scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Make, buy, organize: The interplay between research, external knowledge, and firm structure†

01 Mar 2014-Strategic Management Journal (John Wiley & Sons, Ltd)-Vol. 35, Iss: 3, pp 317-337
TL;DR: This article explored the interplay between R&D, external knowledge, and organizational structure of a firm's innovation strategy, and found that centralized firms invest more in research, and patent more per research dollar, than decentralized firms.
Abstract: We bridge current streams of innovation research to explore the interplay between R&D, external knowledge, and organizational structure�three elements of a firm's innovation strategy, which we argue should logically be studied together. Using within-firm patent assignment patterns, we develop a novel measure of structure for a large sample of American firms. We find that centralized firms invest more in research, and patent more per R&D dollar, than decentralized firms. Both types access technology via mergers and acquisitions, but their acquisitions differ in terms of frequency, size, and integration. Consistent with our framework, their sources of value creation differ: while centralized firms derive more value from internal R&D, decentralized firms rely more on external knowledge. We discuss how these findings should stimulate more integrative work on theories of innovation. Copyright © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

Summary (3 min read)

1 Introduction

  • Using a novel largescale dataset, the authors explore whether rms demonstrate distinct and coherent combinations of R&D organizational structure and knowledge-sourcing strategies, as would be expected given the concatenated predictions of these emerging theories of innovation.
  • The authors ndings extend and clarify prior results.
  • The implied coherence, however, does not necessarily imply a particular causal structure.

2 Three Pillars of Innovation Strategy

  • The authors draw upon important streams in the innovation literature that have explored dyadic relationships between research, external knowledge and structure.
  • Firms that invest heavily 3 in basic research have been shown to have more centralized R&D, whereas decentralized R&D, managed by business units and divisions, tends to be more applied and incremental (Argyres and Silverman, 2004).
  • Though Argyres and Silverman (2004) hint at this issue by exploring how structure conditions a rm s propensity to "build on.
  • Nonetheless, Microsoft has struggled with large acquisitions, such as aQuantive, an online advertising technology rm bought in 2006.
  • A rm will perform well (and survive) if organizational structure, internal research, and knowledge acquisition are aligned to support each other if they are coherent (Siggelkow, 2011;.

3 Sample and Data

  • The authors match rms to patents by matching assignee names and addresses.
  • Ownership data consists of two parts: cross-sectional ownership information from Icarus for 2008, and M&A data from SDC Platinum and Zephyr.
  • By matching to SDC, the authors can see that WebTV was purchased in 1997 by Microsoft, then dissolved and absorbed into Microsoft s MSN Networks.

3.1 Patent Assignment as a Proxy for Decentralization

  • Whereas a rm s research focus and external knowledge-sourcing activities can be tracked using patents, R&D spending or alliances (Arora, Fosfuri, and Gambardella, 2001; Henderson and Cockburn, 1994; Mowery, Oxley, and Silverman, 1996), the internal organization of R&D is extremely di¢ cult to observe.
  • As their new measure does precisely this, it promises to open a new window into the internal organization of rms R&D function.
  • As with any proxy measure that lends itself to large-scale empirical analysis, their measure is practical but imperfect, and the authors admit that there are trade-o¤s to consider.
  • The authors can see that these patterns are markedly di¤erent.

3.2 Other variable de nitions and measures

  • Scienti c publications are a commonly accepted measure of a rm s basic science orientation (Gambardella, 1995; Stern, 2004), and rms such as DuPont, IBM, Merck, and Microsoft, which have traditionally relied upon internally generated innovations, have also tended to produce a great number of scienti c publications.
  • The authors use three supplemental measures to probe the robustness of their results to alternate measures, since the literature suggests a variety of empirical proxies.
  • Typically, rms that rely upon internal research to fuel growth have higher levels of R&D intensity.
  • The authors classify rms according to tertiles of share of patents assigned, and operationalize using categorical variables.
  • The authors use the centralized category as their baseline in all regressions.

3.3 Descriptive statistics and evidence of persistence

  • Average value of sales in their sample is $3.4 billion, and market value is $5.9 billion (of which $3 billion are in physical assets).
  • An analysis of variance (not presented in a table) indicates that between- rm variation accounts for 87%, 81%, and 88% of the total variance for share patents acquired, share patents assigned, and publication intensity, respectively.
  • This strongly supports the view that there are reinforcing interactions among the various choices, which may make it di¢ cult or undesirable for rms to abruptly change any of their core strategies.
  • This way of assessing persistence obviates the need to control for changes in the environment or changes in rm size or other such variables.
  • About 4 percent of all rms move down the distribution, but none drops by more than a single quartile.

