scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Payment Evasion: Payment Evasion

01 Dec 2017-Journal of Industrial Economics (Wiley)-Vol. 65, Iss: 4, pp 804-832
TL;DR: In this article, the authors show that a firm can use the purchase price and the fine imposed on detected payment evaders to discriminate between unobservable consumer types, and they illustrate with data from fare dodging on public transportation.
Abstract: This paper shows that a firm can use the purchase price and the fine imposed on detected payment evaders to discriminate between unobservable consumer types. Assuming that consumers self‐select into regular buyers and payment evaders, we show that the firm typically engages in second‐degree price discrimination in which the purchase price exceeds the expected fine. In addition, we find that higher fines do not necessarily reduce payment evasion. We illustrate with data from fare dodging on public transportation.

Summary (4 min read)

1 Introduction

  • Payment evasion—fraudulent consumption by nonpaying consumers—is a serious issue for firms in different industries.
  • The implicit assumption is, of course, that the consumers’ co t associated with payment evasion are high enough for them to refrain from fraudulent consumption.
  • Yet, since the enforcement by public agencies is sketchy and varies acrossjuri dictions, firms undertake substantial private investments in technologies to detectand punish payment evasion.
  • 3Retailers, for instance, regularly impose in-store penalties for shoplifting.
  • Using data on the universe of detected payment evaders, the authors find the following main results.

2 The Model

  • The authors first introduce the decision makers in their model: the firm and the consumers.
  • Next, the authors derive the demand of paying consumers and the demand for payment evasion and study how the demand functions depend on the price and the fine, as well as the cost of evading payment.

2.1 Firm

  • The fixed cost of providing the product isF > 0 5Rational consumer choices also give rise to payment evasionunder pay-as-you-wish pricing (Chen et al. 2013).
  • The key difference is that, under such a pricing scheme, payment evasion is tolerated and not subject to a fine.
  • The authors let(π ,Fπ) denote the detection technology that allows the firm to detect payment evasion with probabilityπ ∈ [0,1] after investingFπ >.
  • Forπ < 1, detection is uncertain and assumed equally likely for all consumers (Polinsky and Shavell 2000).
  • If no such technology were available, the firm could not recoup the unit cost with the highest possible expected fine, which in turn implies that payment evasion cannot be an additional source of profit.

2.2 Consumers

  • The authors consider a market with a mass ofN potential consumers who observe the pricep and the finef before making a choice.
  • Assumption 1 assures that consumers self-select into one ofthree segments.
  • Notice that Assumption1 implies that the consumers who evade payment suffer from a perceived qualitydegradation (Yaniv 2009, Belleflamme and Peitz 2012).
  • This definition implies that a higher price increases payment evasion (∂E/∂ p > 0), mirroring the associated reduction in demand (∂D/∂ p < 0).
  • In effect, payment evasion allows the firm to sells two versions of the same product at different prices to consumers with different valuations of these versions.

3 Managing Payment Evasion

  • This section derives the optimal price and fine in the presence of payment evasion and provides the relevant comparative statics.
  • In addition, weconsider two extensions where the firm has additional tools to deal with payment evasion.
  • First, the authors allow the firm to choose the effectiveness of its enforcement technology through costly effort.
  • To simplify exposition, the authors suppress the dependence on the model parameters wherever possible.

3.1 Optimal Price and Fine

  • In the presence of payment evasion, the firm can generate profit from two consumer segments: paying consumers and payment evaders.
  • The reason for the cost-reducing effect is that some payment evaders are deterred and leave the market.
  • The maximum admissible fine and the evasion cost clearly affect th firm’s choice of the optimal price.
  • In addition, Proposition 2 shows that higher evasion costs go along with a higher price.
  • 12This result is reminiscent of multiproduct monopoly pricing with interdependent demands when the products are substitutes (Tirole 1988, p. 69).

3.2 Endogenous Detection Probability

  • To endogenize the choice of the detection technology, the authors nowassume that the firm can influence both the detection probability and the cost of the det ction technology through its choice of costly effort.
  • To this end, the authors extend their model to a setting where the firm makes sequential decisions.
  • Specifically, the authors consider the following two-stage game:.
  • This timeline captures a business environment in which the control effort can be varied in the short run, whereas the price and the fine are chosen in the long run.13 0.
  • In addition, Proposition 5 shows that the comparative statics with respect to f̄ are similar to the predictions in the law and economics literature:.

