scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
BookDOI

Rethinking Asian Drama

01 Dec 2018-
About: The article was published on 2018-12-01 and is currently open access. It has received 6 citations till now. The article focuses on the topics: Drama.

Summary (3 min read)

3 Rationale and objective

  • The reality of development that has unfolded in Asia since then has belied such pessimism about its prospects.
  • Streeten continues this story to write, perhaps tongue in cheek, that for Myrdal ‘In fact, the Americans came almost as high in the rank order of creation as the Swedes.
  • The share of Asia in world exports of manufactured goods almost doubled in just two decades, from 21 per cent in 1995 to 39 per cent in 2016.
  • This book uses bold strokes on a wide canvas to sketch a picture of the economic transformation of Asia during the past 50 15 For a detailed discussion on this sequence of developments, and on the factors underlying the decline and fall of Asia in the world economy, see Nayyar (2013).

4 Themes, stylized facts, and lessons

  • This paper does not even attempt a summary or a synthesis of the UNU-WIDER study (Nayyar 2019a).
  • Given the space constraint, it would be an exceedingly difficult task.
  • It would also serve little purpose as it might detract from the richness and depth of the analysis.
  • In any case, the companion volume (Nayyar 2019b) seeks to provide a cohesive analytical narrative.
  • This is, at best, selective and illustrative.

4.1 Diversity in development

  • The diversity of Asia is a recurring theme.
  • The reliance on markets and the degree of openness in economies varied greatly across space and over time.
  • Outcomes in development were also diverse, ranging from success at one end, interspersed with mixed performances or muddling through, to failure at the other, which differed not only between countries at any point in time but also within countries over time.
  • There were different paths to development, simply because there were no unique solutions or magic wands, as one size does not fit all.
  • 20 Obviously, generalizations are difficult if not perilous.

4.2 History, context, and conjuncture

  • It is clear that development trajectories of countries in Asia were shaped, in part, by their histories, while the context and the conjuncture at the outset made a difference.
  • The legacy of Japanese colonialism in South 19 Lee (1981) was among the first to emphasize the limitations of export-led industrialization.
  • Soon after, the geopolitics of the Cold War era in Asia brought about a dramatic change in the state of affairs, transforming this into an unequal relationship of dependence on the United States for military and economic support.
  • Of course, the USSR also provided military and economic support, but communist governments in China and Viet Nam were acutely conscious of their geopolitical vulnerabilities which, together with political ideology, motivated them to address problems in their legacy of initial conditions.

4.3 Economic growth and structural change

  • The transformation of Asia was driven by rapid economic growth.
  • Over a period that spanned almost five decades, 1970–2016, the GDP growth rate in Asia was more than double that in industrialized countries and almost twice that in the world economy.
  • This was associated with a dramatic change in the composition of output and employment.
  • 23 21 Manchuria in northern China, or Manchukuo as the Japanese described it, experienced the same colonial legacy.
  • For an analysis of structural change in Asia compared with Latin America and Africa, see McMillan and Rodrik (2011) and Nayyar (2013).

4.4 Wellbeing of people

  • The rapid economic growth led to a sharp reduction in absolute poverty in Asia, but not as much as it could have, partly because the initial income distribution was unequal and partly because of rising income inequality.
  • And inequality rose almost everywhere in Asia from the 1990s.
  • The wellbeing of people was also dependent on the social infrastructure that supported social consumption.
  • But education and health were also drivers of economic growth in so far as they increased the productivity of the most abundant resource in Asian economies— labour—and were thus instrumental in development.
  • In contrast, countries that witnessed slow employment creation or jobless growth, with inadequate or poor public provision of education and healthcare, were laggards in Asian development.

4.5 States, markets, and governments

  • The development experience of Asia during the past 50 years shows that the role of governments was critical everywhere, although this role differed significantly across countries.
  • Even the ‘soft states’ in Southeast Asia managed to reach some understanding with business elites in the pursuit of national objectives.