3.4.1 Non-parametric analysis

  • The authors begin by exploring the relationships between organization, acquisitions, and internal research in Table 2.
  • Speci cally, the authors look at how both share patents acquired and publication intensity vary across rms with varying levels of decentralization.
  • Centralized rms are smaller than decentralized rms in terms of sales, but they have close to double the number of patents.
  • It is important to note that this relationship is also driven by how the rm deals with acquisitions, not simply by how acquisitive the rm is.
  • These ndings are important because structural integration is one of the levers that managers use to shape both the nature of research and the structure of the rm (Haspeslagh and Jemison, 1991; Puranam, Singh, and Zollo, 2006).

3.4.2 Parametric analysis

  • The authors ndings thus far serve as large-scale validation and extension of earlier studies.
  • In unreported speci cations the authors explore the extent to which structure conditions the publications-acquisitions relationship.
  • This supports the notion that centralized rms would acquire more nascent external technology to integrate into their existing research (Capron et al., 1998; Karim, 2006), whereas decentralized rms may acquire more developed technology that is closer to being commercialized (e.g., Cisco s "acquire and develop" model).
  • The authors also nd a negative relation between publications and share patents acquired (column 9), however, it is not statistically signi cant when controlling for structure.
  • Organization structure thus is signi cantly associated with investment in internal research, even after conditioning on external knowledge sourcing.

3.5 Firm Market Value

  • The authors have shown that centralization is associated with investment in basic research while decentralization is associated with a strong emphasis on accessing external innovations.
  • In fact, this drop is mostly attributed to controlling for sales growth: when excluding sales growth but still controlling for sales, the coe¢ cient estimate on external patents stock is 0.07 and is statistically signi cant at the 1 percent level.
  • Among the set of technically diversi ed rms, centralized rms derive considerable value from internal R&D, whereas decentralized rms derive little value from internal R&D (coe¢ cient estimates of 0.16 versus -0.01).
  • Conversely, external patents are associated with value in decentralized rms but not in centralized rms (coe¢ cient estimate of 0.10 compared to 0.03).
  • 21 Overall, their ndings support the interpretation that rms that rely upon internal research to create value are best served by a centralized organization, in contrast to rms that rely upon external knowledge, especially in large or technically diversi ed rms.

3.6 Robustness

  • The authors checked the sensitivity of their results to rm size by excluding very small and very large rms from the sample (lowest and highest sales deciles).
  • Though there is a growing literature on the geographical location and management of R&D activities (Leiponen and Helfat, 2011; Singh, 2008), the question of geography is logically distinct from the question of internal organization.
  • As Singh (2008) puts it, a rm could have a decentralized formal organization even with relatively small number of R&D locations, while another rm might have a much more centralized organization despite having a much greater number of R&D locations.
  • To test whether their set of relationships is driven by the distinction between rms with and without a¢ liates, the authors estimate the main speci cations 22 for a sample that includes only rms with at least one a¢ liate, regardless of whether the a¢ liate patents or not.
  • Demonstrating that their results continue to hold also within a sample of rms that have at least one a¢ liate eliminates the concern that the results are driven by comparing rms with and without a¢ liates.

4 Discussion and Conclusion

  • External knowledge sourcing, and internal research focus.the authors.
  • It is likely that rms that innovate primarily by developing knowledge internally favor investments in more basic, long-term research and do not rely much on incremental research that merely improves existing goods and services.
  • Given the role of structure in conditioning the relationship between internal development and external knowledge 24 integration, it is unlikely that innovation strategy can be charted using a simple "make vs. buy" logic, if this does not take into account the complex role played by organizational structure.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