3.3 Endogenous Technological Protection

  • The authors now assume that the firm can invest in technical protectionto raise the evasion cost borne by consumers before it chooses the price and the fine.
  • 14Examples include the installment of anti-shoplifting devices or the use of digital rights management systems.
  • Clearly, the optimal choice of technical protection depends on the functional form of the cost functionFk(k).
  • Now, if the solution to problem (8), denoted ask∗, exceeds̄k, a level ofk so high that evading payment is “too costly,” payment evasion is prevented endogenously by means of technical protection.
  • Fork∗ < k̄, there remains some level of payment evasion, which is detected with probabilityπ .

4 Illustrative Example

  • The authors now illustrate their above analysis with an example where the consumers’ indirect utility functions are explicitly specified.
  • For simplicity, the authors setN equal to unity and assume that consumer typesθ are drawn independently from a uniform distribution over the interval[0,1].
  • In addition, the authors assume that consumers have rational expectations about the actual detection probability and setφ = π .
  • In addition, notice that the demand for the outside option does not dependon the pricep.
  • The next result illustrates the key results derived in Propositions1 to 4.

5 Empirical Evidence

  • The authors examine payment evasion on theZurich Transport Network(ZVV), where evading payment is equivalent to fare dodging.
  • In contrast to the extensive literature on the impact of public enforcement on unlawful behavior (see, e.g., Levitt 1997, DiTella and Schargrodsky 2004, DeAngelo 15Waldfogel (2012b) provides a comprehensive survey on the empirics of digital piracy.
  • 14 and Hansen 2014), the authors focus on the private enforcement by the ZVV, exploiting passengerlevel data over a period of four years, extending from June 1,2009 to May 31, 2013.
  • Then, the authors compare the characteristics of all passengers who use public transportation with those of payment evaders, using census data and individual-level data from the ZVV.
  • Next, the authors estimate the amount of payment evasion on the transport network.

5.1 Transportation Company

  • The ZVV is a public transportation company that coordinatesmore than 50 operators and offers railroad, bus, tram, and boat services in Zurich and its surrounding regions.
  • Specifically, the ZVV chooses the following fines: Passengers who fail to present a valid ticket are required toprove their identity and to pay CHF 80 (about $85) in the case of a first offense.
  • In the case of a thirdoffense (or more than three offenses), the fine increases to CHF 150 (about $160), but there are no criminal charges pressed.
  • The personal information collected from payment evaders isstored in a data pool operated by the ZVV.
  • 17Additional charges apply for noncooperative behavior in ticket inspections, giving incorrect personal information, and for forging tickets (which may lead to criminal prosecution).

5.2 Passengers

  • The characteristics of passengers who use the ZVV transportnetwork are obtained from a sample constructed from 2010 census data on transportationand mobility.
  • 18 This indirect approach using census data is necessary to construct a reference group, since the ZVV solely collects data on detected payment evaders.
  • The characteristics of payment evaders are obtained from a sample constructed from data provided by the ZVV which covers the time span June 1, 2009 to May 31, 2013.19.
  • A unique feature of the data is that it includes all passengers who have been detected as payment evaders during the sample period.
  • Second, roughly 20% of the payment evaders are caught repeatedly.

5.3 Payment Evasion

  • Tickets inspections on the ZVV network are unannounced and co ucted by plain-clothes agents.
  • Next, the authors usêπ and the number of detected payment evadersẼ to estimate the total amount of payment evasion asÊ = Ẽ/π̂, which is the empirical counterpart of payment evasionE in the theoretical model (see Definition 1).
  • Table 3 summarizes these estimates and provides the relevant deterrence levels for first-time and repeat offenses.
  • It is worth noting that even the lowest available ticket price is higher than any of the expected fines, a necessary condition for payment evasion to occur (consistent with Proposition 1).
  • Second, further increasing the detection probability through higher effort is too costly.

5.4 Increase in Maximum Admissible Fines

  • The industry association for public transportation allowed its members to charge higher maximum fines for payment evasion starting from June 1, 2011.
  • Some high-type evaders are induced to pay the price, while some l w-type evaders are induced to refrain from consumption, as illustrated in Figure 2.
  • Reweighting is 20 performed such that the distribution of all offenders is taken as the reference distribution, and the individuals in the different offense groups are reweight d accordingly.
  • Accounting for the change in the control effort does not qualitatively affect the results.
  • Table 3 suggests that the detection probability was indeed reduceda cordingly.

