TL;DR: In this article, the authors investigate the sequencing choice of a buyer who negotiates with the sellers of two complementary objects with uncertain payoffs and identify the first and second-mover advantages for the sellers.
Abstract: This article investigates the sequencing choice of a buyer who negotiates with the sellers of two complementary objects with uncertain payoffs. The possibility of inefficient trade may generate strict sequencing preference. The buyer begins with the weaker seller if the sellers have diverse bargaining powers and with the stronger one if both sellers are strong bargainers. This sequencing is likely to increase the social surplus. Moreover, the buyer may find it optimal to raise her own acquisition cost by committing to a minimum purchase price or outsourcing. The first- and second-mover advantages for the sellers are also identified.
When both sellers are strong bargainers, the buyer’s concern for aggressive pricing shifts to the last seller.
The authors paper belongs to a growing literature on one-to-many bargaining, and complements several papers that address the issue of optimal bargaining sequence without payoff uncertainty.
In Section 5, the authors show that the buyer’s expected payoff may decrease with her own bargaining power and examine the two procurement policies alluded to above.
2 The Model
An employer often has to interview a job candidate to determine the match value; a home-owner frequently needs to consult with a contractor for a customized project; and a real-estate developer may require access to the construction history of a land parcel from the landowner.
It is also conceivable that αi may simply reflect the intrinsic bargaining ability of the seller vis-à-vis the buyer.
Having obtained the two prices pi and pj , and ascertained her valuations v i and vj , the buyer decides which goods to purchase (if any).
Thus, the authors call any equilibrium inefficient if it involves less than joint purchase with a positive probability.
2.1 Discussion of the Assumptions
The authors keep each buyer-seller bargaining simple to better focus on sequencing; nevertheless, their one-shot bargaining can be a good approximation of applications in which the buyer has a short time to acquire the goods, or else the trade opportunity is lost.
But, such a “monotonic” incentive would then lead to the 12For instance, for many customized goods and services such as home re-modeling and landscaping, contractors give a free price estimate to which the customer needs to respond in a short-time period.
6 full disclosure of pi, much like in the literature on signaling a verifiable quality, e.g., Grossman (1981).
Perhaps, what is more important is that sellers know the sequence.
The authors envision environments where any meeting between the buyer and sellers is highly visible or publicized, or it can be easily inferred by the sellers from the calendar time.
3 Equilibrium Characterization
The authors characterize the equilibrium prices for a fixed negotiation sequence.
Recall, however, that the authors break ties in favor of social efficiency.
This requires a price coordination with seller j.
Note also that as the likelihood of having a low-value product j, qj, increases, seller j’s price decreases; but seller i’s price is increasing in qj only when αj is large due to the coordination incentive.
4 Strategic Sequencing
A key observation from Proposition 2 is that for a fixed sequence of negotiations, the sellers’ bargaining powers and the buyer’s payoff uncertainty each influence equilibrium prices.
Since, under an efficient trade, the extra surplus due to complementarity is captured by the sellers unless the buyer proposes in both negotiations, the buyer is indifferent to the sequence.
The authors next finding uncovers how the buyer’s sequencing choice depends on the sellers’ bargaining powers.
The buyer strictly prefers to start negotiations with seller 1 because, being followed by a strong rival, seller 1 has an equilibrium incentive to coordinate prices by lowering his own.
19 According to part (b), even though the buyer is not maximizing the social surplus per se, her sequencing choice increases it.
5 Benefits of Being a Weak Buyer
Up to now, two robust insights have emerged from their analysis.
First, the buyer cares about the negotiation sequence when equilibrium trade is inefficient and at least one seller is a powerful bargainer.
The answer to this question can indeed be affirmative.
Proposition 6 implies that it may sometimes be in the buyer’s best interest to limit her own bargaining power vis-à-vis the sellers.
Consistent with their model, these authors define buyer power as “the bargaining strength that a buyer has with respect to the suppliers with whom it trades.”.
5.1 Minimum Purchase Price
One reason why the sellers may price aggressively in their model is that in equilibrium, the buyer always makes the lowest price offer, namely the marginal-cost, 0.
In particular, it may entice the leading seller to disregard price coordination with the follower and target the buyer’s entire surplus of 1 instead.
It is evident that any positive payment by the buyer will allow the sellers to earn positive profits regardless of who makes the offer while reducing the buyer’s own payoff.
Note that an upfront commitment to w > 0 is crucial here, because, once the leading seller lowers his price offer, the buyer has a strict incentive to lower her offer to 0 in the second negotiation whenever she proposes.
In the same vein, large employers might favor minimum wage regulations when hiring new employees.
5.2 The Make-or-Buy Decision
A critical decision for many industrial buyers is whether to make inputs internally or outsource them from independent suppliers.
If two complementary inputs are required, as in the present setting, the following result shows that the buyer may optimally outsource an input even if it could be costlessly provided inhouse.
