scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

On the Design of Optimal Grandfathering Schemes for Emission Allowances

TL;DR: In this article, the authors determine central design rules for optimal grandfathering within a simple two-period model, and find that for (small) open trading systems, where allowance prices are exogenous, first-best second-period grandfathering schemes must not depend on firm-specific decisions in the first period.
Abstract: To meet its commitment under the Kyoto Protocol, the EU plans to implement an emissions trading system with grandfathering of allowances. Besides having distributional impacts, the choice of the grandfathering scheme may affect efficiency if firms anticipate how future allocations depend on upcoming decisions. In this paper, we determine central design rules for optimal grandfathering within a simple two-period model. We find that for (small) open trading systems, where allowance prices are exogenous, first-best second-period grandfathering schemes must not depend on firm-specific decisions in the first period. Second-best schemes correspond to a Ramsey rule of optimal tax differentiation and are generally based on both previous emissions and output. However, for closed emissions trading systems, i.e. endogeneous allowance prices, firstand second-best rules coincide and must not depend on previous output levels. They consist of an assignment proportional to the emissions in the first period plus a term which does not depend on firm-specific decisions in either of the two periods.

Summary (2 min read)

1 Introduction

  • To meet its emissions reduction commitment under the Kyoto Protocol, the EU plans to implement a emissions trading system within the European Community (EU 2001) which covers large installations of energy-intensive industries.
  • With respect to policy guidance, a key challenge from an economic point of view is to identify allocation rules that preserve overall economic efficiency.
  • Dynamic incentives of grandfathering are studied by Laplante et al. (1997).
  • The authors find that the design of optimal grandfathering schemes crucially depends on whether the emissions trading system is closed or open to a larger (the world) market: For open trading systems where allowance prices are exogenous, first-best second-period grandfathering schemes must not depend on firm-specific decisions in the initial period.
  • The more inelastic output , the larger should be the weight to output in the grandfathering rule.

2 Analytical Framework

  • 2 Firm i’s technology in period t (t = 1, 2) is given by its cost function cit(qit, eit) where qit denotes the output level and eit the emissions emerging from production.
  • The firm sells output qit at a competitive consumer price pt, and must hold allowances for emissions eit.
  • The assignment in period 2 might depend on firm’s decisions in period 1 and other non-firm-specific economic parameters: ēi2 = gi(ei1, qi1).
  • In the following, the authors distinguish the cases whether the emissions trading system is open or closed to the world market.
  • Ēt in both periods and the allowance price σt is endogeneous.

2.1 Socially optimal allocation

  • The authors refer to this as the social optimum ((qit∗, eit∗)i,σ∗t )t.
  • As well-known, in the social optimum the consumer price equals marginal production costs, and marginal abatement costs coincide for all firms.

2.2 The decentralized economy

  • Next, the authors consider the decentralized economy in which firms can trade their emissions allowances and output on competitive markets.
  • The competitive firm i maximizes its 3This reflects concrete policy concerns that the European emissions trading system might not be linked with trading schemes from other signatory countries under the Kyoto Protocol or allow for using credits obtained from Joint Implementation (JI) or Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) projects.
  • Clearly, the openess of the system is a prerequisite for achieving emission reduction at lowest costs.

2.3 The open emissions trading system

  • The first-best therefore coincides with grandfathering rules 6 that are independent of first period emissions and output.
  • As an extreme case, a firm should not perpetually receive allowances although it already dropped out off the market.
  • If, cross-price elasticities are small, optimal grandfathering is based on both emission and output levels, i.e. λiq,λ i e > 0.

2.4 The closed emissions trading system

  • If the emissions trading scheme is closed, i.e. P i e it = Ēt, first period equilibrium again depends on the specific grandfathering rule and is given by (4) and (6).
  • Instead of solving the social welfare maximization problem explicitly, the social optimum, which is given by (1) and (2), can be achieved without relying on lump-sum transfers.
  • If lump-sum transfers are ruled out (λi0 = 0) in a closed emissions trading system, the sole grandfathering scheme that warrants efficiency assigns allowances proportional to first-period emissions.
  • The proportionality factor is given by the targeted contraction factor of aggregate emissions, i.e. λe = Ē2/Ē1. 10.