6 Conclusion

  • This paper has examined endogenous payment evasion in a model where the firm can charge a price to paying consumers and levy a fine on consumerswho are detected as payment evaders.
  • In addition, the authors have provided empirical evidence on payment evasion on theZurich Transport Network, where evading payment is equivalent to fare dodging.
  • In the theoretical part, the authors have derived three key results.
  • Specifically, the presence of payment evaders leads to a peculiar form of price discrimination where the regular price exceeds the expected fine.
  • The authors havconstructed the empirical counterparts of the relevant quantities in the theoreticalmodel, and they have found that the exogenous increase in the maximum admissible fines did not have a significant effect on payment evasion.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

School of Economics and Political Science,
Department of Economics
University of St.Gallen
Payment Evasion
Stefan Buehler, Daniel Halbheer, Michael Lechner
November 2014 Discussion Paper no. 2014-35

Editor:
Martina Flockerzi
University of St.Gallen
School of Economics and Political Science
Department of Economics
Bodanstrasse 8
CH-9000 St. Gallen
Phone +41 71 224 23 25
Fax +41 71 224 31 35
Email seps@unisg.ch
Publisher:
Electronic Publication:
School of Economics and Political Science
Department of Economics
University of St.Gallen
Bodanstrasse 8
CH-9000 St. Gallen
Phone +41 71 224 23 25
Fax +41 71 224 31 35
http://www.seps.unisg.ch

Payment Evasion
1
Stefan Buehler, Daniel Halbheer, Michael Lechner
Author’s address:
Prof. Stefan Buehler
FGN-HSG
Varnbüelstrasse 19
CH-9000 St. Gallen
Phone +41 71 224 23 03
Fax +41 71 224 28 74
Email stefan.buehler@unisg.ch
Website www.fgn.unisg.ch
Associate Prof. Daniel Halbheer
HEC Paris
Department of Marketing
1, rue de la Libération
78351 Jouy-en-Josas Cedex
France
Email halbheer@hec.fr
Prof. Michael Lechner
SEW-HSG
Varnbüelstrasse 14
CH-9000 St. Gallen
Phone +41 71 224 28 14
Fax +41 71 224 23 02
Email michael.lechner@unisg.ch
Website www.sew.unisg.ch
1
The authors thank the Zurich Transport Network ZVV, Hofwiesenstrasse 370, 8090 Zurich, and in particular Peter
Nordenson, for providing the data, as well as Berno B¨uchel, Aaron Edlin, Preyas Desai, Markus Reisinger, and seminar
participants at the University of Hamburg, the University of Lausanne, and the University of Nuremberg for helpful
comments and suggestions.

Abstract
This paper models payment evasion as a source of profit by letting the firm choose the price
charged to paying consumers and the fine collected from detected payment evaders. The
consumers choose whether to purchase, evade payment, or refrain from consumption. We
show that payment evasion allows the firm to charge a higher price to paying consumers and
to generate a higher profit. We also show that higher fines do not necessarily reduce
payment evasion. Finally, we provide empirical evidence which is consistent with our
theoretical analysis, using comprehensive micro data on fare dodging on the Zurich
Transport Network.
Keywords
Payment Evasion, Pricing, Fine, Self-Selection.

1 Introduction
Payment evasion—fraudulent consumption by nonpaying consumers—is a serious issue
for firms in different industries. There are various ways in which consumers might obtain
a product or service without payment, including shoplifting (Yaniv 2009, Perlman and
Ozinci 2014), wardrobing (Timoumi and Coughlan 2014), and digital piracy (Chellappa
and Shivendu 2005, Vernik et al. 2011).
1
Another classic example for payment evasion
is fare dodging on public transportation (Boyd et al. 1989, Kooreman 1993).
2
Standard price theory abstracts from payment evasion and posits the excludability
of nonpaying consumers based on pricing alone. Or, as Hirshleifer et al. (2005, p. 19)
put it: “To acquire a commodity buyers must be willing to pay the market price [...].
The implicit assumption is, of course, that the consumers’ cost associated with payment
evasion are high enough for them to refrain from fraudulent consumption. It is well
known, though, that many products exhibit some degree of nonexcludability (Novos and
Waldman 1984). Several legal instruments have been designed to enforce the exclusion
of nonpaying consumers, including patents, copyrights, and trade marks. Yet, since the
enforcement by public agencies is sketchy and varies across jurisdictions, firms undertake
substantial private investments in technologies to detect and punish payment evasion.
Antitheft devices, video-surveillance cameras, and digital rights management systems all
serve this purpose. It is fair to say that firms spend great effort on managing payment
evasion, but they rarely eliminate it.
In line with this observation, this paper models payment evasion as a source of profit
for the firm. Our focus is therefore on the management of payment evasion, rather than
its elimination. Key to our analysis is the firm’s ability to collect fines—albeit limited up
to a maximum admissible level mandated by law—from consumers detected as payment
evaders.
3
In such a setting, there are two sources of revenue: paying consumers and
payment evaders. We develop a model in which the firm chooses both the price charged
to paying consumers and the fine faced by payment evaders in order to maximize its
expected profit. An important feature is that the demands from paying consumers and
payment evaders are interdependent. Observing the price and the fine, consumers can
1
Belleflamme and Peitz (2012, 2014) provide a comprehensivesurvey and a recent update on the theory
of digital piracy.
2
Recent evidence from the US shows that shoplifters steal more than $13 billion worth of goods from
retailers every year (National Association for Shoplifting Prevention 2014); return fraud costed retailers
more than $9 billion in 2013 (National Retail Federation 2014); the consumption of digitally pirated music
in 2008 is estimated to be between $7 and $20 billion (Frontier Economics 2012).
3
Retailers, for instance, regularly impose in-store penalties for shoplifting. Under New York’s state law,
retailers may collect a penalty “not to exceed the greater of ve times the retail price of the merchandise”
(N.Y. GOB. LAW §11-105).
2

