scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Preference stability along time: the time cohesiveness measure

04 Mar 2017-Progress in Artificial Intelligence (Springer Berlin Heidelberg)-Vol. 6, Iss: 3, pp 235-244
TL;DR: This work introduces a non-traditional perspective about the problem of measuring the stability of agents’ preferences under the assumption of considering dichotomous evaluations, and introduces a particular formulation based on the consideration of any two successive moments of time, the sequential time cohesiveness measure.
Abstract: This work introduces a non-traditional perspective about the problem of measuring the stability of agents’ preferences. Specifically, the cohesiveness of preferences at different moments of time is explored under the assumption of considering dichotomous evaluations. The general concept of time cohesiveness measure is introduced as well as a particular formulation based on the consideration of any two successive moments of time, the sequential time cohesiveness measure. Moreover, some properties of the novel measure are also provided. Finally, and in order to emphasize the adaptability of our proposal to real situations, a factual case of study about clinical decision-making is presented. Concretely, the study of preference stability for life-sustaining treatments of patients with advanced cancer at end of life is analysed. The research considers patients who express their opinions on three life-sustaining treatments at four consecutive periods of time. The novel measure provides information of patients preference stability along time and considers the possibility of cancer metastases.

Summary (2 min read)

1 Introduction

  • Intertemporal decision making is an important scientific area and it has been obtaining attention from several research fields such as Economics, Health Economics, Social Choice, Psychology, Marketing, Decision Analysis, Neuroscience, and so on.
  • Related to empirical literature on preference stability, most studies use small samples in short time periods and they are focused on a specific type of preferences, the risk preferences [27].
  • For this purpose, the notion of preference stability is considered in the same vein that the notion of cohesiveness.
  • Moreover, an specific formulation of the time cohesiveness measure is introduced, the sequential time cohesiveness measure as well as a study of its analytic properties.
  • Furthermore, the measurement proposed is put in practice in a real case of study to emphasise its applicability.

2 A new tool to measure preference stability: The time cohesiveness measure

  • This section is devoted to introduce some notation as well as their proposal of measurement of preference stability, namely, the time cohesiveness measure.
  • Similarly, n tj ,tj+1 1,1 denotes the number of agents that approve alternative x at tj and keep their opinion at the following point of time tj+1.
  • This property shows that the main aspect of the time sequential cohesiveness measure is the stability of agents’ opinions more than an specific value.
  • In order to leave the minimum time stability it is needed that at least the opinions of two agents coincide at the same moment of time and the next one.
  • If the introduction of new moments of time does not affect agents’ opinions in past times, then the sequential time cohesiveness measure of the extended time preference profile P (q) ∈ PN×(T+q) approaches 1 when q tends to infinity.

3 Comparative analysis of preference stability in Clinical Decision Making: The case of terminally cancer patients’ last year of life

  • Acts have become significant with specific regard to life support options [5].
  • To tackle the aforementioned aims, it is necessary to achieve a detail study of patients’ preferences and their preference stability along their illness.
  • For that purpose, patients’ opinions were collected by means of an interview (an adapted LSPQ) where patients answer questions about their preferences of CPR, ICU and MSV treatment when life was in danger as Figure 1 shows.
  • A tube would be placed through your mouth or nose into your lungs.
  • Tables 9 and 10 show the values of the sequential time cohesiveness measure for the time-subprofiles distinguishing patients with and without metastases.

4 Concluding remarks

  • Research on preference stability topic has advanced mainly in Economics.
  • Under this assumption it could be appealing to develop a specific time cohesiveness measure.
  • Many problems from a diversity of fields could be tackled such as the consumers’ preferences, Clinical Decision Making problems and so on.
  • The authors thank the anonymous reviewers and S. Garćıa López and F. Herrera (Editors-in-Chief) for their valuable comments and recommendations.
  • The authors acknowledge financial support by the Spanish Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación under Project Project ECO201677900-P.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Figures (14)