4.6 Economic openness

  • Economic openness also played an important role in Asian development,30 the possibilities of which had not been recognized by Myrdal.
  • The usual characterization of openness is in terms of international trade, international investment, and international finance.
  • There were significant differences between Asian countries,31 most of which were restrictive in terms of openness until around 1970.
  • Calibrated openness was asymmetries in openness by design manifest in strategic trade policy that was open for the export sector, but restrictive for other sectors, with limits on openness to foreign capital and tight curbs on foreign brand names.
  • China, India, and Viet Nam, for quite some time, relied mostly on domestic markets, domestic resources, and domestic technologies, but subsequently these countries joined the quest for external markets with a more open, yet selective, approach to foreign capital and foreign technology.

4.7 Institutions and policies

  • In Asian Drama, Myrdal stressed the importance of an institutional approach, and he was perhaps the first to provide a systematic analysis of the role of institutions in development with reference to Asia.
  • It is clear the institutions were among the important determinants of success, muddling through, or failure at development in Asia.
  • This was also the reason why strategy-based reform with a long-term view of development objectives, emerging from experience or learning within countries rooted in social formations and political processes, did sustain and succeed.
  • 37 Similarly, they used orthodox policies for heterodox or unorthodox objectives, such as interest rates to guide the allocation of scarce investible resources in a market economy, or exchange rates that were deliberately undervalued over long periods to break into the world market for manufactured goods.

5 Afterword

  • The focus of the study is largely on the past 50 years.
  • There are obvious challenges within Asian countries, such as rising economic inequalities between people, emerging divergences among countries, poor infrastructure, underdeveloped institutions, inadequate education, unstable politics, or unsustainable political systems.
  • The response of Asian countries to these complex challenges will shape their future.
  • Gunnar Myrdal described himself as a cheerful pessimist (Streeten 1998) who hoped that Asia might do better, but did not think that it was likely.
  • In contrast, given the remarkable economic transformation of the continent over the past five decades, I could describe myself as a cautious optimist who believes that an even better world is possible for Asia.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Nayyar, Deepak
Working Paper
Rethinking Asian Drama
WIDER Working Paper, No. 2018/150
Provided in Cooperation with:
United Nations University (UNU), World Institute for Development Economics Research
(WIDER)
Suggested Citation: Nayyar, Deepak (2018) : Rethinking Asian Drama, WIDER Working Paper,
No. 2018/150, ISBN 978-92-9256-592-3, The United Nations University World Institute for
Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER), Helsinki,
https://doi.org/10.35188/UNU-WIDER/2018/592-3
This Version is available at:
http://hdl.handle.net/10419/190197
Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen:
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.
Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten,
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
Terms of use:
Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
personal and scholarly purposes.
You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
If the documents have been made available under an Open
Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.

WIDER Working Paper 2018/150
Rethinking
Asian Drama
Deepak Nayyar*
December 2018

* Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi, India, email: nayyar.deepak@gmail.com.
This study has been prepared within the UNU-WIDER project ‘Asian Transformations: An Inquiry into the Development of
Nations’.
Copyright © UNU-WIDER 2018
Information and requests: publications@wider.unu.edu
ISSN 1798-7237 ISBN 978-92-9256-592-3
Typescript prepared by Gary Smith.
The United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research provides economic analysis and policy
advice with the aim of promoting sustainable and equitable development. The Institute began operations in 1985 in Helsinki,
Finland, as the first research and training centre of the United Nations University. Today it is a unique blend of think tank, research
institute, and UN agencyproviding a range of services from policy advice to governments as well as freely available original
research.
The Institute is funded through income from an endowment fund with additional contributions to its work programme from
Finland, Sweden, and the United Kingdom as well as earmarked contributions for specific projects from a variety of donors.
Katajanokanlaituri 6 B, 00160 Helsinki, Finland
The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s), and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Institute or the United
Nations University, nor the programme/project donors.
Abstract: Gunnar Myrdal published Asian Drama in 1968, a work which made important analytical
contributions to our understanding of development but was deeply pessimistic about Asia’s future
prospects. Since then, contrary to Myrdal’s expectations, Asia’s development has been remarkable,
although transformations have been uneven across countries and unequal between people. This
paper explains the conception and design of the UNU-WIDER study on Asian Transformations,
which seeks to analyse the amazing story of economic development in Asia over the past 50 years.
It begins with reflections on Gunnar Myrdal, the author, and rethinking Asian Drama, the book, in
retrospect 50 years later. It goes on to outline the rationale and objective of the study. It then
discusses some critical issues and lessons that emergediversity in development, history and
context, economic growth and structural change, wellbeing of people, markets and governments,
economic openness, and institutions and policiesto serve as a teaser. It concludes with some
brief reflections on Asia’s future prospects over the next 25 years.
Keywords: Asian Drama, development, governments, Gunnar Myrdal, history, industrialization,
institutions, markets, openness, transformations
JEL classification: B20, B31, B41, O10, O20, O53, O57, P50
Acknowledgements: I would like to thank Ronald Findlay, Rajeev Malhotra, Sudipto Mundle,
Frances Stewart, and Finn Tarp for helpful comments and suggestions on a preliminary draft of
this paper.

