scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Pricing and Hedging Path-Dependent Options Under the CEV Process

01 Jul 2001-Management Science (INFORMS)-Vol. 47, Iss: 7, pp 949-965
TL;DR: It is demonstrated that the prices of options, which depend on extrema, can be much more sensitive to the specification of the underlying price process than standard call and put options and show that a financial institution that uses the standard geometric Brownian motion assumption is exposed to significant pricing and hedging errors when dealing in path-dependent options.
Abstract: Much of the work on path-dependent options assumes that the underlying asset price follows geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility. This paper uses a more general assumption for the asset price process that provides a better fit to the empirical observations. We use the so-called constant elasticity of variance CEV diffusion model where the volatility is a function of the underlying asset price. We derive analytical formulae for the prices of important types of path-dependent options under this assumption. We demonstrate that the prices of options, which depend on extrema, such as barrier and lookback options, can be much more sensitive to the specification of the underlying price process than standard call and put options and show that a financial institution that uses the standard geometric Brownian motion assumption is exposed to significant pricing and hedging errors when dealing in path-dependent options.

Summary (2 min read)

1. Introduction

  • Lookback options and barrier options are two of the most popular types of path-dependent options.
  • The authors paper uses this model to examine the pricing and hedging of lookback and barrier options.
  • Similarly, closed-form formulae for lookback options are given in terms of stationary solutions.

2. The Contracts: Barrier and Lookback Options

  • Barrier options are probably the oldest path-dependent options.
  • The rebate is received when the knock-out barrier is first reached.
  • Unlike down-and-out calls which are canceled outof-the-money (the lower barrier is placed below the strike price), up-and-out calls are canceled in-themoney (the upper barrier is placed above the strike).
  • By buying a barrier option, one can eliminate paying for those scenarios one feels are unlikely.
  • Their payoff depends on the maximum or minimum underlying asset price attained during the option’s life.

3. General Valuation Results

  • The authors first develop some results for a general one-dimensional diffusion and later specialize to the CEV assumption.
  • They are linearly independent and all solutions can be expressed as their linear combinations.
  • Then the double knock-out option price in Equation (17) is obtained by inverting the Laplace transform (21) and discounting at the risk-free rate.

4. The CEV Process

  • For 1= 0 (the lognormal model), both zero and infinity are natural boundaries.
  • The CEV density (31) can be expressed in terms of the noncentral chi-square density.
  • To value barrier and lookback options under the CEV process, the authors need to know the functional form of the fundamental solutions ' and ' similar to Equation (15) for geometric Brownian motion.
  • Finally, to compute the price in Equation (17), the Laplace transform is inverted .

5. Model Risk

  • To facilitate the comparison of their analytical results with numerical results already in the literature, the authors adopt the same choice of parameters as Boyle and Tian (1999).
  • The authors focus their discussion on the case of negative 1 because of its empirical importance for the stock index option market.
  • The salient feature of the results is that the value of 1 has a much greater impact on the prices of upand-out and double knock-out calls than on standard, capped and down-and-out calls.
  • Thus, a misspecified value of 1 may cause very large pricing and hedging errors for up-and-out and double knock-out calls.

6. Conclusion

  • This paper studies the pricing and hedging of barrier and lookback options under the CEV process.
  • The contributions of this study are two-fold.
  • First, the authors derive pricing formulae for barrier and lookback options under the CEV process in closed form.
  • The value of delta is given in parentheses underneath the corresponding option price.
  • In particular, up-and-out, double knock-out, and lookback call prices and deltas are extremely sensitive to the specification of the elasticity parameter 1.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Pricing and Hedging Path-Dependent
Options Under the CEV Process
Dmitry Davydov Vadim Linetsky
Equities Quantitative Strategies, UBS Warburg, 677 Washington Boulevard,
Stamford, Connecticut 06901
Department of Industrial Engineering and Management Sciences,
McCormick School of Engineering and Applied Sciences, Northwestern University,
2145 Sheridan Road, Evanston, Illinois 60208
dmitry.davydov@ubsw.com linetsky@iems.nwu.edu
M
uch of the work on path-dependent options assumes that the underlying asset price
follows geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility. This paper uses a more
general assumption for the asset price process that provides a better fit to the empirical
observations. We use the so-called constant elasticity of variance (CEV) diffusion model where
the volatility is a function of the underlying asset price. We derive analytical formulae for
the prices of important types of path-dependent options under this assumption. We demon-
strate that the prices of options, which depend on extrema, such as barrier and lookback
options, can be much more sensitive to the specification of the underlying price process than
standard call and put options and show that a financial institution that uses the standard
geometric Brownian motion assumption is exposed to significant pricing and hedging errors
when dealing in path-dependent options.
(Path-Dependent Options; Barrier Options; Lookback Options; Diffusion Processes; CEV Model;
Generalized Bessel Process; Radial Ornstein-Uhlenbeck Process)
1. Introduction
A standard option gives its owner the right to buy
(or sell) some asset in the future for a fixed price. The
fixed price is known as the strike price. Call options
confer the right to buy the asset, while put options
confer the right to sell the asset. Path-dependent
options represent extensions of this concept. For
example, a lookback call option confers the right to buy
an asset at its minimum price over some time period.
A barrier option resembles a standard option except
that the payoff also depends on whether or not the
asset price crosses a certain barrier level during the
option’s life. Lookback options and barrier options
are two of the most popular types of path-dependent
options.
Most of the academic literature on path-dependent
options follow the lead set by Black and Scholes (1973)
and assume that the underlying asset price follows
geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility.
This implies that the future asset prices are log-
normaly distributed and leads to tractable analytical
formulae.
1
However, the evidence indicates that this
distributional assumption is not rich enough to cap-
ture the empirical observations. If the true asset price
process was geometric Brownian motion with con-
stant volatility, then the Black-Scholes formula could
be used to find out this volatility by equating the
model price of a standard option to its market price.
The volatility thus obtained is known as the implied
1
Merton (1973) derives a closed-form pricing formula for down-
and-out call options. Rubinstein and Reiner (1991) extend Merton’s
result to other types of barrier options. Goldman et al. (1979),
Goldman et al. (1979), and Conze and Vishwanathan (1991)
provide closed-form pricing formulae for lookback options.
0025-1909/01/4707/0949$5.00
1526-5501 electronic ISSN
Management Science © 2001 INFORMS
Vol. 47, No. 7, July 2001 pp. 949–965