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Noname manuscript No.
(will be inserted by the editor)
Preference stability along time: The time cohesiveness measure
T. Gonz´alez-Artega · R. de Andr´es Calle · M. Peral
Received: date / Accepted: date
Abstract This work introduces a non-traditional pers-
pective about the problem of measuring the stability
of agents’ preferences. Specifically, the cohesiveness of
preferences at different moments of time is explored un-
der the assumption of considering dichotomous evalu-
ations. The general concept of time cohesiveness mea-
sure is introduced as well as a particular formulation
based on the consideration of any two successive mo-
ments of time, the sequential time cohesiveness mea-
sure. Moreover, some properties of the novel measure
are also provided. Finally, and in order to emphasize
the adaptability of our proposal to real situations, a
factual case of study about Clinical Decision Making
is presented. Concretely, the study of preference stabil-
ity for life-sustaining treatments of patients with ad-
vanced cancer at end of life is analysed. The research
considers patients who express their opinions on three
life-sustaining treatments at four consecutive periods
of time. The novel measure provides information of pa-
tients preference stability along time and considers the
possibility of cancer metastases.
T. Gonz´alez-Artega
BORDA and PRESAD Research Groups and
Multidisciplinary Institute of Enterprise (IME),
University of Valladolid, E47011 Valladolid, Spain
E-mail: teresag@eio.uva.es
R. de Andr´es Calle
BORDA Research Unit, PRESAD Research Group and
Multidisciplinary Institute of Enterprise (IME),
University of Salamanca, E37007 Salamanca, Spain
E-mail: rocioac@usal.es
M. Peral
Centro de Atenci´on Primaria de Laguna de Duero,
E47140, Valladolid, Spain
E-mail: mperalh@saludcastillayleon.es
Keywords Time cohesiveness measure · Dichotomous
opinions · Preference stability · Patients’ preferences
1 Introduction
Intertemporal decision making is an important scientific
area and it has been obtaining attention from several
research fields such as Economics, Health Economics,
Social Choice, Psychology, Marketing, Decision Analy-
sis, Neuroscience, and so on.
One of the main topics of this area is the study of
preference stability that is often defined like the mea-
surement of the choice consistency among options along
time [8], [20], [28]. Traditionally, preferences have usually
been considered permanent by theory [23], although
there are also different studies to check if they are con-
stant over time [4], [7], [11], [26]. Related to empirical
literature on preference stability, most studies use small
samples in short time periods and they are focused on
a specific type of preferences, the risk preferences [27].
Recently, there has been an increment of works about
time preference [12], [22], [24], while there are few con-
tributions that study the stability of social preference
[10].
From another point of view, a growing number of
studies considers changes in preferences as a result of
shocks such as illness, civil wars, natural disasters, etc.
[9], [15], [21], [25].
The research to date has tend to explore preference
stability by means of statistical approaches: from basic
methods like descriptive analysis and multiple regres-
sion [22], [28] to more elaborate procedures like hierar-
chical generalized linear modelling [8] and others [29].
In order to enhance the preference stability topic,
the aim of this contribution is to develop a new tool