Second, the authors know from Proposition 1 that two powerful suppliers would have the greatest incentives to coordinate and lower their prices.
In contrast, in their model, a single firm outsources production to raise its own cost for an input to receive a favorable deal from the other supplier of a complementary input.
6 First- vs. Second-Mover Advantages for Sellers
So far the authors have focused on the buyer’s preference over the negotiation sequence since she is the central agent who initiates the negotiations.
It is, however, conceivable that the sellers will also have a preference.
In particular, if, all else equal, the sellers expect a higher profit from being the first to negotiate with the buyer than being the second, then they may actively solicit the buyer’s business by offering a discount for the right to be the first.
Otherwise, there will be a second-mover advantage since the follower can then have a significant chance to claim the buyer’s entire surplus if the buyer ends up proposing in the first negotiation.
It is worth comparing their observations from Proposition 9 with those from the standard duopoly theory in which the sellers are price-setters, i.e, α → 1.
7 Concluding Remarks
Unlike the standard consumer theory, the buyer is not a simple price-taker in many real examples; rather she is a powerful agent who actively negotiates the price with the sellers.
The authors first set of results have revealed that to the extent that equilibrium trade is efficient, the buyer will be neutral to the sequence.
The authors believe that this efficiency reasoning is also the driving force behind the similar “indifference” findings in the literature.
In such cases, it would be interesting to determine the buyer’s incentive to invest in this information prior to negotiations given that her sequencing choice can signal her valuations to the sellers.
TL;DR: In this article, the authors develop a model of patent trolls to understand various litigation strategies employed by nonpracticing entities and discuss policy implications including legal fee shifting and the use of injunctive relief.
Abstract: This article develops a model of patent trolls to understand various litigation strategies employed by nonpracticing entities (NPEs). When an NPE faces multiple potential infringers who use related technologies, it can gain a credible threat to litigate even when it has no such credibility vis-a-vis any single potential infringer in isolation. This is due to an information externality generated by an early litigation outcome for subsequent litigation. Successful litigation creates an option value against future potential infringers through Bayesian updating. We discuss policy implications including legal fee shifting and the use of injunctive relief.
TL;DR: This analysis shows that the information of individual sensitivity leads to additional expected profit in the optimal dynamic quotation of leadtime and price for a Make-To-Order manufacturer to improve its expected profit.
Abstract: We study the optimal dynamic quotation of leadtime and price for a Make-To-Order manufacturer to improve its expected profit. The manufacturer knows the probability distribution of customers’ sensitivity on quoted leadtime and price according to history data. They can also obtain information on individual sensitivity of each customer through negotiations with customers. Our analysis shows that the information of individual sensitivity leads to additional expected profit. Moreover, our numerical experiments demonstrate that the additional expected profit can be significant.
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors studied a complete-information bargaining game with one buyer and multiple sellers of different sizes or bargaining strengths, where the bargaining order is determined endogenously. And they showed that with an infinite horizon, if the sellers have sufficiently different sizes, there is a unique equilibrium outcome, which has the same bargaining order.
Abstract: This paper studies a complete-information bargaining game with one buyer and multiple sellers of different “sizes” or bargaining strengths. The bargaining order is determined endogenously. With a finite horizon, there is a unique subgame perfect equilibrium outcome, in which the buyer purchases in order of increasing size–from the smallest to the largest. With an infinite horizon, if the sellers have sufficiently different sizes, there is a unique equilibrium outcome, which has the same bargaining order. If the sellers have similar sizes with an infinite horizon, there may be multiple equilibrium outcomes with different bargaining orders.
TL;DR: In this article, the authors investigated how the microentrepreneurs running water refill stations assess the income generation potential of drinking water sale in Jakarta including the motivations to start up and sustain the business as well as the challenges they face with in the water market.
Abstract: This study discovers how the microentrepreneurs running water refill stations (WRSs) assess the income generation potential of drinking water sale in Jakarta including the motivations to start up and sustain the business as well as the challenges they face with in the water market. The study further provides insights on the broader externalities to which WRSs have contributed. The design of the research and the paper is inspired by the Theory of Evolutionary Economics and the Institutional Theory. Case study approach was employed utilizing qualitative research methods.
The study has found that the main motivations of microenterprises rely not only on the monetary incentives but also on the appreciation shown in society; which implies a set of factors from both the market and non-market environments. The main challenges, however, occur mainly in the market environment due to the lack of legal regulations specific to WRSs and the competition among microentrepreneurs. With regards to the externalities, WRS have been found to spontaneously contribute to the increased awareness of water quality at the societal level.
It can be concluded that the perceptions of market participants are positive and they are satisfied with the dynamics of water market in Jakarta.
TL;DR: In this article, the authors examine bargaining sequences in the setting where a downstream firm makes a merger decision with an upstream partner and faces a negotiation with a union, and they show that when the downstream firm's power in the wage bargaining is relatively equal, firms opt for separation and both negotiations keep on simultaneously.