DAVYDOV AND LINETSKY
Path-Dependent Options Under the CEV Process
volatility of the option. Empirically, we find that the
implied volatilities computed from market prices of
options with different strike prices are not constant
but vary with strike price. This variation is observed
across a wide range of markets and underlying assets
and is known as the implied volatility smile or frown
depending on its shape. The lognormal assumption
with constant volatility does not capture this effect.
There are different ways of extending the basic
model to incorporate this feature. The present paper
uses the constant elasticity of variance (CEV) diffusion
to model asset prices. This process, first introduced
to finance by Cox (1975), is capable of reproducing
the volatility smile observed in the empirical data.
Our paper uses this model to examine the pricing and
hedging of lookback and barrier options.
The contributions of the present paper are two-fold.
First, we derive solutions for barrier and lookback
option prices under the CEV process in closed
form. More generally, we first derive closed-form
expressions for barrier and lookback option prices
under a general time-homogeneous, one-dimensional
diffusion in terms of the two independent solutions
of the stationary Black-Scholes differential equation
with state-dependent volatility. Specializing to the
CEV process, we then derive closed-form expressions
for the stationary solutions and compute barrier and
lookback option prices under the CEV process.
Second, we use the closed-form pricing formulae to
carry out a comparative statics analysis. We demon-
strate that barrier and lookback option prices and
hedge ratios under the CEV process can deviate
dramatically from the lognormal values. Therefore,
substantial model risk exposure exists for finan-
cial institutions making markets in path-dependent
options. Strikingly, we find that deltas of up-and-
out calls, down-and-out puts, double knock-out, and
lookback options can have different signs under the
CEV and lognormal specifications. In these cases,
delta hedging with a misspecified model can produce
worse results than no hedging at all. Finally, to further
assess model risk inherent in writing these contracts,
we carry out a dynamic hedging simulation experi-
ment that quantifies the impact of model misspecifi-
cation on the outcome of dynamic hedging strategies.
Our results indicate that it is much more important
to have an accurate model specification for pricing
and hedging barrier and lookback options than for
standard options.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2
introduces barrier and lookback options. Section 3
focuses on general valuation results. We derive a
closed-form expression for the Laplace transform of
a barrier option price in time to expiration under
a time-homogeneous, one-dimensional diffusion. The
formula involves two independent solutions of the
stationary Black-Scholes differential equation with
state-dependent volatility. Similarly, closed-form for-
mulae for lookback options are given in terms of
stationary solutions. In §4, we specialize to the CEV
diffusion and derive closed-form expressions for the
stationary solutions in terms of Whittaker and Bessel
functions. In §5, we compute barrier and lookback
option prices and sensitivities, conduct a compara-
tive statics analysis, and carry out a dynamic hedg-
ing experiment to quantify model risk due to model
misspecification faced by financial institutions mak-
ing markets in path-dependent options. Section 6 con-
cludes the paper. Proofs are collected in Appendix A.
Appendix B discusses the case of positive elasticity.
Appendix C contains explicit expressions for the inte-
grals entering the barrier option pricing formulae.
Appendix D discusses Laplace transform inversion.
2. The Contracts: Barrier and
Lookback Options
Barrier options are probably the oldest path-dependent
options. Snyder (1969) describes down-and-out stock
options as “limited risk special options.” Merton
(1973) derives a closed-form pricing formula for
down-and-out calls under the lognormal assumption.
A down-and-out call is identical to a European
2
call
with the additional provision that the contract is can-
celed (knocked out) if the underlying asset price hits
a prespecified lower barrier level. The contract may
also specify a cash rebate to be received by the option
holder if cancellation occurs. The rebate is received
when the knock-out barrier is first reached.
2
European options can only be exercised on the expiration date,
while American options can be exercised on any business day
through and including expiration.
950 Management Science/Vol. 47, No. 7, July 2001