&61>-:;1<A7.!-66;A4>)61)&61>-:;1<A7.!-66;A4>)61)
$+074):4A75576;$+074):4A75576;
)6)/-5-6<!)8-:; '0):<76)+=4<A#-;-):+0

)3-=A :/)61B-%0-6<-:84)A*-<?--6#-;-):+0@<-:6)4)3-=A :/)61B-%0-6<-:84)A*-<?--6#-;-):+0@<-:6)4
67?4-,/-)6,1:5$<:=+<=:-67?4-,/-)6,1:5$<:=+<=:-
;01;0:7:)
$0):76-4-6B76
=1;#17;
&61>-:;1<A7.!-66;A4>)61)
7447?<01;)6,),,1<176)4?7:3;)<0<<8;:-87;1<7:A=8-66-,=5/5<(8)8-:;
!):<7.<0-=;16-;;,5161;<:)<176)6)/-5-6<)6, 8-:)<176;75576;=;16-;;6)4A<1+;
75576;=;16-;;)6,7:87:)<-755=61+)<176;75576;=;16-;;)?!=*41+#-;876;1*141<A)6,
<01+;75576;)6)/-5-6<6.7:5)<176$A;<-5;75576;)6)/-5-6<$+1-6+-;)6,"=)6<1<)<1>-
-<07,;75576; 8-:)<176;)6,$=884A0)16)6)/-5-6<75576; :/)61B)<176)4-0)>17:)6,
%0-7:A75576;)6,<0-$<:)<-/1+)6)/-5-6<!741+A75576;
#-+755-6,-,1<)<176#-+755-6,-,1<)<176
:7:)-4-6B76$#17;)3-=A :/)61B-%0-6<-:84)A*-<?--6#-;-):+0@<-:6)4
67?4-,/-)6,1:5$<:=+<=:-
$<:)<-/1+)6)/-5-6<7=:6)4

0<<8,@,717:/
;52
%01;8)8-:1;87;<-,)<$+074):4A75576;0<<8;:-87;1<7:A=8-66-,=5/5<(8)8-:;
7:57:-16.7:5)<17684-);-+76<)+<:-87;1<7:A87*7@=8-66-,=

)3-=A :/)61B-%0-6<-:84)A*-<?--6#-;-):+0@<-:6)467?4-,/-)6,)3-=A :/)61B-%0-6<-:84)A*-<?--6#-;-):+0@<-:6)467?4-,/-)6,
1:5$<:=+<=:-1:5$<:=+<=:-
*;<:)+<*;<:)+<
'-*:1,/-+=::-6<;<:-)5;7.1667>)<176:-;-):+0<7-@847:-<0-16<-:84)A*-<?--6#-@<-:6)4
367?4-,/-)6,7:/)61B)<176)4;<:=+<=:-D<0:---4-5-6<;7.)E:5;1667>)<176;<:)<-/A?01+0?-):/=-
;07=4,47/1+)44A*-;<=,1-,<7/-<0-:&;16/?1<016E:58)<-6<);;1/65-6<8)<<-:6;?-,->-478)67>-4
5-);=:-7.;<:=+<=:-.7:)4):/-;)584-7.5-:1+)6E:5;'-E6,<0)<+-6<:)41B-,E:5;16>-;<57:-16
:-;-):+0)6,8)<-6<57:-8-:#,744):<0)6,-+-6<:)41B-,E:5;7<0<A8-;)++-;;<-+06747/A>1)
5-:/-:;)6,)+9=1;1<176;*=<<0-1:)+9=1;1<176;,1..-:16<-:5;7..:-9=-6+A;1B-)6,16<-/:)<176
76;1;<-6<?1<07=:.:)5-?7:3<0-1:;7=:+-;7.>)4=-+:-)<176,1..-:?014-+-6<:)41B-,E:5;,-:1>-57:-
>)4=-.:7516<-:6)4#,-+-6<:)41B-,E:5;:-4A57:-76-@<-:6)4367?4-,/-'-,1;+=;;07?<0-;-
E6,16/;;07=4,;<15=4)<-57:-16<-/:)<1>-?7:376<0-7:1-;7.1667>)<176
-A?7:,;-A?7:,;
,-+-6<:)41B)<1767:/)61B)<176)4;<:=+<=:-5-:/-:;)6,)+9=1;1<176;8)<-6<;#5):3-<>)4=-
1;+18416-;1;+18416-;
=;16-;;,5161;<:)<176)6)/-5-6<)6, 8-:)<176;C=;16-;;6)4A<1+;C=;16-;;)6,7:87:)<-
755=61+)<176;C=;16-;;)?!=*41+#-;876;1*141<A)6,<01+;C)6)/-5-6<6.7:5)<176$A;<-5;C
)6)/-5-6<$+1-6+-;)6,"=)6<1<)<1>--<07,;C 8-:)<176;)6,$=884A0)16)6)/-5-6<C
:/)61B)<176)4-0)>17:)6,%0-7:AC$<:)<-/1+)6)/-5-6<!741+A
%01;27=:6)4):<1+4-1;)>)14)*4-)<$+074):4A75576;0<<8;:-87;1<7:A=8-66-,=5/5<(8)8-:;