1
1 Introduction
Gunnar Myrdal published his magnum opus, Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations, in
1968. The 50 years since then have witnessed a remarkable economic transformation in Asia
even if it has been uneven across countries and unequal between peoplethat would have been
difficult to imagine, let alone predict, when Myrdal and his associates completed their work. The
UNU-WIDER study, in two volumes, analyses the story of economic development in Asia
spanning half a century (see Nayyar 2019a, 2019b). This paper explains the conception and design
of the study for the reader. It begins with a discussion on Gunnar Myrdal, the author, and Asian
Drama, the book, as a point of reference. It then sets out the rationale and the objective of the
study, to outline its structure and framework. This leads into a discussion, illustrative rather than
exhaustive, of some important ideas and lessons that emerge, which might serve as a teaser. A
short afterword on future prospects concludes.
2 Gunnar Myrdal and
Asian Drama
Gunnar Myrdal was a man of many parts. The word polymath is an apt description, which might
not suffice to describe a man who was a distinguished academic, policy practitioner, member of
parliament, cabinet minister, international civil servant, political actor, public intellectual, and
concerned citizen.
1
This diversity of experiences shaped his work and thinking.
In academia, Stockholm University was his institutional home (193350). He started as a brilliant
theorist, a brash young academic
2
who went on to question the methodological foundations and
ideological underpinnings of economics, returning to his ivory tower at Stockholm University
(196267) where he founded the Institute for International Economic Studies. He was awarded
the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1974. In professional life outside academia, he turned to political
economy and developed the idea of counter-cyclical macroeconomic policies in the early 1930s.
There was an interregnum of four years (1938–42) when he lived in the United States to study the
‘Negro Problem’. He returned home to political institutions in the 1940s when he chaired a
committee that outlined the elements of the post-war Swedish welfare state, to become a member
of parliament, Chairman of the Planning Commission in Sweden, and Minister for Trade and
Commerce. During the Cold War era, he was appointed Executive Secretary of the United Nations
Economic Commission in Europe, where he served from 1947 to 1957. The next 10 years were
devoted to his study of Asia, during which he spent four years in New Delhi, where his wife, Alva
Myrdal (sociologist, diplomat, and politician, who was awarded the Nobel Peace Prize in 1982),
served as Sweden’s Ambassador in India from 1955 to 1961.
There was also a remarkable intellectual journey that ran in parallel, with many milestones and
some landmarks. Three deserve mention for their common purposecritique of systemic biases
and implicit values in economic thinkingand for their diversity of subjects: politics in economics,
1
For accounts of Gunnar Myrdal, the person and his life, see Streeten (1990, 1998), Bok (2005), Appelqvist and
Andersson (2005), Barber (2008), and Kanbur (2018).
2
Gustav Cassel, whom he succeeded as Chair in Political Economy at Stockholm University (193339), once warned
him against his brashness, Gunnar, you should be more respectful to your elders, because it is we who will determine
your promotion.’ Yes, the young Myrdal replied, but it is we who will write your obituaries.’ After Cassel’s death, he
did indeed write his obituary (Streeten 1990).