DAVYDOV AND LINETSKY
Path-Dependent Options Under the CEV Process
An up-and-out call is the same, except the contract is
canceled when the underlying asset price first reaches
a prespecified upper barrier level. A cash rebate may
also be received when the barrier is first reached.
Unlike down-and-out calls which are canceled out-
of-the-money (the lower barrier is placed below the
strike price), up-and-out calls are canceled in-the-
money (the upper barrier is placed above the strike).
Generally, contracts that are canceled in-the-money
are called reverse knock-out options.
Down-and-out and up-and-out puts are similar
modifications of European put options. Knock-in
options are complementary to the knock-out options:
They pay off at expiration if and only if the under-
lying asset price does reach the prespecified barrier.
The combination of otherwise identical in and out
options is equivalent to the corresponding stan-
dard European option. Rubinstein and Reiner (1991)
derive closed-form pricing formulae for all eight
types of single-barrier options under the lognormal
assumption.
Double-barrier (double knock-out) options are canceled
when the underlying asset first reaches either the
upper or the lower barrier. A rebate may also be
received at that time. Different representations of
the closed-form pricing formula for double barrier
options under the lognormal assumption are obtained
by Kunitomo and Ikeda (1992), Geman and Yor (1995),
Pelsser (2000), and Schroder (2000).
A capped call is an up-and-out call with the cash
rebate equal to the difference between the upper bar-
rier (cap) and the strike price. It combines a European
exercise feature and an automatic exercise feature. The
automatic exercise is triggered when the index value
first exceeds the cap (Broadie and Detemple 1995).
Barrier options are one of the most popular types
of path-dependent options traded over-the-counter on
stocks, stock indexes, currencies, commodities, and
interest rates. Derman and Kani (1996) offer a detailed
discussion of their investment, hedging, and trading
applications. There are several reasons to use bar-
rier options rather than standard options. First, bar-
rier options may more closely match investor beliefs
about the future behavior of the asset. By buying a
barrier option, one can eliminate paying for those
scenarios one feels are unlikely. Second, barrier option
premiums are generally lower than those of standard
options because an additional condition has to be met
for the option holder to receive the payoff (e.g., the
lower barrier not reached for down-and-out options).
The premium reduction can be substantial, especially
when volatility is high.
Lookback options are another important example of
path-dependent options. Their payoff depends on
the maximum or minimum underlying asset price
attained during the option’s life. A standard lookback
call gives the option holder the right to buy at the low-
est price recorded during the option’s life. A standard
lookback put gives the right to sell at the highest price
recorded during the option’s life. Lookbacks were
first studied by Goldman, Sosin, and Gatto (1979)
and Goldman, Sosin, and Shepp (1979) who derived
closed-form pricing formulae under the lognormal
assumption. In addition to standard lookback options,
Conze and Vishwanathan (1991) introduce calls on
maximum and puts on minimum. A call on maximum
pays off the difference between the realized maximum
price and some prespecified strike or zero, whichever
is greater. A put on minimum pays off the difference
between the strike and the realized minimum price
or zero, whichever is greater. These options are called
fixed-strike lookbacks. In contrast, the standard lookback
options are also called floating-strike lookbacks, because
the floating terminal underlying price S
T
serves as the
strike price in standard lookback options.
3. General Valuation Results
We first develop some results for a general
one-dimensional diffusion and later specialize to the
CEV assumption. We take an equivalent martingale
measure (risk-neutral probability measure) Q as given
(Duffie 1996). Under Q, we suppose that the asset
price S
t
t 0 is a time-homogeneous, nonnegative
diffusion process solving the stochastic differential
equation
dS
t
= S
t
dt +S
t
S
t
dB
t
t 0S
0
= S>0 (1)
where B
t
t 0 is a standard Brownian
motion defined on a filtered probability space
 
t
t0
Q, is a constant ( = r q, where
r 0 and q 0 are the constant risk-free interest
Management Science/Vol. 47, No. 7, July 2001 951