2.5 Policy implications

  • A major policy claim in the debate on allocation schemes is that an installation (firm) should not perpetually receive transfers via the grandfathering rule although it has already been shut down.
  • The allocation rule could meet such concerns by choosing λi0 = 0, i.e. by using the discussed second-best allocations rules.
  • In the closed system, economic efficiency, i.e. the decision to maintain or drop the installation, will not be affected since the effective costs of holding emission allowances do not depend on the choice of λe.
  • Another key issue in the set-up of allocation schemes is the treatment of new market entrants.
  • If the latter are not grandfathered, there is a distributional bias towards incumbent firm.

3 Conclusions

  • From 2005, the EU will have the first international trading system for greenhouse gas emission allowances.
  • Until then, Member States must have developed national allocation plans for emission allowances across large installations of energy-intensive firms.
  • The authors have studied first- and 11 second-best allocation rules for dynamic grandfathering schemes with concretions to an open or a closed trading system.
  • In real practice, implementation of even second-best rules across EU Member States may not be possible due to various reasons.
  • Allocation rules typically addressed in the policy debate are either based on emissions or output.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

ZEW
Zentrum für Europäische
Wirtschaftsforschung GmbH
Centre for European
Economic Research
Discussion Paper No. 03-08
On the Design of Optimal Grandfathering
Schemes for Emission Allowances
Christoph Böhringer and Andreas Lange

Discussion Paper No. 03-08
On the Design of Optimal Grandfathering
Schemes for Emission Allowances
Christoph Böhringer and Andreas Lange
Die Discussion Papers dienen einer möglichst schnellen Verbreitung von
neueren Forschungsarbeiten des ZEW. Die Beiträge liegen in alleiniger Verantwortung
der Autoren und stellen nicht notwendigerweise die Meinung des ZEW dar.
Discussion Papers are intended to make results of ZEW research promptly available to other
economists in order to encourage discussion and suggestions for revisions. The authors are solely
responsible for the contents which do not necessarily represent the opinion of the ZEW.
Download this ZEW Discussion Paper from our ftp server:
ftp://ftp.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/dp/dp0308.pdf

Non-tec hnical summary
To meet its emissions reduction commitment under the Ky oto Protocol, the EU plans
to implement an emission s trad in g syste m within the European Community which
co v ers large installations of energy-in tensive industries. An important element of the
Directive left open to Mem ber States is the grandfathering mechanism of allowances
across industries (installations). Several metrics hav e been proposed for the alloca-
tion of allowa nc e s across production facilities, most notably output-bas ed approaches
or emission-based approaches. Ho wev er, dynamic grandfathering schemes whic h take
production or emission levels as a bas is for allocation can lead to strateg ic behavior of
rms with adverse implica tion s for overall economic eciency. With respect to policy
guidan ce, a key c h alle n ge from an economic point of view is to iden tif y allocation rules
that minimize eciency losses.
In this paper, we study rst- and second-best allocation rules for dynamic grandfather-
ing sc hem es with concr etions to an open or a closed emissions trading system:
For (s mall) open tradin g sys tems where allowance prices a re ex ogen ou s, rst-best
second-period grandfathering schemes must not depend on rm-specic dec ision s
in the initial period. Second-best schemes are based on a w eigh ted com bination of
rst-period output and emission levels. They correspond to a Ram sey-type rule
of optimal tax dierentiation: The more in elastic outpu t (em issions), the larger
should be the weight to output (emissio ns). This highligh ts the importance of
rm s’ (sectors’) characteristics when designing a grandfathering scheme.
If the emissions trading system is clo sed , rst- and second-best rules coincide. To
preserve eciency, grandfathering m ust not depend on previous output levels.
Optim al grandfathering sc hem e s consist of an assignment proportional to the
emissions in the r st period plus a term w hich does not depend on rm-specic
decisions in either of the two periods. The proportion ality factor m us t not dier
between rms (sectors).