2 T. Gonz´alez-Artega et al.
capable of measuring preference stability from a non-
traditional perspective. For this purpose, the notion of
preference stability is considered in the same vein that
the notion of cohesiveness. This seems natural because
the measurement of preference stability resembles the
notion of measurement of cohesiveness over time, in the
sense that the maximum value captures the notion of
full stability, that is unanimity along time, while the
minimum value captures the notion of total lack of sta-
bility, that is, total disagreement along time.
The cohesiveness or consensus measurement has
been dealt in the Social Choice literature from Bosch’s
seminal work [6]. Subsequently, Alcalde-Unzu and
Vorsatz [1], Alcantud et al. [2] and Garc´ıa-Lapresta and
P´erez-Rom´an [14] introduced several classes of consen-
sus measures based on distances for ordinal informa-
tion. Additionally, several studies related to consensus
problem deal also with cardinal information like the
approaches proposed by Gonz´alez-Arteaga et al. [16],
Gonz´alez-Pach´on and Romero [17], Gonz´alez-Pacon et
al. [18], Herrera-Viedma et al. [19], and so on. From
another point of view, Alcantud, de Andr´es Calle and
Casc´on [3] introduced a cohesiveness measure when opin-
ions are dichotomous.
Taking into account the previous contributions on
preference stability and cohesiveness measure, this pa-
per is focused on an inter-temporal decision making
problem where a set of agents express their opinions
on an alternative along different moments of time. To
be precise, agents have to approve or disapprove the
alternative under study at diverse point of time. Thus,
the paper objective is to determine how much stability
or cohesiveness agents’ opinions conveys to the group
on the alternative along time. In order to measure such
stability, a new general approach is defined, the time
cohesiveness measure. Following the Social Choice tra-
dition, this measurement takes values in the unit inter-
val considering value 1 full stability and value 0 total
lack of stability. Moreover, an specific formulation of the
time cohesiveness measure is introduced, the sequential
time cohesiveness measure as well as a study of its ana-
lytic properties. Under this approach, the stability of
preferences is understood like the probability that for
a randomly chosen moment of time, two randomly cho-
sen agents have the same opinion at such a time and
its consecutive.
Furthermore, the measurement proposed is put in
practice in a real case of study to emphasise its ap-
plicability. In particular, the stability of preferences for
life-sustaining treatments in terminally cancer patients’
last year of life is analysed.
The paper is structured as follows. It has been di-
vided into three parts. The first part, Section 2, intro-
duces our proposal to measure preference stability: the
time cohesiveness measure. Moreover, an specific type
of this measure, the sequential time cohesiveness mea-
sure, is presented as well as its properties. The second
part, Section 3, includes an application of the novel ap-
proach to a real case of study. Finally, some concluding
remarks are provided.
2 A new tool to measure preference stability:
The time cohesiveness measure
This section is devoted to introduce some notation as
well as our proposal of measurement of preference sta-
bility, namely, the time cohesiveness measure. Then, an
specific formulation, the sequential time cohesiveness
measure, is defined and its properties are examined.
2.1 Notation
Let N = {1, 2, ..., N} a set of agents or experts. Agents
express their opinions on an alternative, x, at different
time moments T = {t
1
, . . . , t
T
} by means of dichoto-
mous opinions.
From now on, the notation used to formalize theses
assessments is the following:
Definition 1 A time preference profile of a set of agents
N on an alternative x at T different time moments is
an N × T matrix
P =
P
1t
1
. . . P
1t
T
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
P
Nt
1
. . . P
Nt
T
N×T
where P
it
j
is the opinion of the agent i over alternative
x at t
j
moment, in the sense
P
it
j
=
1 if agent i approves x at the t
j
time,
0 otherwise.
Let P
N×T
denote the set of all such N × T matrices.
For simplicity of notation, (1)
N×T
is the N × T matrix
whose cells are universally equal to 1 and (0)
N×T
is the
N × T matrix whose cells are universally equal to 0.
A time preference profile P is unanimous if alter-
native x is approved (resp. disapproved) over T by all
agents. In matrix terms, if the time preference
profile P P
N×T
is constant, P = (1)
N×T
(resp. P = (0)
N×T
).