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors conducted an artefactual field experiment using a diversified sample of passengers of public transportations to study attitudes towards dishonesty and found that the diversity of behavior in terms of dis/honesty in laboratory tasks and in the field correlate.
Abstract: We conduct an artefactual field experiment using a diversified sample of passengers of public transportations to study attitudes towards dishonesty. We find that the diversity of behavior in terms of dis/honesty in laboratory tasks and in the field correlate. Moreover, individuals who have just been fined in the field behave more honestly in the lab than the other fare-dodgers, except when context is introduced. Overall, we show that simple tests of dishonesty in the lab can predict moral firmness in life, although frauders who care about social image cheat less when behavior can be verified ex post by the experimenter.

48 citations


Cites background from "Payment Evasion: Payment Evasion"

  • ...4 Surprisingly, economic studies on fare evasion are very few (Boyd et al., 1989; Kooreman, 1993; Nikiforakis, 2007; Bucciol et al., 2013; Buehler et al., 2014)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: An overview and classification in five main areas, i.e., fare evader-oriented, criminological, economic, technological, and operational, of the research on fare evasion is provided.
Abstract: Fare evasion has become an important issue for public transport companies, especially for those that have adopted proof-of-payment ticketing systems. Recent years have seen strong growth in the publication of studies on fare evasion. This paper reviews 113 studies to identify the characteristics of the research on fare evasion. An overview and classification in five main areas, i.e., fare evader-oriented, criminological, economic, technological, and operational is provided. Next, the status quo of these studies is assessed to support possible unifying research development.

40 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A Hybrid Discrete Choice model is proposed to understand current evaders’ behavior considering sociodemographic, fare evasion records, trip characteristics, user satisfaction with the transport system, and perceptual indicators and found that personality traits, such as individual rule-unconsciousness, moderate the effect of satisfaction on the evasion behavior.
Abstract: Fare evasion is currently a significant concern for public transport systems worldwide. Evasion causes huge economic losses to operators and cities, but also negatively influences the system’s security perceptions. Despite its importance, there are few efforts to understand which observable and non-observable factors motivate individuals to evade fares in a public transport system. Most studies dealing with fare evasion evaluate the effectiveness of several policies, quantify the amount of evasion, or correlate fare evasion with system satisfaction using aggregate data. This paper proposes a Hybrid Discrete Choice model to understand current evaders’ behavior considering sociodemographic, fare evasion records, trip characteristics, user satisfaction with the transport system, and perceptual indicators. The model was estimated using a unique stated preferences survey applied to 324 fare evaders of Transmilenio, the Bogota (Colombia) Bus Rapid Transit system, in mid-2019. This is an interesting case study because, in 2018, the evasion rate was measured for the first time and it was discovered that evaders comprised approximately 15% of their users on weekdays. The contribution of this research is twofold. First, results highlight the importance of considering observable and latent variables to understand individual behavior in examining fare evasion in similar public transport systems. Age and the evasion records resulted in being the most important observable variables in our case study. Latent variables suggest that the more the user is satisfied with the transport system, the less likely is to evade fares. However, we found that personality traits, such as individual rule-unconsciousness, moderate the effect of satisfaction on the evasion behavior. Second, our results provide evidence that the discussion between certainty and severity of punishment on fare evasion should not necessarily be centered on whether to exacerbate one of these factors. A combination of both, however, should reduce the recidivism rate.