On the D esign of Op timal Grandfathering Schem es
for Emiss io n Allowance s
by
Christoph Böhringer
and Andreas Lange
, ∗∗
Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW), M annheim
∗∗
In te rd iscip linar y Institute for En viro n m ental Economics , University of Heidelberg
Abstract: To meet its commitm ent under the Kyoto Protocol, the EU plans to imple-
men t an emissions trading system whith grandfathering of allow ances. Besides ha ving
distributional impacts, the choice of the grandfathering scheme may aect eciency if
rms anticipate how future allocation s depend on upcoming decisions. In this paper,
we determ ine central design rules for optimal grandfath ering within a simple t wo-period
model. We nd that for (small) open trading systems, where allowan c e prices are exoge-
nous, rst-best second-period grandfathering schemes must not depend on rm -specic
decisions in the rst period. Second-best schemes correspond to a Ramsey rule of opti-
mal tax dierentiation and are generally based on both previous emissions and output.
However, ofr closed emiss ion s trading systems, i.e. en d oge n eo us allowance prices, rst-
and second-best rules coincide and m ust not depend on previous output levels. They
consist of an assignm e nt proportional to the emissions in the rst period plus a term
which does not depend on rm -specic decisions in either of the tw o periods.
JEL: Q28
Keyw ords: emissions trading, grandfathering, eciency
Correspondence: A. Lange, Cen tre for European Econom ic Research (ZEW), P.O.Box
103443, D-68034 Mannheim, Germ any, tel: +49 (0)621 1235-208, fax: -226, em ail:
lange@zew.de, boehringer @zew.de
The authors would like to thank Heinz Welsc h and Michael Rauscher for v aluable comments.

1Introduction
To meet its emissions reduction co mmitmen t under the Kyoto Protocol, the EU plans
to implement a emissio ns trading sy stem within the European Com mun ity (EU 2001)
whic h cov ers large installations of energy-intensive industries. It is envisaged to link
the trading scheme with other (non-EU-)schemes and project-based mechanisms like
Joint Implemen tation (JI) and Clean Developmen t Mechanism (CDM) under the Ky oto
Protocol (UNFCCC 1997). Th e propo sed sch eme consists of several temporal stages:
a rst phase from 2005 until 2007, a second one from 2008 until 2012, coinciding
withthelaunchoftheKyotoProtocol,andsubsequentve-y ear-periods co vering P ost-
Kyoto commitment pe riods. M e mber States will allocate emiss ion allo wanc es for free
(grandfa th ering) until 2008 and can auction 10 per cent of the allowances in the second
phase.
An important eleme nt of the Directive left open to Member States is the gran d fath ering
mec hanism of allow ances across industries (installations). Sev eral metrics have been
proposed (Harrison and Radov 2002) for the allocation of allo wances across produc tion
facilities, mos t notably output-based approache s (e.g. kilowatt-hour s of electricity
production) or emission-based approaches (e.g. tons of CO
2
emissions). With respect
to policy guidance, a k ey challenge from an econ omic point of view is to identify
allocation rules that preserv e o verall economic eciency.
Grandfathering schemes lead to ecien cy losses if rms can in crease their grandfa-
thered amount by choosing higher production or emission levels.
1
As a consequence,
the literature has stressed the importance of static grandfathering schemes which are
only based upon historical information. Abstracting from income and terms-of-trade-
eects, the die re nt metrics then simply hav e varyin g distribution a l impacts but leave
production plans of rm s unaected. Grandfathering boils do wn to non-distortionary
lump-sum transfers of allowances (Laan and Nentjes 2001; Woerdm an 2001).
Howev e r, grandfathering sch eme s whic h tak e historical emissions as a basis for alloca-
tion within con tin uous planning cannot completely circumven t the problem of distor-
1
For example, initial allocation can be based on past emissions or on standards from a previous
command-and-c ontrol system. Within the European emissions trading scheme, Germany discusses to
use (re lative) emissions in 1990 as a basis for grandfathering, in order to not reward rms for “early
actions”.
1

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
Beat Hintermann1
TL;DR: In this paper, a structural model of the allowance price under the assumption of efficient markets was derived and the extent to which this variation in price can be explained by marginal abatement costs was examined.