Preference stability along time: The time cohesiveness measure 3
Any permutation σ of the agents {1, 2, ..., N } deter-
mines a time preference profile P
σ
by permutation of
the rows of P, that is, row i of the profile P
σ
is row
σ(i) of the profile P.
For each time preference profile P, P
S
is the restric-
tion to a subset of agents, an agent-subprofile on the
agents in S N, and it emerges from selecting the rows
of P that are associated with the respective agents in S.
For each time preference profile P, P
I
is the restric-
tion to a subset of consecutive moments of time, time-
subprofile on the moments of time in I T, and it
emerges from selecting consecutive columns of P that
are associated with the respective moments of time in
I. Any partition {I
1
, . . . , I
p
} of P generates a decom-
position of P into time-subprofiles P
I
1
, . . . , P
I
p
where
P
I
1
. . . P
I
p
= P.
An extension of a time preference profile P of a
group of agents N at T = {t
1
, . . . , t
T
} is a time prefe-
rence profile
P at T = {t
1
, . . . , t
T
, t
T +1
, . . . , t
T +q
} such
that the restriction of P to the first T moments of time
of T coincides with P.
A replication of a time preference profile P of a
group of agents N on alternative x is the time prefe-
rence profile P ] P P
2N×T
obtained by duplicating
each row of P, in the sense that rows r and N + r of
P ] P are row r of P, for each r = 1, ..., N.
For each time preference profile P on alternative x,
n
t
j
0
denotes the number of agents that disapprove x at
the t
j
moment of time, and n
t
j
1
denotes the number of
agents that approve alternative x at the t
j
moment of
time. Therefore, N = n
t
j
0
+ n
t
j
1
for each t
j
T.
In addition, n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
denotes the number of agents
that disapprove alternative x at t
j
and keep their opin-
ion at the following point of time t
j+1
. Similarly, n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
denotes the number of agents that approve alternative
x at t
j
and keep their opinion at the following point of
time t
j+1
.
In this way, n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,1
is the number of agents that
disapprove alternative x at t
j
but change their opinion
at t
j+1
, and n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,0
is the number of agents that ap-
prove alternative k at t
j
but change their opinion at
t
j+1
. For each t
j
T, n
t
j
0
= n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
+ n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,1
and like-
wise n
t
j
1
= n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
+ n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,0
. See Table 1 for improving
understanding.
For the purpose of clarifying the use of the pre-
vious notation, the following illustrative example is in-
troduced.
P
P
P
P
P
P
t
j
t
j+1
No Yes
No n
t
j
,t
j +1
0,0
n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,1
n
t
j
0
Yes n
t
j
,t
j +1
1,0
n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
n
t
j
1
n
t
j +1
0
n
t
j+1
1
N
Table 1 Notation summary table
Example 1 Let N = {1, 2, . . . , 10} be a set of ten agents
that express their opinions on alternative x along four
consecutive moments of time T = {t
1
, t
2
, t
3
, t
4
}. Their
time preference profile is:
P =
P
1t
1
. . . P
1t
4
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
P
10t
1
. . . P
10t
4
10×4
=
1 1 1 0
0 1 1 0
0 1 0 0
0 1 0 1
1 0 1 1
1 1 1 1
0 0 0 0
0 0 1 1
0 1 1 0
0 1 0 1
This time preference profile can be summarized in a
table containing the number of agents who approve or
disapprove alternative x at each moment of time t
j
as
well as the number of agents that keep or change their
opinion during consecutive time moments (see Table 2).
2.2 New approach to measure preference stability:
Definition and properties
Influenced by Bosch’s consensus approach [6], our pro-
posal of cohesivenesses measure along time is intro-
duced below.
Definition 2 A time cohesiveness measure for a group
of agents N = {1, ..., N } on an alternative x is a
mapping
τ : P
N×T
[0, 1]
that assigns a number τ(P) [0, 1] to each time preferen-
ce profile P, with the properties:
i) τ(P) = 1 if and only if P is unanimous (full stabi-
lity).
ii) τ(P
σ
) = τ(P) for each permutation σ of the agents
and P P
N×T
(anonymity).
A time cohesiveness measure is a collection of time
cohesiveness measures for each group of agents N.