10 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a unified analytical framework that nests monopoly pricing and optimal law enforcement is presented for escalating prices and fines, and it is shown that escalation emerges as an optimal outcome if the principal lacks commitment ability and gives less than full weight to agent benefits.
Abstract: This paper provides an explanation for escalating prices and fines based on a unified analytical framework that nests monopoly pricing and optimal law enforcement. We show that escalation emerges as an optimal outcome if the principal (i) lacks commitment ability, and (ii) gives less than full weight to agent benefits. Escalation is driven by decreasing transfers for non-active agents rather than increasing transfers for active agents. Some forward-looking agents then strategically delay their activity, which drives a wedge between the optimal static transfer and the benefit of an indifferent agent. This wedge is the source of escalation.

9 citations


Cites background from "Payment Evasion: Payment Evasion"

  • ...3That is, law enforcement is uncertain (Polinsky and Shavell, 2007), or consumption may be subject to payment evasion (Buehler et al., 2017)....

    [...]

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In fact, some common properties are shared by practically all legislation, and these properties form the subject matter of this essay as discussed by the authors, which is the basis for this essay. But, in spite of such diversity, some commonsense properties are not shared.
Abstract: Since the turn of the twentieth century, legislation in Western countries has expanded rapidly to reverse the brief dominance of laissez faire during the nineteenth century. The state no longer merely protects against violations of person and property through murder, rape, or burglary but also restricts ‘discrimination’ against certain minorities, collusive business arrangements, ‘jaywalking’, travel, the materials used in construction, and thousands of other activities. The activities restricted not only are numerous but also range widely, affecting persons in very different pursuits and of diverse social backgrounds, education levels, ages, races, etc. Moreover, the likelihood that an offender will be discovered and convicted and the nature and extent of punishments differ greatly from person to person and activity to activity. Yet, in spite of such diversity, some common properties are shared by practically all legislation, and these properties form the subject matter of this essay.

9,613 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, two sampling schemes are discussed in connection with the problem of determining optimum selection probabilities according to the information available in a supplementary variable, which is a general technique for the treatment of samples drawn without replacement from finite universes when unequal selection probabilities are used.
Abstract: This paper presents a general technique for the treatment of samples drawn without replacement from finite universes when unequal selection probabilities are used. Two sampling schemes are discussed in connection with the problem of determining optimum selection probabilities according to the information available in a supplementary variable. Admittedly, these two schemes have limited application. They should prove useful, however, for the first stage of sampling with multi-stage designs, since both permit unbiased estimation of the sampling variance without resorting to additional assumptions. * Journal Paper No. J2139 of the Iowa Agricultural Experiment Station, Ames, Iowa, Project 1005. Presented to the Institute of Mathematical Statistics, March 17, 1951.

3,990 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation (TIIN) as mentioned in this paper is a popular textbook for regulatory economics, with a particular focus on the regulation of natural monopolies such as military contractors, utility companies and transportation authorities.
Abstract: More then just a textbook, A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation will guide economists' research on regulation for years to come. It makes a difficult and large literature of the new regulatory economics accessible to the average graduate student, while offering insights into the theoretical ideas and stratagems not available elsewhere. Based on their pathbreaking work in the application of principal-agent theory to questions of regulation, Laffont and Tirole develop a synthetic approach, with a particular, though not exclusive, focus on the regulation of natural monopolies such as military contractors, utility companies, and transportation authorities. The book's clear and logical organization begins with an introduction that summarizes regulatory practices, recounts the history of thought that led to the emergence of the new regulatory economics, sets up the basic structure of the model, and previews the economic questions tackled in the next seventeen chapters. The structure of the model developed in the introductory chapter remains the same throughout subsequent chapters, ensuring both stability and consistency. The concluding chapter discusses important areas for future work in regulatory economics. Each chapter opens with a discussion of the economic issues, an informal description of the applicable model, and an overview of the results and intuition. It then develops the formal analysis, including sufficient explanations for those with little training in information economics or game theory. Bibliographic notes provide a historical perspective of developments in the area and a description of complementary research. Detailed proofs are given of all major conclusions, making the book valuable as a source of modern research techniques. There is a large set of review problems at the end of the book.

3,619 citations

Journal ArticleDOI

3,258 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (2)
Q1. What are the contributions mentioned in the paper "Payment evasion" ?

This paper models payment evasion as a source of profit by letting the firm choose the price charged to paying consumers and the fine collected from detected payment evaders. The authors show that payment evasion allows the firm to charge a higher price to paying consumers and to generate a higher profit. The authors also show that higher fines do not necessarily reduce payment evasion. Finally, the authors provide empirical evidence which is consistent with their theoretical analysis, using comprehensive micro data on fare dodging on the Zurich Transport Network. 

Their analysis suggests several avenues for future research. Second, one could extend the analysis to allow for competition among firms to study the role of payment evasion as a particular form of non-price competition. The authors hope to address these issues in future research.