(ˆ , (13) 6.
  • The empirical evidence supports the view that monetary policy shocks cause deviations from UIP (e.g., Faust and Roger, 2003; and Bluedorn and Bowdler, 2011).
  • The monetary policy rule shows that the inflation target is zero.
  • Therefore, the deviation of output from the initial steady state measures the output gap.
  • The central bank responds directly to the deviations of output from the initial level.

2.3.1 Skill Level, Demand and Profits

  • Chang et al. (2002) assume that the skill level of the household depends on hours worked in the past, and that the skill level raises the effective unit of labour supplied by the household.
  • The stock of the skill level evolves according to the following log-linear equation: )(ˆˆˆ 1 zxx ttt , (14) where 10 and 0 are parameters.
  • The firm minimises its costs, )(zw tt , subject to the production function (15).

2.3.2 Price Setting

  • (19) Under flexible prices, the price is simply a mark-up over the marginal cost.
  • Equations (16) and (19) demonstrate that an increase in the skill level is like a productivity shock that reduces the price of the domestic good.
  • Following Calvo (1983), I introduce nominal rigidities by assuming that each firm may reset its price with a probability of 1 in each period, independently of other firms and time passed since the last price adjustment.

2.4 Symmetric Equilibrium

  • Every firm that changes its price in any given period chooses the same price and output.
  • The price setting framework means that each period, a fraction of 1 of firms sets a new price, while the remaining firms keep their price unchanged.
  • (24) Equation (23) is the Calvo-weighted price index of domestic goods.
  • The model is log-linearized around a symmetric steady state, where initial net foreign assets are zero ( 00D ) and the initial skill level is normalized to one ( 00x ).
  • The consolidated budget constraint, in the case of a symmetric equilibrium, implies that )(00 zyC .

3 Choice of Parameter Values

  • The rationale for the choice of parameter values is as follows: Periods are defined as quarters, therefore =0.99.
  • Gopinath and Rigobon (2008) find that the trade weighted median price duration is 10.6 months for U.S. imports and 12.8 months for U.S. exports.
  • Chang et al. (2002) use a Bayesian approach and micro level data to estimate these parameters.
  • Therefore, a unit increase in the number of hours worked today increases the skill level in the next period by 0.11 units, and the depreciation rate of the skill level is 20%.9.

4.1 Method of Welfare Analysis

  • The method used for welfare analysis is as follows: I first analyse the change in period-byperiod utility.
  • Then, I calculate the discounted present value (PDV) of the change in utility.
  • The PDV value of the change in utility is calculated as 8.
  • On the other hand, Sutherland (2006) argues that typical estimates for the average elasticity across all traded goods are in the range of 5 to 6.

4.4 Sensitivity Analysis

  • The next step is to assess how responsive the international effects of monetary policy are to changes in parameter values, which govern the strength )( and duration )( of LBD.
  • These imply a stronger effect of employment on the skill level, and a faster depreciation rate of the skill level.
  • Table 5 shows the cumulative change in output.
  • On one hand, the improvement in the foreign terms of trade implies that foreign consumption increases despite a fall in output.
  • Table 7 shows the effects of the new parameterisation on output when cross-country substitutability is 1.5.

5 Conclusions

  • This paper analyses the consequences of LBD for the international transmission of monetary policy.
  • This mechanism implies that demand-driven business cycles affect the supply side of the economy.
  • LBD implies that this, in turn, leads to an increase in the U.S. skill level, which not only lowers the relative price of U.S. goods even further, but also increases the supply of U.S. goods.
  • If the elasticity of substitution between U.S. and foreign goods is low, LBD reverses to positive the effect of U.S. interest rate reductions on U.S. welfare.
  • The United States can increase not only its output, but also its welfare at the expense of the rest of the world.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors analyzed the implications of hysteresis for fiscal policy in a DSGE model and showed that the welfare multiplier is larger in the presence of hystresis.

23 citations


Cites background or methods from "Learning by Devaluating: A Supply-S..."

  • ...We assume, unlike Chang et al. (2002) and Tervala (2013), that fluctuations in employment can affect TFP quasi-permanently....

    [...]

  • ...As in Tervala (2013), the level of TFP evolves according to the following log-linear equation: ât(z) = φât−1(z) + µˆ̀t−1 (z) , (10) where 0 ≤ φ ≤ 1 and µ are parameters....

    [...]

  • ...To model endogenous changes in TFP, we add a simple learningby-doing mechanism into the production function, following the formulation of Tervala (2013), based on the idea of Chang et al. (2002)....

    [...]

  • ...Following this, Tervala (2013) assumes that the level of TFP accumulates over time according to past employment....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the effects of learning by doing resulting from the production of a final good on economic growth in a region that is creative in the sense of Richard Florida are studied.
Abstract: We study the effects of learning by doing resulting from the production of a final good on economic growth in a region that is creative in the sense of Richard Florida. Firms in this region use creative and physical capital to produce output. We model learning by doing formally and our analysis of the working of this creative region leads to four results. First, we derive analytic expressions for the growth rates of physical capital and technology. Second, we draw phase diagrams and show that in the steady state, the preceding two growth rates must be equal. Third, we show that the economy of our creative region converges to a balanced growth path (BGP) in which the growth rates of physical capital, technology, and the output of the final good are identical. Finally, we investigate the impact that an increase in the savings rate has on the economic growth of our creative region in the long run.

15 citations


Cites background from "Learning by Devaluating: A Supply-S..."