4 T. Gonz´alez-Artega et al.
H
H
H
H
t
1
t
2
No Yes
No n
t
1
,t
2
0,0
= 2 n
t
1
,t
2
0,1
= 5 n
t
1
0
= 7
Yes n
t
1
,t
2
1,0
= 1 n
t
1
,t
2
1,1
= 2 n
t
1
1
= 3
n
t
2
0
= 3 n
t
2
1
= 7 N = 10
H
H
H
H
t
2
t
3
No Yes
No n
t
2
,t
3
0,0
= 1 n
t
2
,t
3
0,1
= 2 n
t
2
0
= 3
Yes n
t
2
,t
3
1,0
= 3 n
t
2
,t
3
1,1
= 4 n
t
2
1
= 7
n
t
3
0
= 4 n
t
3
1
= 6 N = 10
H
H
H
H
t
3
t
4
No Yes
No n
t
3
,t
4
0,0
= 2 n
t
3
,t
4
0,1
= 2 n
t
3
0
= 4
Yes n
t
3
,t
4
1,0
= 3 n
t
3
,t
4
1,1
= 3 n
t
3
1
= 6
n
t
4
0
= 5 n
t
4
1
= 5 N = 10
Table 2 Notation summary table for Example 1
Our proposal in contrast to Bosch’s contribution
does not require neutrality property, time moments can
not be exchanged, due to the fact that time order is an
essential aspect to measure the stability of preferences.
Now a particular time cohesiveness measure is in-
troduced. Formally:
Definition 3 The sequential time cohesiveness mea-
sure for a group of agents N = {1, ..., N} on an al-
ternative x is the mapping τ
S
: P
N×T
[0, 1] given
by
τ
S
(P) =
=
1
T 1
·
j=T 1
X
j=1
n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
· ( n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
1)
N(N 1)
+
1
T 1
·
j=T 1
X
j=1
n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
· ( n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
1)
N(N 1)
Intuitively, it measures the probability that for a
randomly chosen moment of time, two randomly cho-
sen agents of a group have the same opinion upon an
alternative at the moment of time selected and its con-
secutive.
It is easy to check that Definition 3 provides a time
cohesiveness measure.
Hereunder, some desirable properties of the sequen-
tial cohesiveness measure are defined and proved.
Properties
Reversal invariance: This property shows that the
main aspect of the time sequential cohesiveness mea-
sure is the stability of agents’ opinions more than an
specific value. If the 0’s are changed for 1’s and vice
verse, then the sequential time cohesiveness measure
reminds equal. Formally:
Let P
c
be the complementary time preference profile
of P defined by P
c
= (1)
N×T
P. If τ
S
verifies
reversal invariance then τ
S
(P
c
) = τ
S
(P).
Proof Agents’ opinions at t
j
, t
j+1
T do not change
in P and P
c
, then τ
S
does not change. That is, those
agents whose opinions coincide at t
j
and t
j+1
in
P have also coincident opinions at t
j
and t
j+1
in
P
c
although those opinions are different than in P.
Taking into account the Definition 3, τ
S
does not
change.
ut
Time-reducibility: It means that the stability of a
time preference profile is the average of the time
cohesiveness measures of all its consecutive time-
subprofiles of two consecutive moments of time. For-
mally:
Let P P
N×T
be a time preference profile. We say
that τ
S
verifies time-reducibility if
τ
S
(P) =
1
T 1
T 1
X
j=1
τ
S
(P
I
j,j+1
)
where P
I
j,j+1
P
N×2
is the time-subprofile of P
containing the columns corresponding to times t
j
and t
j+1
.
Proof It is straightforward from the Definition 3
since
τ
S
(P
I
j,j+1
) =
=
n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
(n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
1)
N(N 1)
+
n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
(n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
1)
N(N 1)
ut