Make, Buy, Organize: The Interplay Between Research,
External Knowledge, and Firm Structure
Ashish Arora
y
Sharon Belenzon
z
Luis A. Rios
x
December 11, 2012
Abstract
We bridge current streams of innovation research to explore the interplay between
R&D, external knowledge, an d organizational structure–three elements of a rm’s inno-
vation strategy which we argue should logically be studied together. Using within-…rm
patent assignment patterns, we develop a novel measure of structure for a large sample of
American rms. We nd that centralized rms invest more in research and patent more
per R&D dollar than decentralized rms. Both types acc ess technology via mergers and
acquisitions, but their acquisitions di¤er in terms of frequency, size, and integration. Con-
sistent with our framework, their sources of value creation di¤er: while centralized rms
derive more value from internal R&D, decentralized rms rely more on external knowl-
edge. We discuss how these ndings s hould stimulate more integrative work on theories of
innovation.
Keywords: decentralization, organizational structure, mergers and acquisitions, patents,
R&D, market value
JEL Classi…cation: D23 D83 L22
1 Intro duction
How do rms allocate resources between R&D and external technology in order to maximize
value and drive growth? And in turn, do their ensuing growth trajectories themselves shape
such future resource allocation? Over the past three decades, the eld of innovation strategy
All authors contributed equally and are listed in alphabetical order.
y
Duke University, Fuqua School of Business, 100 Fuqua Drive, Durham, NC 27708, U.S.A. E-mail:
ashish.arora@duke.edu
z
Duke University, Fuqua School of Business, 100 Fuqua Drive, Durham, NC 27708, U.S.A. E-mail:
sharon.belenzon@duke.edu
x
Corresponding author. Duke University, Fuqua School of Business, 100 Fuqua Drive, Durham, NC 27708,
U.S.A. E-mail: luis.rios@duke.edu
1

has isolated a set of important dyadic relationships in an ort to understand these interrelated
questions. For example, a substantial body of work has advanced our understanding of the
relationship b etween internal R&D and external knowledge, (e.g. Cohen and Levinthal, 1990;
Pisano, 1990; Katz and Allen, 1982). More recently, a small literature on the structure of R&D
has explored how the resource allocation decision is related to the centralization or decentraliza-
tion of R&D (e.g. Argyres and Silverman, 2004; Lerner and Wulf, 2007). Separately, work on
structural integration and resource recon…guration has lo oked at how organizations are shaped
by acquisitions and absorption (e.g., Ahuja and Katila, 2001; Puranam, Singh, and Zollo, 2006;
Karim and Mitchell, 2000).
Surprisingly, there remains little integration of the aforementioned streams. This lack of
synthesis may be due to data constrains, since most work that considers such organizational
dynamics tends to rely on small samples (Karim and Mitchell, 2004, and Cohen and Levinthal,
1990 are notable exceptions). Understandably, researchers must often cede the pursuit of a richer
understanding of strategic interrelationships in exchange for "analytical precision and theoretical
rigor" (Zollo and Singh, 2004). Nonetheless, this lacuna is an important and understudied
limitation, since the very word "organization"from the Greek organon ("tool, instrument, set
of rules")–denotes a coherent system or unit where interdependent parts work as one. In fact,
a central tenet of organization theory holds that the structures, systems, and processes of a rm
should be interdependent and must be mutually supportive and coherent (Drazin and Van de
Ven, 1985; Nadler and Tushman, 1997; Rivkin and Siggelkow, 2003; Siggelkow, 2011).
It is the pursuit of this coherence logic that motivates our paper. Using a novel large-
scale dataset, we explore whether rms demonstrate distinct and coherent combinations of
R&D organizational structure and knowledge-sourcing strategies, as would be expected given
the concatenated predictions of these emerging theories of innovation. We propose that rms
pursuing a particular approach to innovation (e.g., a strong focus on internal research like
IBM or an "acquire and develop" approach like Cisco) also need a well-matched supporting
organizational structure (e.g., centralized or decentralized). Empirically, we exploit a sample
that includes nearly all patenting public American rms, and develop a new measure of R&D
organizational structure which uses the ratio of patents assigned to liates versus corporate
parents as a proxy for the decentralization of R&D. This involves matching 576,052 patents
to 1,014 publicly traded American corporations and their 2,768 liates. By do cumenting the
types of choices that rms make, we bridge streams of the literature that have previously studied
dyadic relationships b etween internal and external knowledge sourcing, between organizational
2