  • ...The object of inquiry in a recent paper by Batabyal and Nijkamp (2010) is a two-sector 4 See Chou and Wong (2001), Goh and Wan (2005), Kutsoati and Zabojnik (2005), D’Albis et al. (2012) and Tervala (2013) for a more detailed corroboration of this claim....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors show that the level of banks leverage, which may be imposed by banks regulation, affects the steady state level of output, employment and consumption, as might be expected in a non-Modigliani-Miller world.
Abstract: In a NK model with two types of rational agents, savers and capitalists, and non- maximizing banks, nancial shocks do a¤ect the macroeconomic dynamics depending on banksbehaviour as for their leverage ratio. We rst show that the level of banks leverage - which may be imposed by banks regulation - a¤ects the steady state level of output, employment and consumption, as might be expected in a non-Modigliani- Miller world. Di¤erent banks behaviour after a shock has widely di¤erent e¤ects on the macroeconomic dynamics: passive leverage results to be shock absorbing and capable of neutralizing an initial nancial shock, whilst procyclical behaviour implies higher and more persistent instability and distributive e¤ects than the constant lever- age behaviour. Finally, we show that the interaction of procyclical leverage with hysteresis in output and employment stregthens the persistence of nancial shocks.

12 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This article examined the United States' trade balance with Chile, both at the aggregate level and for 49 individual industries, and found that most effects concentrated among certain manufactures, with agricultural products and raw materials responding less to currency movements than do other commodities.

5 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This article showed that the welfare costs of recessions are huge (negligible) in the New Keynesian model with (without) hysteresis and showed that an empirically observed degree of hystresis increases the welfare cost of a recession by a factor of 121.

5 citations

References
More filters
Posted Content
TL;DR: This paper developed a stochastic new open economy macroeconomic model based on sticky nominal wages to analyze the effects of the monetary regime on welfare, expected output, and the expected terms of trade.
Abstract: The paper develops a simple stochastic new open economy macroeconomic model based on sticky nominal wages. Explicit solution of the wage-setting problem under uncertainty allows one to analyze the effects of the monetary regime on welfare, expected output, and the expected terms of trade. Despite the potential interplay between imperfections due to sticky wages and monopoly, the optimal monetary policy rule has a closed-form solution. To motivate our model, we show that observed correlations between terms of trade and exchange rates are more consistent with our traditional assumptions about nominal rigidities than with a popular alternative based on local-currency pricing.

753 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: This paper examined the frequency of price changes for 350 categories of goods and services covering about 70% of consumer spending, based on unpublished data from the BLS for 1995 to 1997, and found much more frequent price changes, with half of prices lasting less than 4.3 months.
Abstract: We examine the frequency of price changes for 350 categories of goods and services covering about 70% of consumer spending, based on unpublished data from the BLS for 1995 to 1997. Compared with previous studies we find much more frequent price changes, with half of prices lasting less than 4.3 months. The frequency of price changes differs dramatically across categories. We exploit this variation to ask how inflation for 'flexible-price goods' (goods with frequent changes in individual prices) differs from inflation for 'sticky-price goods' (those displaying infrequent price changes). Compared to the predictions of popular sticky price models, actual inflation rates are far more volatile and transient, particularly for sticky-price goods. The data appendix for this paper can be found at http://www.nber.org/data-appendix/w9069/

642 citations


"Learning by Devaluating: A Supply-S..." refers result in this paper

  • ...This is consistent with the estimates of Bils and Klenow (2004), which are based on U.S. retail prices....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: The authors construct a dynamic general equilibrium model in which the typical industry colludes by threatening to punish deviations from an implicitly agreed upon pricing path and calibrate a linearized version of the model using methods similar to those of Kydland and Prescott (1982).
Abstract: We construct a dynamic general equilibrium model in which the typical industry colludes by threatening to punish deviations from an implicitly agreed upon pricing path We argue that models of this type explain better than do competitive models the way in which the economy responds to aggregate demand shocks When we calibrate a linearized version of the model using methods similar to those of Kydland and Prescott (1982), we obtain predictions concerning the economy's response to changes in military spending which are close to the response we estimate with postwar US data

595 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors showed that monetary policy shocks may lead to large uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) deviations, which is consistent with overshooting, and implies that the over-shooting cannot be driven by Dornbusch's mechanism.

347 citations

Book ChapterDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors discuss the real exchange rate misalignment in the context of currency exchange and propose a solution to solve the problem of currency misalignments in the currency market.
Abstract: Сегодня концепция отклонения реального курса от своего равновесного уровня (real exchange rate misalignment) является стандартной в международной макроэкономической теории и политике. Однако до сих пор нет единого мнения по поводу того, что считать показателем отклонения и как его строить. В данной статье показатель отклонения строится на основе расширенной модели IS-LM и оценивается с помощью широкого массива данных по развитым и развивающимся странам. Затем эта оценка используется в качестве одной из объясняющих переменных в регрессии для темпа экономического роста. В статье получен интересный результат - связь между отклонением реального курса и темпом роста имеет явно нелинейный характер. Только значительное завышение курса по сравнению с равновесием замедляет рост, в то время как ускорение роста наблюдается при относительно небольшом, но не чрезмерном, занижении курса.

342 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Aboa centre for economics" ?

This study shows that the learning by doing ( LBD ) effect has substantial, both quantitative and qualitative, consequences for the international transmission of monetary policy.