DAVYDOV AND LINETSKY
Path-Dependent Options Under the CEV Process
rate and the constant dividend yield, respectively),
and = S is a given local volatility function, which
is assumed continuous and strictly positive for all
S 0 . We also assume that the local volatility
function remains bounded as S →. This is sufficient
to insure that infinity is a natural boundary
3
for the
diffusion (1). The boundary behavior at the origin
depends on the growth behavior of S as S 0. If
S remains bounded as S 0, then zero is a natural
boundary. If S grows as S
p
with some 0 <p1/2
as S 0, then it is an exit boundary (bankruptcy). If
S grows as S
p
with some p>1/2asS 0, then
zero is a regular boundary point, and we specify it as
a killing boundary by adjoining a killing boundary
condition (bankruptcy).
Throughout this paper t denotes the running time
variable. We assume that all options are written at
time t = 0 and expire at time t = T>0. Time remain-
ing to expiration is denoted by = T t. Suppose
the initial asset price is S and the lower and upper
barrier levels are L and U , L<S<U. Define the
first hitting time of the lower barrier
L
= inft
0; S
t
= L, the first hitting time of the upper bar-
rier
U
= inft 0S
t
= U, and the first exit time
from an interval between the two barriers
LU
=
inft 0S
t
L U  (by convention, the infimum of
the empty set is infinity). Then a down-and-out call
with strike price K and no rebate has the payoff at
expiration 1
L
>T
S
T
K
+
, where 1
A
is the indica-
tor function of the event A, and x
+
maxx 0 is the
positive part of x. The up-and-out call has the payoff
1
U
>T
S
T
K
+
. The double-barrier call has the pay-
off 1
LU
>T
S
T
K
+
. Rebates are fixed cash amounts
paid at times =
L
,
U
,or
LU
, given T .
Before attacking the problem of pricing finitely
lived barrier options with rebates and expiration
T<, it is convenient to examine first three more
primitive securities: perpetual claims that pay one
dollar at times
L
,
U
, and
LU
, respectively, and
have no set expiration date (see Ingersoll 1987, p. 371).
The claim that pays one dollar at
LU
can be
decomposed into a combination of two additional
3
The boundary classification of one-dimensional diffusions due to
Feller is described in Karlin and Taylor (1981, Chapter 15) and
Borodin and Salminen (1996, Chapter 2).
claims, the first claim paying one dollar at
L
, given
the lower barrier is reached first (
L
<
U
), and the
second claim paying one dollar at
U
, given the upper
barrier is reached first (
U
<
L
).
Proposition 1. Suppose the risk-neutral asset price
process is a diffusion (1) and the constant risk-free interest
rate is r>0. Then the prices at time t =0 of the five perpet-
ual claims described above are (the expectation E
S
is with
respect to the risk-neutral measure Q and the subscript S
indicates that the process (1) is starting at S
0
= S):
One dollar paid at
L
:
E
S
e
r
L
1
L
<
=
r
S
r
L
S L (2)
One dollar paid at
L
, given
L
<
U
:
E
S
e
r
L
1
L
<
U
=
r
S U
r
LU
L S U (3)
One dollar paid at
U
:
E
S
e
r
U
1
U
<
0
=
r
S
r
U
S U (4)
One dollar paid at
U
, given
U
<
L
:
E
S
e
r
U
1
U
<
L
=
r
LS
r
LU
L S U (5)
One dollar paid at
LU
:
E
S
e
r
LU
=
r
LS+
r
SU
r
LU
LS U (6)
where ( for any 0 <A<B<)
r
AB =
r
A
r
B
r
A
r
B (7)
The functions
r
S and
r
S can be characterized as the
unique (up to a multiplicative constant) solutions of the
ordinary differential equation (ODE)
4
1
2
2
SS
2
d
2
u
dS
2
+S
du
dS
ru = 0S 0  (8)
first by demanding that
r
S is increasing in S and
r
S
is decreasing in S, and secondly, if the origin is a regular
boundary point, posing a killing boundary condition:
r
0+ = 0 (9)
4
In our characterization of the functions
r
and
r
, we follow
Borodin and Salminen (1996, pp. 18–19). The subscript r indicates
the dependence on the risk-free rate that enters the ODE (8).
952 Management Science/Vol. 47, No. 7, July 2001

DAVYDOV AND LINETSKY
Path-Dependent Options Under the CEV Process
The functions
r
S and
r
S have the following
properties (Borodin and Salminen 1996, pp. 18–19). If
zero is an exit boundary, then
r
0+ = 0
r
0+<+ (10)
If zero is a natural boundary, then
r
0+ = 0
r
0+ =+ (11)
Because we assume that S is bounded as S →,
+ is a natural boundary and
lim
S→
r
S =+ lim
S→
r
S = 0 (12)
The functions
r
S and
r
S are called fundamen-
tal solutions of the ODE (8). They are linearly inde-
pendent and all solutions can be expressed as their
linear combinations. Moreover, the Wronskian w
r
,
defined by
r
S
d
r
dS
S
r
S
d
r
dS
S = Sw
r
(13)
is independent of S. Here S is the scale density of
the diffusion (1)
S = exp
S
2dx
2
xx
(14)
Proposition 1 expresses the prices of the five claims
in terms of the two fundamental solutions of the
stationary Black-Scholes differential equation with
the local volatility function S (note that the time
derivative term is absent from Equation (8)). For
geometric Brownian motion S
t
= Se

2
/2t+B
t
with
constant volatility , the functional form of the
fundamental solutions is (see Ingersoll 1987, p. 372,
and Carr and Picron 1999):
r
S = S
+