Abstract: Bargaining sequences, though vital to the real-world business strategies, are often treated as exogenously given. We examine bargaining sequences in the setting where a downstream firm makes a merger decision with an upstream partner and faces a negotiation with a union. When the downstream firm's power in the wage bargaining is weak, separation results and the input price bargaining proceeds prior to the wage bargaining. When the downstream firm's power in both negotiations is relatively equal, firms opt for separation and both negotiations keep on simultaneously. When the downstream firm's power in the wage negotiation is strong, the firms merge.
TL;DR: The Informational Role of Warranties and Private Disclosure about Product Quality Author(s): Sanford J. Grossman Source: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 24, No. 3, Consumer Protection Regulation: A Conference Sponsored by the Center for the Study of the Economy and the State (Dec., 1981), pp. 461-483 as mentioned in this paper
Abstract: The Informational Role of Warranties and Private Disclosure about Product Quality Author(s): Sanford J. Grossman Source: Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 24, No. 3, Consumer Protection Regulation: A Conference Sponsored by the Center for the Study of the Economy and the State (Dec., 1981), pp. 461-483 Published by: The University of Chicago Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/725273 Accessed: 27/08/2008 20:18
TL;DR: In this article, a model of duopoly in which firms acquire inputs through bilateral monopoly relations with suppliers is presented, which combines a bargaining model with a duopoly model to examine how input pri...
Abstract: The paper presents a model of duopoly in which firms acquire inputs through bilateral monopoly relations with suppliers. It combines a bargaining model with a duopoly model to examine how input pri ...
TL;DR: In this paper, a non-cooperative multilateral bargaining framework between the firm and its employees is presented, and equilibrium firm profits are characterizable as both a weighted average of a neo-classical (non-bargaining) firm's profits and a generalization of Shapley value for a corresponding cooperative game.
Abstract: We present a new methodology for studying the problem of intra-firm bargaining, based on the notion that contracts cannot commit the firm and its agents to wages and employment. We develop and analyse a general non-cooperative multilateral bargaining framework between the firm and its employees and consider outcomes which are immune to renegotiations by any party. Equilibrium firm profits are characterizable as both a weighted average of a neo-classical (non-bargaining) firm's profits and a generalization of Shapley value for a corresponding cooperative game. Furthermore, the resulting payoffs induce economically significant distortions in the firm's input and organizational-design decisions.
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors study inefficiencies arising in contracting between one principal and N agents when the utility of each agent depends on all agents' trades with the principal and show that when N is large, each agent can be treated as non-pivotal, provided that appropriate continuity assumptions are satisfied.
Abstract: The paper studies inefficiencies arising in contracting between one principal and N agents when the utility of each agent depends on all agents' trades with the principal. When the principal commits to a set of publicly observable bilateral contract offers, the arising inefficiency is due entirely to the externalities imposed on non-signers. In contrast, when the principal's offers are privately observed, the distortion is due to the externalities given agents' equilibrium trades. Comparison of the two externalities determines the relative efficiency of the two contracting regimes. In both cases, we show that when N is large, each agent can be treated as non-pivotal, provided that appropriate continuity assumptions are satisfied. We also study the case in which the principal can condition each agent's trade on other agents' messages. We characterize the set of such mechanisms in which each agent's participation is voluntary. When the principal can commit to any such mechanism, she implements the first-best outcome, while threatening each deviator with the harshest possible punishment. However, in the presence of noise that goes to zero slower than N goes to infinity, in the limit we obtain a (generally inefficient) outcome in which each agent feels non-pivotal.
Q1. What are the contributions mentioned in the paper "Payoff uncertainty, bargaining power, and the strategic sequencing of bilateral negotiations" ?
This paper investigates the sequencing choice of a buyer who negotiates with the sellers of two complementary objects with uncertain payoffs. The authors show that the sequencing matters to the buyer only when equilibrium trade can be inefficient. Their analysis further reveals that it is sometimes optimal for the buyer to raise her own cost of acquisition to better manage the supplier competition. As such, the authors find that the buyer may commit to paying the sellers a minimum price strictly above the marginal cost ; and that the buyer may outsource an input even though it can be made in-house.
Q2. What are the future works in "Payoff uncertainty, bargaining power, and the strategic sequencing of bilateral negotiations" ?
In this paper, the authors have focused on the sellers of complementary goods, and included the possibility that the buyer can be uncertain of her valuations. Their first set of results have revealed that to the extent that equilibrium trade is efficient, the buyer will be neutral to the sequence. The authors believe that this efficiency reasoning is also the driving force behind the similar “ indifference ” findings in the literature. This commitment can manifest itself in the form of a procurement policy such as a minimum purchase price or the outsourcing of an input when it can be made in-house at the same cost.