Preference stability along time: The time cohesiveness measure 5
Replication monotonicity: When a non-unanimous
time preference profile is replicated, its sequential
time cohesiveness measure increases. Formally:
Let P P
N×T
be a non unanimous time preference
profile then
τ
S
(P ] P) > τ
S
(P)
Proof Using time-reducibility is enough to prove this
property for only two moments of time. Consider
P
I
j,j+1
P
N×2
a time-subprofile for t
j
and t
j+1
.
τ
S
(P
I
j,j+1
) =
=
n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
(n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
1)
N(N 1)
+
n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
(n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
1)
N(N 1)
τ
S
(P
I
j,j+1
] P
I
j,j+1
) =
=
2n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
(2n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
1)
2N(2N 1)
+
2n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
(2n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
1)
2N(2N 1)
It is enough that
2z 1
2N 1
>
z 1
N 1
for each natu-
ral number z N with z < N . And this is easily
checked. ut
In addition, for an unanimous time preference pro-
file P P
N×T
, by Definition 3, τ
S
verifies
τ
S
(P ] P) = τ
S
(P) = 1
Minimum time stability: If all agents express their
opinions at a moment of time and change their opin-
ions at the next moment of time, that is, all agents
change their opinions along two successive moments
of time, then the sequential time cohesiveness mea-
sure takes a zero value. It also happens when there
are at most two agents that keep their opinion at
two consecutive moments of time but their opinions
do not coincide each other. Formally:
Let P P
N×T
be a time preference profile such that
there is at most one agent who has the same opinion
at t
j
and t
j+1
for j {1, . . . T }, that is, n
t
j
,t
j+1
0,0
1
and n
t
j
,t
j+1
1,1
1 for all j T. Then, τ
S
(P) = 0.
Proof It is immediately from Definition 3. ut
Leaving minimum time stability: In order to leave
the minimum time stability it is needed that at least
the opinions of two agents coincide at the same mo-
ment of time and the next one. Formally:
Let P P
N×T
be a time preference profile such
that there exists at least a k, k T, such that
n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
> 1 or n
t
k
,t
k+1
1,1
> 1, then τ
S
(P) > 0.
Proof Using Definition 3 is straightforward. ut
Time monotonicity: Consider two time preference
profiles, P and P
0
, that coincide in all their ele-
ments excepting the opinion of an agent m N,
at t
k
and t
k+1
. Concretely, this agent has different
opinion at t
k
and t
k+1
in P: P
mt
j
6= P
mt
j+1
, and
the agent’s opinion is the same at t
k
and t
k+1
in
P
0
: P
0
mt
j
= P
0
mt
j+1
. In this case, the sequential time
cohesiveness measure verifies τ
S
(P
0
) τ
S
(P). For-
mally:
Let P, P
0
P
N×T
be time preference profiles such
that:
a) P
it
j
= P
0
it
j
, i {N \ {m}},
b) P
mt
k
6= P
mt
k+1
, m N, t
k
, t
k+1
T,
c) P
0
mt
k
= P
0
mt
k+1
, m N, t
k
, t
k+1
T.
Then, τ
S
(P
0
) τ
S
(P).
Proof It is enough to prove that τ
S
(P
0
)τ
S
(P) 0.
Let n
t
k
,t
k+1
1,1
and n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
the number of agents that
approve and disapprove alternative x at t
k
and t
k+1
from P and (n
t
k
,t
k+1
1,1
)
0
and (n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
)
0
the number of
agents that approve and disapprove alternative x at
t
k
and t
k+1
from P
0
.
If P
0
mt
k
= P
0
mt
k+1
= 0, then
(n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
)
0
= n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
+ 1
and
τ
S
(P
0
) τ
S
(P) =
=
1
T 1
(n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
+1)((n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
+1)1)
N(N 1)
1
T 1
n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
(n
t
k
,t
k+1
0,0
1)
N(N 1)
0
since for all z N, (z + 1)z z(z 1) 0.
If P
0
mt
k
= P
0
mt
k+1
= 1, then
(n
t
k
,t
k+1
1,1
)
0
= n
t
k
,t
k+1
1,1
+ 1

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
01 Feb 2020
TL;DR: A novel approach for measuring the stability of preferences and also for improving understanding of current and future decisions is proposed, as well as two specific measures: the local and the global decision stability measure.
Abstract: Traditionally, preferences have been considered stable although there are growing evidences that such stability is a mere theoretical assumption. Attending to this fact, it should be interesting to measure how much stability preferences provide in order to improve decision making processes. Surprisingly, no research has been found on measuring preferences stability. To overcome this drawback, this paper proposes a novel approach for measuring the stability of preferences and also for improving understanding of current and future decisions. In order to be faithful to reality, this research considers decisions like complete pre-orders on a set of alternatives. Following this reasoning, this paper provides the general concept of decision stability measure as well as two specific measures: the local and the global decision stability measure. Moreover, the main features of the novel approach are examined, including several mathematical results on the behaviour of the proposed measure. And eventually, this contribution develops two real cases of study, with in-depth analysis of preferences behaviour and their stability over time. Specifically, the first one explores into the characteristics of Spanish citizens' voting behaviour and the second one attempts to analyse European citizens' preferences about passenger car market.

7 citations

Book ChapterDOI
11 Jun 2018
TL;DR: A non-traditional approach on the measurement of agents behaviour is presented, focusing on measuring stability of agents’ preferences on an intertemporal context under the assumption of considering uncertainty opinions.
Abstract: A non-traditional approach on the measurement of agents behaviour is presented. This contribution focus on measuring stability of agents’ preferences on an intertemporal context under the assumption of considering uncertainty opinions. To this aim, the concept of behaviour stability measure is defined as well as a particular one, the sequential behaviour stability measure. Finally and in order to highlight the good behaviour of novel measure, some properties are also provided.

3 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Analyzing the stability of citizens’ preferences on public healthcare services in Spain shows that preferences on the public healthcare system are very stable along time.