r
S = S
±
=− ±
2
+
2r
2
(15)
=
2
1
2
In §4 we present closed-form expressions for and
for the CEV process.
To value cash rebates included in finitely lived
knock-out option contracts with expiration T<,we
need to value claims that pay one dollar at times =
L
,
U
,or
L U
, given T . That is, we need to eval-
uate expectations of the form E
S
1
T
e
r
.
Proposition 2. For any >0, the Laplace transform
of the rebate price in time to expiration
5
is equal to 1/
times the price of the corresponding perpetual claim with
the adjusted discount rate r +:
0
e
T
E
S
1
T
e
r
dT =
1
E
S
e
r+
 (16)
Given the associated perpetual claim value (Proposition 1),
the rebate price is found by inverting this Laplace
transform.
Now we are ready to price terminal payoffs of
finitely lived knock-out options. First, consider the
more difficult case of double-barrier options. We need
to evaluate the discounted expectation (in this paper
we focus on calls; puts can be treated similarly)
e
rT
E
S
1
LU
>T
S
T
K
+
(17)
Proposition 3. Let S be the scale density (14) and
S—the speed density
6
of the diffusion (1)
S =
2
2
SS
2
S
(18)
For 0 <KA<B< and >0, define
I
KAB =
B
A
Y K
Y Y dY (19)
J
KAB =
B
A
Y K
Y Y dY (20)
where
and
are the functions defined in Proposition 1
(with the risk-free rate r replaced with ). Then the Laplace
5
It is sometimes easier to solve for the Laplace transform of an
option price in time to expiration than for the option price itself.
This Laplace transform (premultiplied by ) can be interpreted as
the price of an exponentially stopped option, i.e., an option expiring
at a random independent exponential time (the first jump time of
a Poisson process with intensity and independent of the under-
lying asset price process). Geman and Yor (1993) use this idea
to obtain closed-from solutions for arithmetic Asian options. Carr
(1998) applies this idea to develop analytical approximations to
value American options.
6
See Karlin and Taylor (1981, p. 194) Karatzas and Shreve (1991,
p. 343) and Borodin and Salminen (1996, p. 17) for discussions of
scale and speed densities. Our definition of the speed density coin-
cides with that of Karatzas and Shreve (1991) and Borodin and
Salminen (1996) and differs from Karlin and Taylor (1981) who do
not include two in the definition.
Management Science/Vol. 47, No. 7, July 2001 953

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
Steven Kou1
TL;DR: In this article, a double exponential jump-diffusion model is proposed for option pricing, which is simple enough to produce analytical solutions for a variety of option-pricing problems, including call and put options, interest rate derivatives, and path dependent options.
Abstract: Brownian motion and normal distribution have been widely used in the Black--Scholes option-pricing framework to model the return of assets. However, two puzzles emerge from many empirical investigations: the leptokurtic feature that the return distribution of assets may have a higher peak and two (asymmetric) heavier tails than those of the normal distribution, and an empirical phenomenon called "volatility smile" in option markets. To incorporate both of them and to strike a balance between reality and tractability, this paper proposes, for the purpose of option pricing, a double exponential jump-diffusion model. In particular, the model is simple enough to produce analytical solutions for a variety of option-pricing problems, including call and put options, interest rate derivatives, and path-dependent options. Equilibrium analysis and a psychological interpretation of the model are also presented.

1,326 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors propose a jump diffusion model for asset prices whose jump sizes have a mixed-exponential distribution, which is a weighted average of exponential distributions but with possibly negative weights.
Abstract: This paper aims to extend the analytical tractability of the Black--Scholes model to alternative models with arbitrary jump size distributions. More precisely, we propose a jump diffusion model for asset prices whose jump sizes have a mixed-exponential distribution, which is a weighted average of exponential distributions but with possibly negative weights. The new model extends existing models, such as hyperexponential and double-exponential jump diffusion models, because the mixed-exponential distribution can approximate any distribution as closely as possible, including the normal distribution and various heavy-tailed distributions. The mixed-exponential jump diffusion model can lead to analytical solutions for Laplace transforms of prices and sensitivity parameters for path-dependent options such as lookback and barrier options. The Laplace transforms can be inverted via the Euler inversion algorithm. Numerical experiments indicate that the formulae are easy to implement and accurate. The analytical solutions are made possible mainly because we solve a high-order integro-differential equation explicitly. A calibration example for SPY options shows that the model can provide a reasonable fit even for options with very short maturity, such as one day. This paper was accepted by Michael Fu, stochastic models and simulation.

486 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A flexible and analytically tractable framework which unifies the valuation of corporate liabilities, credit derivatives, and equity derivatives is developed, and it is shown that deterministic changes of time and scale reduce the stock price process to a standard Bessel process with killing.
Abstract: We develop a flexible and analytically tractable framework which unifies the valuation of corporate liabilities, credit derivatives, and equity derivatives. We assume that the stock price follows a diffusion, punctuated by a possible jump to zero (default). To capture the positive link between default and equity volatility, we assume that the hazard rate of default is an increasing affine function of the instantaneous variance of returns on the underlying stock. To capture the negative link between volatility and stock price, we assume a constant elasticity of variance (CEV) specification for the instantaneous stock volatility prior to default. We show that deterministic changes of time and scale reduce our stock price process to a standard Bessel process with killing. This reduction permits the development of completely explicit closed form solutions for risk-neutral survival probabilities, CDS spreads, corporate bond values, and European-style equity options. Furthermore, our valuation model is sufficiently flexible so that it can be calibrated to exactly match arbitrarily given term structures of CDS spreads, interest rates, dividend yields, and at-the-money implied volatilities.