structure and innovation, and between acquisitions and structure.
Our ndings extend and clarify prior results. We nd evidence that strongly supports the
coherence logic. Knowledge sourcing strategies appear to be systematically related to orga-
nizational structure. Moreover, the market valuation of these knowledge sourcing strategies
strongly correlates with structure. We nd con…rmatory large-scale evidence that research-
oriented rms are signi…cantly more centralized than others, consistent with earlier small-sample
ndings (Hoskisson, et al. 1993; Kay, 1988; Argyres and Silverman, 2004). But we also nd
that organizational structure seems to strongly condition the relationship between rms re-
search focus and their external knowledge acquisition strategy. Though both centralized and
decentralized rms acquire external technology, centralized rms do so less frequently and tend
to make smaller acquisitions. Moreover, they manage acquisitions di¤erently. Acquisitions by
centralized rms frequently undergo full structural integration (Puranam et al., 2006), whereas
decentralized rms tend to keep acquisitions as discrete entities.
Importantly, the logic underlying these patterns of choice is re‡ected in measurable di¤er-
ences in the composition of rms’market value. Whereas centralized rms draw most of their
intangible value from internal R&D stocks, decentralized rms derive relatively more value
from externally acquired patents. This nding is especially strong for large rms and rms with
higher technological diversity.
Our results imply that a successful innovation strategy requires careful alignment both be-
tween internal and external knowledge sourcing, and between the internal/external mix of inputs
and organizational structure. The implied coherence, however, does not necessarily imply a par-
ticular causal structure. Establishing causality is important, but given the nature of our data,
it is beyond the scope of our project. Furthermore, it is just as important to develop a fuller
theory of innovation that accounts for the dynamics we highlight in this study. By developing a
new empirical measure and systematically exposing the relationships between internal research,
external knowledge, and organizational structure among a nearly comprehensive set of rms,
we take an important step towards the development of such theory.
2 Three Pillars of Innovation Strategy
We draw upon important streams in the innovation literature that have explored dyadic relation-
ships between research, external knowledge and structure. The rst explores how the nature of
research inside a rm is related to how the activity itself is organized. Firms that invest heavily
3

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This article explored the effect of two sources of external knowledge: new product development (NPD) alliances, representing tightly coupled sources, and loosely coupled sources such as industry associations, and found that the extent to which firms utilize knowledge from NPD alliances has a curvilinear relationship with strategic flexibility.
Abstract: Strategic flexibility is a vital capability for new ventures to update their strategies in a timely manner. However, the role of external knowledge sources in new ventures’ endeavours to develop strategic flexibility are unclear. Drawing on the knowledge†based and relational views, we explore the effect of two sources of external knowledge: new product development (NPD) alliances, representing tightly coupled sources, and loosely coupled sources such as industry associations. Our field study of 148 high†tech ventures found that the extent to which firms utilize knowledge from NPD alliances has a curvilinear relationship with strategic flexibility, whereas the extent to which firms utilize loosely coupled sources has a positive linear relationship with strategic flexibility. We also found that in new ventures, decentralization of decision†making and institutional support enhance knowledge integration, positively moderating these relationships.

56 citations


Cites background from "Make, buy, organize: The interplay ..."

  • ...…a large variety of external resources, particularly knowledge, which influences important aspects of firm strategies such as exploitation and exploration (Foss et al., 2013), open innovation (Cassiman and Veugelers, 2006; Laursen and Salter, 2006), and acquisition decisions (Arora et al., 2014)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors analyze the relationship between knowledge management and innovation in SMEs in the region of Murcia, Spain and find that knowledge management can help SMEs to professionally develop employees, improve innovation processes, grow sales, satisfy customers and thus achieve organizational success.
Abstract: Introduction The era of knowledge plays an essential role in the economic growth and development of all enterprises (Foray, 2004; Mosconi & Roy, 2013). With the arrival of globalization, knowledge has become an intangible resource generator of permanent competitive advantage (Ikujiro & Hiroshi, 2013; Tunc Bozbura, 2007) and contributes to the generation of intellectual capital and to the economic activities of organizations (Kristandl & Bontis, 2007). In these times of constant motion, small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) require the extraction of knowledge from both domestic sources and foreign sources to achieve greater participation in the markets, foster innovation, and improve performance (Gold, Malhotra, & Segars, 2001; Morgan & Berthon, 2008). Knowledge management (KM) is a comprehensive approach that includes capture, receipt, and transfer of information in a company that considers the policies, procedures, knowledge, and experience of employees (Duhon, 1998). In addition, technology systems influence the behavior of employees and strengthen a culture based on the use and transfer of information (Davenport, 1994). KM is a business practice that integrates essential strategies, policies, techniques, and procedures (Davenport, 2013; Lavergne & Earl, 2006). The alignment of corporate strategy with KM is vital for adding value and achieving results (Chuang, 2004; M. H. Zack & Singh, 2010). KM influences business systems by increasing profitability, creating a harmonious atmosphere among employees, and ensuring businesses' sustainability and competitiveness (Darvish, Mohammadi, & Afsharpour, 2012; Darvish & Nazari, 2013). However, KM is not sufficiently widespread in SMEs, mainly due to the lack of strategic planning, lack of financial resources, distaste to change cultural, uncertainty regarding benefits, and technological immaturity, which are typical in these organizations (Edvardsson & Durst, 2013; Yew Wong, 2005). A reasonable number of empirical studies have analyzed the impact of KM and innovation in SMEs (Constantinescu, 2009; C. Yu, Yu-Fang, & Yu-Cheh, 2013). However, the relationship between innovation and performance is still a wide field for exploration (Price, Stoica, & Boncella, 2013; Vaccaro, Parente, & Veloso, 2010). Works on KM have placed minimal emphasis on the benefits generated in SMEs; the majority of research focuses on large organizations (Darroch, 2005; Roxas, Battisti, & Deakins, 2014). In addition, minimal understanding of how companies create, transfer, and use knowledge has led to difficulty in transforming knowledge into a competitive advantage (C. Lin, Wu, & Yen, 2012; Perrin, Vidal, & McGill, 2006). The difficulty of measuring KM in SMEs provides a reasonable explanation for the scarcity of empirical studies in this developing discipline (Becerra-Fernandez & Sabherwal, 2014; Choi, Poon, & Davis, 2008). By the great influence of the KM in the progress and development of SMEs, it is important to develop this type of study more regularly (Imran, 2014; Vaccaro et al., 2010). The objective of this work is to empirically analyze the relationships between KM, innovation, and performance in SMEs in the region of Murcia, Spain. In the current competitive global environment, it is important to analyze the key factors that affect the development and growth of these companies. The research questions that we attempt to answer are as follows: 1. Does knowledge management influence innovation activities in SMEs? 2. Does business innovation exert any influence on SME performance? Literature reveals that KM can help SMEs to professionally develop employees, improve innovation processes, grow sales, satisfy customers and thus achieve organizational success (Edvardsson & Durst, 2013; Lopez-Nicolas & Merono-Cerdan, 2011; Madrid-Guijarro, Garcia, & Van Auken, 2009). …