1 citations

Book ChapterDOI
23 Oct 2018
TL;DR: This paper considers the classic definition of General Decision Making Problem and introduces two new key elements for building ADS: the nature of the information available and the context in which the problem is being solved.
Abstract: The replacement of people by Automatic Decision-making Systems (ADS) has become a threat today. However, it seems that this replacement is unstoppable. Thus, the need for future and current ADS to perform their tasks as perfectly as possible is, more than a necessity an obligation. Hence, the design of these ADS must be carried out in accordance with the theoretical models on which they are to be built. From this point of view, this paper considers the classic definition of General Decision Making Problem and introduces two new key elements for building ADS: the nature of the information available and the context in which the problem is being solved. The new definition allows to cover different models and decision and optimization problems, some of which are presented for illustrative purposes.

Cites background from "Preference stability along time: th..."

  • ...Introduction In the very recent decades, because of an enormous growth of the population and the necessity to provide food for them from one hand and the other hand an immethodical consumption of fossil fuel, our planet is experiencing an unexampled growth in terms of green-house gases (GHG) emission such as CO2, CH4 and N2O in its atmosphere that cause an ascending amount of global warming year by year and a drastic climate change [6,20]....

    [...]

01 Jan 2018
TL;DR: Gonzalez-Arteaga et al. as discussed by the authors proposed a method for the analysis of the BORDA research group at the University of Salamanca in Spain, which is based on fundamental physics and mathematics.
Abstract: R. de Andrés Calle BORDA Research Unit, PRESAD Research Group and Multidisciplinary Institute of Enterprise University of Salamanca, E37007 Salamanca, Spain rocioac@usal.es J.M. Cascón Department of Economics and Economic History Institute on Fundamental Physics and Mathematics University of Salamanca, E37007 Salamanca, Spain casbar@usal.es T. González-Arteaga BORDA and PRESAD Research Groups Multidisciplinary Institute of Enterprise University of Valladolid, E47011 Valladolid, Spain teresa.gonzalez.arteaga@uva.es

Cites background from "Preference stability along time: th..."

  • ...[8] T. González-Artega, R. de Andrés Calle, and M. Peral, “Preference stability along time: the time cohesiveness measure,” Progress in Artificial Intelligence, vol. 6, no. 3, pp. 235–244, 2017....

    [...]

  • ...Este trabajo está inspirado en la metodologa propuesta por González-Arteaga, de Andrés Calle y Peral [8], [9] donde la noción de estabilidad de las decisiones intertemporales se considera en la misma lı́nea que la noción de cohesión....

    [...]

  • ...Este trabajo está inspirado en la metodologa propuesta por González-Arteaga, de Andrés Calle y Peral [8], [9] donde la noción de estabilidad de las decisiones intertemporales se considera en la misma lı́nea que la noción de cohesión....

    [...]

  • ...En [8] los agentes establecen sus preferencias sobre una única alternativa de manera dicotómica....

    [...]

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
01 May 2002
TL;DR: The main improvement of this consensus model is that it supports consensus process automatically, without moderator, and, in such a way, the possible subjectivity that the moderator can introduce in the consensus process is avoided.
Abstract: In this paper, we present a consensus model for multiperson decision making (MPDM) problems with different preference structures based on two consensus criteria: 1) a consensus measure which indicates the agreement between experts' opinions and 2) a measure of proximity to find out how far the individual opinions are from the group opinion. These measures are calculated by comparing the positions of the alternatives between the individual solutions and collective solution. In such a way, the consensus situation is evaluated in each moment in a more realistic way. With these measures, we design a consensus support system that is able to substitute the actions of the moderator. In this system, the consensus measure is used to guide the consensus process until the final solution is achieved while the proximity measure is used to guide the discussion phases of the consensus process. The consensus support system has a feedback mechanism to guide the discussion phases based on the proximity measure. This feedback mechanism is based on simple and easy rules to help experts change their opinions in order to obtain a degree of consensus as high as possible. The main improvement of this consensus model is that it supports consensus process automatically, without moderator, and, in such a way, the possible subjectivity that the moderator can introduce in the consensus process is avoided.

681 citations

Book
27 Feb 2003

454 citations


"Preference stability along time: th..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Traditionally, preferences have usually been considered permanent by theory [23], although there are also different studies to checkwhether they are constant over time [4,7,11,26]....