264 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
Steven Kou1
TL;DR: In this article, a double exponential jump diffusion model is proposed for option pricing, which is based on the Brownian motion and normal distribution to model the return of assets, and it is shown that the return distribution of assets may have a higher peak and two (asymmetric) heavier tails than those of the normal distribution.
Abstract: _Content: Brownian motion and normal distribution have been widely used in the Black-Scholes option pricing framework to model the return of assets. However, two puzzles emerge from many empirical investigations: the leptokurtic feature that the return distribution of assets may have a higher peak and two (asymmetric) heavier tails than those of the normal distribution, and an empirical abnormity called "volatility smile'' in option pricing. To incorporate both of them, this paper proposes, for the purpose of option pricing, a double exponential jump diffusion model. The main attraction of the model is its simplicity. In particular, it is simple enough to derive analytical solutions for a variety of option pricing problems, including call and put options, interest rate derivatives and path-dependent options; it seems impossible for many other alternative models to do this. Equilibrium analysis and a psychological interpretation of the model are also presented.

206 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
01 Jul 1960-Nature
TL;DR: In this paper, the Confluent Hypergeometric Functions (CGF) are used to express the hypergeometric functions of a given hypergeometrical function in the form of a convex polygon.
Abstract: Confluent Hypergeometric Functions By Dr L J Slater Pp ix + 247 (Cambridge: At the University Press, 1960) 65s net

194 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, a theoretical valuation formula for options is derived, based on the assumption that options are correctly priced in the market and it should not be possible to make sure profits by creating portfolios of long and short positions in options and their underlying stocks.
Abstract: If options are correctly priced in the market, it should not be possible to make sure profits by creating portfolios of long and short positions in options and their underlying stocks. Using this principle, a theoretical valuation formula for options is derived. Since almost all corporate liabilities can be viewed as combinations of options, the formula and the analysis that led to it are also applicable to corporate liabilities such as common stock, corporate bonds, and warrants. In particular, the formula can be used to derive the discount that should be applied to a corporate bond because of the possibility of default.

28,434 citations


"Pricing and Hedging Path-Dependent ..." refers background or methods in this paper

  • ...Most of the academic literature on path-dependent options follow the lead set by Black and Scholes (1973) and assume that the underlying asset price follows geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility....

    [...]

  • ...We use the so-called constant elasticity of variance (CEV) diffusion model where the volatility is a function of the underlying asset price....

    [...]

  • ...…to the constant elasticity of variance (CEV) process of Cox (1975)7 dSt = Stdt+0S1+1t dBt t ≥ 0 S0 = S > 0# (28) The CEV specification (28) nests the lognormal model of Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) (1= 0) and the absolute (1=−1) and square-root (1=−1/2) models of Cox and Ross (1976)....

    [...]

Book
12 Sep 2011
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors deduced a set of restrictions on option pricing formulas from the assumption that investors prefer more to less, which are necessary conditions for a formula to be consistent with a rational pricing theory.
Abstract: The long history of the theory of option pricing began in 1900 when the French mathematician Louis Bachelier deduced an option pricing formula based on the assumption that stock prices follow a Brownian motion with zero drift. Since that time, numerous researchers have contributed to the theory. The present paper begins by deducing a set of restrictions on option pricing formulas from the assumption that investors prefer more to less. These restrictions are necessary conditions for a formula to be consistent with a rational pricing theory. Attention is given to the problems created when dividends are paid on the underlying common stock and when the terms of the option contract can be changed explicitly by a change in exercise price or implicitly by a shift in the investment or capital structure policy of the firm. Since the deduced restrictions are not sufficient to uniquely determine an option pricing formula, additional assumptions are introduced to examine and extend the seminal Black-Scholes theory of option pricing. Explicit formulas for pricing both call and put options as well as for warrants and the new "down-and-out" option are derived. The effects of dividends and call provisions on the warrant price are examined. The possibilities for further extension of the theory to the pricing of corporate liabilities are discussed.