55 citations


Cites background from "Make, buy, organize: The interplay ..."

  • ...The literature indicates that the acquisition of external knowledge is one of the most basic corporate practices in the management of innovation (Arora et al., 2014; W. M. Cohen, 2010; W. M. Cohen & Levinthal, 1990)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A novel prospect-based two-sided matching decision model for matching supply and demand of technological knowledge assisted by a broker is proposed to account for the stakeholders’ psychological behaviours and their impact on the matching decision in an open innovation setting.
Abstract: Purpose The purpose of this paper is to propose a novel prospect-based two-sided matching decision model for matching supply and demand of technological knowledge assisted by a broker. This model enables the analyst to account for the stakeholders’ psychological behaviours and their impact on the matching decision in an open innovation setting. Design/methodology/approach The prospect theory and grey relational analysis are used to develop the proposed two-sided matching decision framework. Findings By properly calibrating model parameters, the case study demonstrates that the proposed approach can be applied to real-world technological knowledge trading in a market for technology (MFT) and yields matching results that are more consistent with the reality. Research limitations/implications The proposed model does not differentiate the types of knowledge exchanged (established vs novel, tacit vs codified, general vs specialized) (Ardito et al., 2016, Nielsen and Nielsen, 2009). Moreover, the model focuses on incorporating psychological behaviour of the MFT participants and does not consider their other characteristics. Practical implications The proposed model can be applied to achieve a better matching between technological knowledge suppliers and users in a broker-assisted MFT. Social implications A better matching between technological knowledge suppliers and users can enhance the success of open innovation, thereby contributing to the betterment of the society. Originality/value This paper furnishes a novel theoretical model for matching supply and demand in a broker-assisted MFT. Methodologically, the proposed model can effectively capture market participants’ psychological considerations.

53 citations


Cites background or methods from "Make, buy, organize: The interplay ..."

  • ...In MFTs, universities and research institutes are key creators or suppliers of technological knowledge, and enterprises are potential users and adopters [Arora et al. 2014; Arora et al. 2001a, b; Arora and Gambardella 2010]....

    [...]

  • ...For example, by surveying recent research on MFTs, Arora and Gambardella [2010] analyzed the supply and demand of technology, examined what factors affect MFT formation and growth, and explored the dynamic interactions between industry structure and MFTs [Arora et al. 2014]....

    [...]

  • ...The aforesaid discussions allow us to summarize the solution procedure of the proposed decision method for two-sided matching technological knowledge supply and demand as follows: Step 1: Determine evaluation matrices A and B by using (1) and (2) based on the suppliers’ and users’ evaluations of the other party and criteria weights; Step 2: Find the positive and negative ideal users and suppliers as per Definition 2 and 3, and calculate positive and negative relational coefficients of the suppliers and users by using the grey relational analysis method; Step 3: Obtain prospect values and prospect matrices for the suppliers and users based on the positive and negative relational coefficients of the suppliers and users as per Eqs....