363 citations


Cites background from "On the Design of Optimal Grandfathe..."

  • ...27 disincentive to abate, and [51, 52] formally show that the permit price will be greater in this case than if allocations were fixed based on historic emissions....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors present an analytical supply chain planning model that can be used to examine the supply chain performance at the tactical/operational planning level under carbon pricing and carbon emissions trading.

263 citations


Cites methods from "On the Design of Optimal Grandfathe..."

  • ...In the most widely used allocation method, emissions allowances are grandfathered (allocated) according to the available historical emission data (Böhringer and Lange, 2005)....

    [...]

  • ...methods have been proposed and investigated (Böhringer and Lange, 2005; Burtraw et al., 2001; Cramton and Kerr, 2002)....

    [...]

  • ...Some emissions allocation methods have been proposed and investigated (Böhringer and Lange, 2005; Burtraw et al., 2001; Cramton and Kerr, 2002)....

    [...]

  • ...In the most widely used allocation method, emissions allowances are grandfathered (allocated) according to the available historical emission data (Böhringer and Lange, 2005)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors provide a framework to assess the economic incentives and distortions that provisions in NAPs can have on market prices, operation and investment decisions, and use both analytic models to illustrate the effects of the incentives, and results from numerical simulation runs that estimate the magnitude of impacts from different allocation rules.

253 citations


Cites background from "On the Design of Optimal Grandfathe..."

  • ...The CO2 market price must therefore rise to ensure that the CO2 budget is not violated (see Boeringer and Lange, 2005 )....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a comprehensive index is developed and an intensity allocation model is constructed to allocate the CO2 reduction target regionally to meet the national reduction target to meet this objective, the following aspects may be taken into consideration: equity principles, common but differentiated responsibilities, intensity reduction target fulfillment, and economic difference and reduction potential among provinces.

225 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A literature review of CO2 emissions allocation with emphasis on the evolution of allocation methods used is provided in this article, where the main features and findings of past studies are identified and summarized.

205 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In accordance with decision 9/2 of the Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee of the Framework Convention on Climate Change (INC/FCCC) and endorsed by the Conference of the Parties in its decision, 3/CP.1 (FCCC/CP/1995/7/Add.1), the secretariat is to make available, in the official languages of the United Nations, the executive summaries of the national communications submitted by Annex I Parties.
Abstract: In accordance with decision 9/2 of the Intergovernmental Negotiating Committee of the Framework Convention on Climate Change (INC/FCCC) and endorsed by the Conference of the Parties in its decision, 3/CP.1 (FCCC/CP/1995/7/Add.1), the secretariat is to make available, in the official languages of the United Nations, the executive summaries of the national communications submitted by Annex I Parties.