9,635 citations

Book
01 Jan 1987
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a characterization of continuous local martingales with respect to Brownian motion in terms of Markov properties, including the strong Markov property, and a generalized version of the Ito rule.
Abstract: 1 Martingales, Stopping Times, and Filtrations.- 1.1. Stochastic Processes and ?-Fields.- 1.2. Stopping Times.- 1.3. Continuous-Time Martingales.- A. Fundamental inequalities.- B. Convergence results.- C. The optional sampling theorem.- 1.4. The Doob-Meyer Decomposition.- 1.5. Continuous, Square-Integrable Martingales.- 1.6. Solutions to Selected Problems.- 1.7. Notes.- 2 Brownian Motion.- 2.1. Introduction.- 2.2. First Construction of Brownian Motion.- A. The consistency theorem.- B. The Kolmogorov-?entsov theorem.- 2.3. Second Construction of Brownian Motion.- 2.4. The SpaceC[0, ?), Weak Convergence, and Wiener Measure.- A. Weak convergence.- B. Tightness.- C. Convergence of finite-dimensional distributions.- D. The invariance principle and the Wiener measure.- 2.5. The Markov Property.- A. Brownian motion in several dimensions.- B. Markov processes and Markov families.- C. Equivalent formulations of the Markov property.- 2.6. The Strong Markov Property and the Reflection Principle.- A. The reflection principle.- B. Strong Markov processes and families.- C. The strong Markov property for Brownian motion.- 2.7. Brownian Filtrations.- A. Right-continuity of the augmented filtration for a strong Markov process.- B. A "universal" filtration.- C. The Blumenthal zero-one law.- 2.8. Computations Based on Passage Times.- A. Brownian motion and its running maximum.- B. Brownian motion on a half-line.- C. Brownian motion on a finite interval.- D. Distributions involving last exit times.- 2.9. The Brownian Sample Paths.- A. Elementary properties.- B. The zero set and the quadratic variation.- C. Local maxima and points of increase.- D. Nowhere differentiability.- E. Law of the iterated logarithm.- F. Modulus of continuity.- 2.10. Solutions to Selected Problems.- 2.11. Notes.- 3 Stochastic Integration.- 3.1. Introduction.- 3.2. Construction of the Stochastic Integral.- A. Simple processes and approximations.- B. Construction and elementary properties of the integral.- C. A characterization of the integral.- D. Integration with respect to continuous, local martingales.- 3.3. The Change-of-Variable Formula.- A. The Ito rule.- B. Martingale characterization of Brownian motion.- C. Bessel processes, questions of recurrence.- D. Martingale moment inequalities.- E. Supplementary exercises.- 3.4. Representations of Continuous Martingales in Terms of Brownian Motion.- A. Continuous local martingales as stochastic integrals with respect to Brownian motion.- B. Continuous local martingales as time-changed Brownian motions.- C. A theorem of F. B. Knight.- D. Brownian martingales as stochastic integrals.- E. Brownian functionals as stochastic integrals.- 3.5. The Girsanov Theorem.- A. The basic result.- B. Proof and ramifications.- C. Brownian motion with drift.- D. The Novikov condition.- 3.6. Local Time and a Generalized Ito Rule for Brownian Motion.- A. Definition of local time and the Tanaka formula.- B. The Trotter existence theorem.- C. Reflected Brownian motion and the Skorohod equation.- D. A generalized Ito rule for convex functions.- E. The Engelbert-Schmidt zero-one law.- 3.7. Local Time for Continuous Semimartingales.- 3.8. Solutions to Selected Problems.- 3.9. Notes.- 4 Brownian Motion and Partial Differential Equations.- 4.1. Introduction.- 4.2. Harmonic Functions and the Dirichlet Problem.- A. The mean-value property.- B. The Dirichlet problem.- C. Conditions for regularity.- D. Integral formulas of Poisson.- E. Supplementary exercises.- 4.3. The One-Dimensional Heat Equation.- A. The Tychonoff uniqueness theorem.- B. Nonnegative solutions of the heat equation.- C. Boundary crossing probabilities for Brownian motion.- D. Mixed initial/boundary value problems.- 4.4. The Formulas of Feynman and Kac.- A. The multidimensional formula.- B. The one-dimensional formula.- 4.5. Solutions to selected problems.- 4.6. Notes.- 5 Stochastic Differential Equations.- 5.1. Introduction.- 5.2. Strong Solutions.- A. Definitions.- B. The Ito theory.- C. Comparison results and other refinements.- D. Approximations of stochastic differential equations.- E. Supplementary exercises.- 5.3. Weak Solutions.- A. Two notions of uniqueness.- B. Weak solutions by means of the Girsanov theorem.- C. A digression on regular conditional probabilities.- D. Results of Yamada and Watanabe on weak and strong solutions.- 5.4. The Martingale Problem of Stroock and Varadhan.- A. Some fundamental martingales.- B. Weak solutions and martingale problems.- C. Well-posedness and the strong Markov property.- D. Questions of existence.- E. Questions of uniqueness.- F. Supplementary exercises.- 5.5. A Study of the One-Dimensional Case.- A. The method of time change.- B. The method of removal of drift.- C. Feller's test for explosions.- D. Supplementary exercises.- 5.6. Linear Equations.- A. Gauss-Markov processes.- B. Brownian bridge.- C. The general, one-dimensional, linear equation.- D. Supplementary exercises.- 5.7. Connections with Partial Differential Equations.- A. The Dirichlet problem.- B. The Cauchy problem and a Feynman-Kac representation.- C. Supplementary exercises.- 5.8. Applications to Economics.- A. Portfolio and consumption processes.- B. Option pricing.- C. Optimal consumption and investment (general theory).- D. Optimal consumption and investment (constant coefficients).- 5.9. Solutions to Selected Problems.- 5.10. Notes.- 6 P. Levy's Theory of Brownian Local Time.- 6.1. Introduction.- 6.2. Alternate Representations of Brownian Local Time.- A. The process of passage times.- B. Poisson random measures.- C. Subordinators.- D. The process of passage times revisited.- E. The excursion and downcrossing representations of local time.- 6.3. Two Independent Reflected Brownian Motions.- A. The positive and negative parts of a Brownian motion.- B. The first formula of D. Williams.- C. The joint density of (W(t), L(t), ? +(t)).- 6.4. Elastic Brownian Motion.- A. The Feynman-Kac formulas for elastic Brownian motion.- B. The Ray-Knight description of local time.- C. The second formula of D. Williams.- 6.5. An Application: Transition Probabilities of Brownian Motion with Two-Valued Drift.- 6.6. Solutions to Selected Problems.- 6.7. Notes.