    [...]

  • ...Step 1: Given the suppliers’ evaluations of the users in Table 1 and the users’ assessments of the suppliers in Table 2 as well as the associated criteria weights, one can obtain the overall evaluation values based on formulas (1) and (2) as shown in Table 4....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
Julia Bodner1, Laurence Capron1
TL;DR: The authors discusses post-merger integration (PMI) and the trade-off between the economic benefits and costs that arise when organizations merge under a new organizational structure and reconfigure their businesses and resources.
Abstract: This article discusses post-merger integration (PMI) and the trade-off between the economic benefits and costs that arise when organizations merge under a new organizational structure and reconfigure their businesses and resources. To reconfiguration scholars, PMI is a crucial tool for firms to reconfigure resources, product lines, and business units to adjust to internal and external environment needs. Other scholars focus on organization design, shedding light on structural integration following an acquisition and exploring key trade-offs of this process. We integrate reconfiguration and organization design aspects on choices of what and how to integrate after mergers and acquisitions, questions that have often been treated separately. We then outline how to design and conduct empirical research on PMI. We conclude by offering ideas for future research.

51 citations


Cites background from "Make, buy, organize: The interplay ..."

  • ...Arora et al. (2014) find that the organization design of firms (centralized vs. decentralized) affects the integration of knowledge....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper found that both task-related training and employee participation improve firm innovation in terms of the commercial success of new product development and the percentage of firm revenue from newly developed products, and that the effects of training on innovation are stronger when firms have a high (rather than low) centralization of authority and when firms are located in fast-growing economies.

45 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors argue that the ability of a firm to recognize the value of new, external information, assimilate it, and apply it to commercial ends is critical to its innovative capabilities.
Abstract: In this paper, we argue that the ability of a firm to recognize the value of new, external information, assimilate it, and apply it to commercial ends is critical to its innovative capabilities. We label this capability a firm's absorptive capacity and suggest that it is largely a function of the firm's level of prior related knowledge. The discussion focuses first on the cognitive basis for an individual's absorptive capacity including, in particular, prior related knowledge and diversity of background. We then characterize the factors that influence absorptive capacity at the organizational level, how an organization's absorptive capacity differs from that of its individual members, and the role of diversity of expertise within an organization. We argue that the development of absorptive capacity, and, in turn, innovative performance are history- or path-dependent and argue how lack of investment in an area of expertise early on may foreclose the future development of a technical capability in that area. We formulate a model of firm investment in research and development (R&D), in which R&D contributes to a firm's absorptive capacity, and test predictions relating a firm's investment in R&D to the knowledge underlying technical change within an industry. Discussion focuses on the implications of absorptive capacity for the analysis of other related innovative activities, including basic research, the adoption and diffusion of innovations, and decisions to participate in cooperative R&D ventures. **

31,623 citations


"Make, buy, organize: The interplay ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Internal research helps …rms identify, evaluate, and assimilate external knowledge (Rosenberg, 1979; Cohen and Levinthal, 1990), which often comes via acquisitions (Kogut and Zander, 1993; Fleming, 2001)....

    [...]

  • ...This lack of synthesis may be due to data constrains, since most work that considers such organizational dynamics tends to rely on small samples (Karim and Mitchell, 2004, and Cohen and Levinthal, 1990 are notable exceptions)....

    [...]

  • ...For example, a substantial body of work has advanced our understanding of the relationship between internal R&D and external knowledge, (e.g. Cohen and Levinthal, 1990; Pisano, 1990; Katz and Allen, 1982)....

    [...]

  • ...Internal research helps rms identify, evaluate, and assimilate external knowledge (Rosenberg, 1979; Cohen and Levinthal, 1990), which often comes via acquisitions (Kogut and Zander, 1993; Fleming, 2001)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors empirically examined the decision to transfer the capability to manufacture new products to wholly owned subsidiaries or to other parties and found that the less codifiable and the harder to teach is the technology, the more likely the transfer will be to wholly-owned operations.
Abstract: Firms are social communities that specialize in the creation and internal transfer of knowledge. The multinational corporation arises not out of the failure of markets for the buying and selling of knowledge, but out of its superior efficiency as an organizational vehicle by which to transfer this knowledge across borders. We test the claim that firms specialize in the internal transfer of tacit knowledge by empirically examining the decision to transfer the capability to manufacture new products to wholly owned subsidiaries or to other parties. The empirical results show that the less codifiable and the harder to teach is the technology, the more likely the transfer will be to wholly owned operations. This result implies that the choice of transfer mode is determined by the efficiency of the multinational corporation in transferring knowledge relative to other firms, not relative to an abstract market transaction. The notion of the firm as specializing in the transfer and recombination of knowledge is the foundation to an evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation

3,376 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, a measure of changes in alliance partners' technological capabilities, based on the citation patterns of their patent portfolios, is used to analyze changes in the extent to which partner firms' technological resources overlap as a result of alliance participation.
Abstract: This paper examines interfirm knowledge transfers within strategic alliances. Using a new measure of changes in alliance partners' technological capabilities, based on the citation patterns of their patent portfolios, we analyze changes in the extent to which partner firms' technological resources ‘overlap’ as a result of alliance participation. This measure allows us to test hypotheses from the literature on interfirm knowledge transfer in alliances, with interesting results: we find support for some elements of this ‘received wisdom’—equity arrangements promote greater knowledge transfer, and ‘absorptive capacity’ helps explain the extent of technological capability transfer, at least in some alliances. But the results also suggest limits to the ‘capabilities acquisition’ view of strategic alliances. Consistent with the argument that alliance activity can promote increased specialization, we find that the capabilities of partner firms become more divergent in a substantial subset of alliances.

3,355 citations


"Make, buy, organize: The interplay ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...…a rm s research focus and external knowledge-sourcing activities can be tracked using patents, R&D spending or alliances (Arora, Fosfuri, and Gambardella, 2001; Henderson and Cockburn, 1994; Mowery, Oxley, and Silverman, 1996), the internal organization of R&D is extremely di¢ cult to observe....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors empirically examined the decision to transfer the capability to manufacture new products to wholly owned subsidiaries or to other parties and found that the less codifiable and the harder to teach is the technology, the more likely the transfer will be to wholly-owned operations.
Abstract: Firms are social communities that specialize in the creation and internal transfer of knowledge. The multinational corporation arises not out of the failure of markets for the buying and selling of knowledge, but out of its superior efficiency as an organizational vehicle by which to transfer this knowledge across borders. We test the claim that firms specialize in the internal transfer of tacit knowledge by empirically examining the decision to transfer the capability to manufacture new products to wholly owned subsidiaries or to other parties. The empirical results show that the less codifiable and the harder to teach is the technology, the more likely the transfer will be to wholly owned operations. This result implies that the choice of transfer mode is determined by the efficiency of the multinational corporation in transferring knowledge relative to other firms, not relative to an abstract market transaction. The notion of the firm as specializing in the transfer and recombination of knowledge is the foundation to an evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation.

3,354 citations


"Make, buy, organize: The interplay ..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Internal research helps rms identify, evaluate, and assimilate external knowledge (Rosenberg, 1979; Cohen and Levinthal, 1990), which often comes via acquisitions (Kogut and Zander, 1993; Fleming, 2001)....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this article, the authors present evidence that firms' patents, profits and market value are systematically related to the technological position of firms' research programs, and that firms are seen to "move" in technology space in response to the pattern of contemporaneous profits at different positions.
Abstract: This paper presents evidence that firms' patents, profits and market value are systematically related to the"technological position" of firms' research programs. Further, firms are seen to "move" in technology space in response to the pattern of contemporaneous profits at different positions. These movements tend to erode excess returns."Spillovers" of R&D are modelled by examining whether the R&D of neighboring firms in technology space has an observable impact on the firm's R&D success. Firms whose neighbors do much R&D produce more patents per dollar of their own R&D,with a positive interaction that gives high R&D firms the largest benefit from spillovers. In terms of profit and market value, however, their are both positive and negative effects of nearby firms' R&D. The net effect is positive for high R&D firms, but firms with R&D about one standard deviation below the mean are made worse off overall by the R&D of others.

3,313 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (2)
Q1. What are the future works in "Make, buy, organize: the interplay between research, external knowledge, and firm structure" ?

Future work should further exploit their novel measure of decentralization, as well as time and exogenous variation in order to better explain the systematic patterns the authors have described. For example, given the role of structure in conditioning the relationship between internal development and external knowledge 24 integration, it is unlikely that innovation strategy can be charted using a simple `` make vs. buy '' logic, if this does not take into account the complex role played by organizational structure. 

The authors bridge current streams of innovation research to explore the interplay between R & D, external knowledge, and organizational structure–three elements of a firm 's innovation strategy which they argue should logically be studied together. The authors discuss how these findings should stimulate more integrative work on theories of innovation. Using within-firm patent assignment patterns, the authors develop a novel measure of structure for a large sample of American firms.