    [...]

Posted Content
TL;DR: The authors study whether natural disasters affect risk-taking behavior exploiting geographic variation in exposure to natural disasters and find that individuals who recently suffered a flood or earthquake exhibit more risk aversion than individuals living in otherwise like villages.
Abstract: We study whether natural disasters affect risk-taking behavior exploiting geographic variation in exposure to natural disasters We conduct standard risk games (using real money) with randomly selected individuals in Indonesia and find that individuals who recently suffered a flood or earthquake exhibit more risk aversion than individuals living in otherwise like villages The impact persists for several years, particularly if the disaster was severe Some, but not all, of this effect is due to income losses While we cannot rule out fundamental changes in risk preferences, data on subjective beliefs of the probability of a disaster occurring and the expected severity of such a disaster suggest that changes in perceptions of background risk are driving the more risk-averse behavior we observe We show that access to insurance can partly offset this effect Finally, we relate the observed experimental behavior to the propensity of respondents to take risks in their daily lives and show that an increase in risk-aversion has important implications for economic development

382 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigate whether experiencing a natural disaster affects risk-taking behavior and find that individuals who recently suffered a flood or earthquake exhibit more risk-aversion, and conclude that this change in perception of background risk causes people to take fewer risks.
Abstract: We investigate whether experiencing a natural disaster affects risk-taking behavior. We conduct standard risk games (using real money) with randomly selected individuals in rural Indonesia. We find that individuals who recently suffered a flood or earthquake exhibit more risk-aversion. Experiencing a natural disaster causes people to perceive that they now face a greater risk of a future disaster. We conclude that this change in perception of background risk causes people to take fewer risks. We provide evidence that experimental risk behavior is correlated with real-life risk behavior, highlighting the importance of our results.

355 citations


"Preference stability along time: th..." refers background in this paper

  • ...From another point of view, a growing number of studies considers changes in preferences as a result of shocks such as illness, civil wars and natural disasters [9,15,21,25]....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper investigated the impact of several dimensions of experience (effort, choice, and experience) on preference stability and found that the type of experience and its corresponding effort had a large impact on the process of preference development.

282 citations


"Preference stability along time: th..." refers background in this paper

  • ...One of the main topics of this area is the study of preference stability that is often defined like the measurement of the choice consistency among options along time [8,20,28]....

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (7)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Preference stability along time: the time cohesiveness measure" ?

This work introduces a non-traditional perspective about the problem of measuring the stability of agents ’ preferences. The general concept of time cohesiveness measure is introduced as well as a particular formulation based on the consideration of any two successive moments of time, the sequential time cohesiveness measure. Moreover, some properties of the novel measure are also provided. Finally, and in order to emphasize the adaptability of their proposal to real situations, a factual case of study about Clinical Decision Making is presented. Concretely, the study of preference stability for life-sustaining treatments of patients with advanced cancer at end of life is analysed. The novel measure provides information of patients preference stability along time and considers the possibility of cancer metastases. 

Some straight lines of future research that could be addressed from the new approach are listed bellow: – It could be interesting to analyse preference stabi- lity problem and its measure when the number of experts decreases along time because loss of experts to follow-up e. g., patients deaths before ended study. 

For each time preference profile P, PI is the restriction to a subset of consecutive moments of time, timesubprofile on the moments of time in The author⊆ T, and it emerges from selecting consecutive columns of P that are associated with the respective moments of time in I. 

The sequential time cohesiveness measure for a group of agents N = {1, ..., N} on an alternative x is the mapping τS : PN×T → [0, 1] given byτS(P) == 1T − 1 ·j=T−1∑ j=1 n tj ,tj+1 0,0 · (n tj ,tj+1 0,0 − 1)N(N − 1)+ 

the case of terminally cancer patients’ last year of life is studied using the new sequential time cohesiveness measure. 

Taking into account the previous contributions on preference stability and cohesiveness measure, this paper is focused on an inter-temporal decision making problem where a set of agents express their opinions on an alternative along different moments of time. 

Following the Social Choice tradition, this measurement takes values in the unit interval considering value 1 full stability and value 0 total lack of stability.