8,639 citations

Book
01 Jan 1990
TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a comprehensive survey of the literature on limit theorems in distribution in function spaces, including Girsanov's Theorem, Bessel Processes, and Ray-Knight Theorem.
Abstract: 0. Preliminaries.- I. Introduction.- II. Martingales.- III. Markov Processes.- IV. Stochastic Integration.- V. Representation of Martingales.- VI. Local Times.- VII. Generators and Time Reversal.- VIII. Girsanov's Theorem and First Applications.- IX. Stochastic Differential Equations.- X. Additive Functionals of Brownian Motion.- XI. Bessel Processes and Ray-Knight Theorems.- XII. Excursions.- XIII. Limit Theorems in Distribution.- 1. Gronwall's Lemma.- 2. Distributions.- 3. Convex Functions.- 4. Hausdorff Measures and Dimension.- 5. Ergodic Theory.- 6. Probabilities on Function Spaces.- 7. Bessel Functions.- 8. Sturm-Liouville Equation.- Index of Notation.- Index of Terms.- Catalogue.

7,338 citations


"Pricing and Hedging Path-Dependent ..." refers background or methods in this paper

  • ...The authors are especially grateful to Phelim Boyle for his support with this project....

    [...]

  • ...The change of variable zt = 1/0 1 S−1t reduces the CEV process without drift ( = 0) to a standard Bessel process of order 1/ 21 (see Borodin and Salminen 1996, p. 66, and Revuz and Yor 1999, p. 439, for details on Bessel processes)....

    [...]

  • ...…on S0 = S, is obtained from the well known expression for transition density of the Bessel process (see Borodin and Salminen 1996, p. 115, and Revuz and Yor 1999, p. 446) and is given by (3 = 1/ 2 1 ) p0 T S ST = S −21− 32 T S 1 2 02 1 T exp ( −S −21+S−21T 20212T ) × I3 ( S−1S−1T 0212T )…...

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (11)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "Pricing and hedging path-dependent options under the cev process" ?

Much of the work on path-dependent options assumes that the underlying asset price follows geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility. This paper uses a more general assumption for the asset price process that provides a better fit to the empirical observations. The authors demonstrate that the prices of options, which depend on extrema, such as barrier and lookback options, can be much more sensitive to the specification of the underlying price process than standard call and put options and show that a financial institution that uses the standard geometric Brownian motion assumption is exposed to significant pricing and hedging errors when dealing in path-dependent options. 

The CEV model with negative elasticity exhibits convex and monotonically decreasing implied volatility smiles similar to the smiles empirically observed in the stock index options market and, thus, allows us to study the effect of volatility smiles on pricing and hedging of path-dependent options. Parameters used in the calculation: 0 = 100 = 0 25, r = 0 1, q = 0, T = 0 5. Second, the authors apply the analytical formulae to carry out a comparative statics analysis and demonstrate that, in the presence of a CEV-based volatility smile, barrier and lookback option prices and their hedge ratios can deviate dramatically from the lognormal values. Strikingly, the authors show that their deltas can have different signs under lognormal and CEV specifications, as well as CEV specifications with different elasticities. The authors find that it is much more important to have the accurate model specification for hedging barrier options that are canceled in-the-money than for standard options and barrier options that are canceled out-of-the-money. 

13The salient feature of the results is that the value of 1 has a much greater impact on the prices of upand-out and double knock-out calls than on standard, capped and down-and-out calls. 

The Black-Scholes implied volatility of CEV calls exhibits a typical downward sloping volatility smile pattern (also called smirk, skew or frown), with higher implied volatilities corresponding to lower strikes (in-the-money calls) and lower implied volatilities corresponding to higher strikes (out-of-themoney calls). 

The CEV model with negative elasticity exhibits convex and monotonically decreasing implied volatility smiles similar to the smiles empirically observed in the stock index options market and, thus, allows us to study the effect of volatility smiles on pricing and hedging of path-dependent options. 

To value cash rebates included in finitely lived knock-out option contracts with expiration T < , the authors need to value claims that pay one dollar at times = L, U , or L U , given ≤ T . 

For 1< 0, the risk-neutral probability of absorption at zero (bankruptcy), given S0 = S, is (Cox 1975) QS ST = 0 =G 3 4/2 where G 3 x is the complementary Gamma distribution function and 4 is defined in Equation (33) below. 

The negative elasticity values are characteristic of stock index options (Reiner 1994 and Jackwerth and Rubinstein 1998 find that the prices of S&P 500 index options imply values of beta as low as 1 = −4). 

A slight error in estimating knockout probability can result in large pricing and hedging errors as it is multiplied by the large dollar value. 

The mean of their daily estimates over the post-crash 1988–1994 period is close to −4, with the mean at-the-money implied volatility of 17%. 

The continuous part of the risk-neutral density of ST , conditional on S0 = S, is obtained from the well known expression for transition density of the Bessel process (see Borodin and Salminen 1996, p. 115, and Revuz and Yor 1999, p. 446) and is given by (3 = 1/ 2 1 )p0 T S ST = S −21− 32 T S 1 2 02 1 T exp ( −S −21+S−21T 20212T )×