2,787 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors consider the problem of adjusting the marginal utility of money to different people in a purely competitive system with no foreign trade and assume that private and social net products are always equal or have been made so by State interference not included in the taxation.
Abstract: TILE problem I propose to tackle is this: a given revenue is to be raised by proportionate taxes on some or all uses of income, the taxes on different uses being possibly at different rates; how should these rates be adjusted in order that the decrement of utility may be a minimum? I propose to neglect altogether questions of distribution and considerations arising from the differences in the marginal utility of money to different people; and I shall deal only with a purely competitive system with no foreign trade. Further I shall suppose that, in Professor Pigou's terminology, private and social net products are always equal or have been made so by State interference not included in the taxation we are considering. I thus exclude the case discussed in Marshall's Principles in which a bounty on increasing-return commodities is advisable. Nevertheless we shall find that the obvious solution that there should be no differentiation is entirely erroneous. The effect of taxation is to transfer income in the first place from individuals to the State and then, in part, back again to rentiers and pensioners. These transfers will slightly alter the demand schedules in a way depending on the incidence of the taxes and the manner of their expenditure. I neglect these alterations; 1 and I also suppose that \" a given revenue \" means a given money revenue, \" money \" being so adjusted that its marginal utility is constant. This problem was suggested to me by Professor Pigou, to whom I am also indebted for help and encouragement in its solution. In the first part I deal with the perfectly general utility function and establish a result which is valid for a sufficiently small revenue, and takes a peculiarly simple form if we can treat the revenue as an infinitesimal. I prove, in fact, that in raising an infinitesimal revenue by proportionate taxes on given commodities the taxes should be such as to diminish in the same proportion the production of each commodity taxed. In the second part I assume that the utility function is quadratic, which means roughly that the supply and demand

2,563 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The JSTOR Archive as mentioned in this paper is a trusted digital repository providing for long-term preservation and access to leading academic journals and scholarly literature from around the world, including the Journal of Economic Perspectives.
Abstract: Stable URL:http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0895-3309%28199822%2912%3A3%3C69%3AWCWLFT%3E2.0.CO%3B2-TThe Journal of Economic Perspectives is currently published by American Economic Association.Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available athttp://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtainedprior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content inthe JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained athttp://www.jstor.org/journals/aea.html.Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printedpage of such transmission.The JSTOR Archive is a trusted digital repository providing for long-term preservation and access to leading academicjournals and scholarly literature from around the world. The Archive is supported by libraries, scholarly societies, publishers,and foundations. It is an initiative of JSTOR, a not-for-profit organization with a mission to help the scholarly community takeadvantage of advances in technology. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.http://www.jstor.orgTue Jun 26 16:25:17 2007

713 citations

Book ChapterDOI
01 Jan 2005
TL;DR: The European Climate Change Programme has considered Community policies and measures through a multi-stakeholder process, including a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community (the Community scheme) based on the Green Paper as discussed by the authors.
Abstract: (1) The Green Paper on greenhouse gas emissions trading within the European Union launched a debate across Europe on the suitability and possible functioning of greenhouse gas emissions trading within the European Union. The European Climate Change Programme has considered Community policies and measures through a multi-stakeholder process, including a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community (the Community scheme) based on the Green Paper. In its Conclusions of 8 March 2001, the Council recognised the particular importance of the European Climate Change Programme and of work based on the Green Paper, and underlined the urgent need for concrete action at Community level.

712 citations

Journal ArticleDOI

506 citations


"On the Design of Optimal Grandfathe..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Interpreting cit(q, e) as the costs of an aggregate input to produce (q, e), one can easily transform the formula into a Corlett-Hague type relationship (Corlett and Hague 1953)....

    [...]

  • ...As well-known, in the social optimum the consumer price equals marginal production costs, and marginal abatement costs coincide for all firms....

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (6)
Q1. What are the contributions mentioned in the paper "On the design of optimal grandfathering schemes for emission allowances" ?

In this paper, the authors determine central design rules for optimal grandfathering within a simple two-period model. 

With respect to policy guidance, a key challenge from an economic point of view is to identify allocation rules that minimize efficiency losses. 

An important element of the Directive left open to Member States is the grandfathering mechanism of allowances across industries (installations). 

To meet its emissions reduction commitment under the Kyoto Protocol, the EU plans to implement an emissions trading system within the European Community which covers large installations of energy-intensive industries. 

For (small) open trading systems where allowance prices are exogenous, first-best second-period grandfathering schemes must not depend on firm-specific decisionsin the initial period. 

Optimal grandfathering schemes consist of an assignment proportional to the emissions in the first period plus a term which does not depend on firm-specific decisions in either of the two periods.