2
race in society, and poverty in the world. The Political Element in the Development of Economic Theory
was published in Swedish in 1930, in German in 1932, and in English, translated by Paul Streeten,
in 1953. An American Dilemma: The Negro Problem and Modern Democracy, for which he spent four
years in the United States, was published in 1944.
3
Asian Drama, on which he worked in India for
four years and in Sweden for six years, was published in 1968. Yet, the book was also influenced
by the evolution of Myrdal’s thinking in economics and the social sciences over a lifetime.
In this magnum opus, the fundamental point of departure from conventional thinking was the
conviction that economic problems cannot be studied in isolation but only in their own
demographic, social and political setting(Myrdal 1968: ix). The book and its approach are best
described in the author’s words from the preface:
It is not an altogether pretentious metaphor when I describe my endeavour to
apply an institutional approach in this study as an attempt to analyze the
development problems of South Asia in a manner that Adam Smith studied
England’s development problems two hundred years ago… The length is
abominable. The question can, indeed, be raised why I did not break it up into five
or six books… But the central idea in the institutional approach is that history and
politics, theories and ideologies, economic structures and levels, social
stratification, agriculture and industry, population developments, health and
education, and so on, must be studied not in isolation but in their mutual
relationships. (Myrdal 1968: x)
The title, Asian Drama, was deceptive in terms of its country coverage. Its focus was on the
erstwhile British India, made up of India, Pakistan, and Ceylon, the sub-continent now described
as South Asia. Burma and Indonesia were paid some attention. But Malaysia, the Philippines, and
Thailand were grouped together as the rest of Southeast Asia, while Cambodia, Laos, and South
Viet Nam were touched upon when some information of interest was available. It is interesting,
although somewhat puzzling, to note that Myrdal described all of these countries broadly as South
Asia even if many of them are now seen as part of Southeast Asia.
4
However, Japan, Korea, China,
Formosa (Taiwan), Hong Kong, and Singapore were excluded. So was West Asia. And, it is no
surprise that the Central Asian economies, then part of the USSR, were also excluded.
Gunnar Myrdal set out a conceptual framework and an analytical approach to study the constraints
on, and possibilities of, development in Asia at an early stage of the post-colonial era, when
experience in terms of outcomes was limited. Some important points of departure from studies of
development at that time, which reflected his methodological concerns, are set out explicitly in the
prologue, titled ‘The Beam in Our Eyes’. It begins with a plea for the sociology of knowledge, to
emphasize the importance of a multidisciplinary approach in social sciences, the recognition of
many biases in the study of development, the critical role of institutions, and the necessity of
making assumptions, priors, and values explicit. The implicit critique of mainstream economics
had three dimensions. First, the essence of the institutional approach is to use all relevant
knowledge to analyse a problem, unconstrained by the boundaries of disciplines, because in an
interdependent social system there are only problems that are not simply economic, social, or
3
Economic Theory and Underdeveloped Regions, published in 1957, was early thinking about development, while Value in
Social Theory, critical essays on methodology written earlier, translated into English, and edited by Paul Streeten, was
published in 1958. For a more detailed discussion on Myrdal’s academic writings, see Kanbur (2018). See also Streeten
(1998) and Barber (2008).
4
This description is illustrated by a map of South Asia in Myrdal (1968), which includes all the selected countries
(volume 1, 4–5). The scope and coverage of the study is also set out in the text (volume 1, 3941).

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors show that a firm's ability to dismiss employees not only affects firing, but also hiring, capital investments, acquisition, divestiture, and CEO turnover, and increases the persistence of negative (positive) performance.
Abstract: Research Summary This study characterizes and tests interdependencies in corporate activities used to adjust resources and implement change. Because each activity contributes only a partial result and depends on others to complete an intended change, constraining one can create a bottleneck that traps multiple other activities. For my empirical analysis, I leverage the staggered adoptions of employment protection laws intended to constrain one specific adjustment to one specific resource: dismissing employees. The constraint, however, not only affects the contraction but also the expansion in labor as well as capital investments, acquisition, divestiture, CEO turnover, and other adjustments, and increases (shortens) the persistence of negative (positive) performance. The expansive interdependencies are critical to understanding firm rigidity and resilience, implementation failures, and the persistence of firm performance. Managerial Summary This study shows how executing even a seemingly straightforward improvement requires piecing together a series of interdependent corporate strategic activities. As a result, a constraint on just one is sufficient to foil a successful firm response. Using changes in employment laws, I show that a firm's ability to dismiss employees not only affects firing, but also hiring, capital investments, acquisition, divestiture, and CEO turnover, and increases (shortens) the persistence of negative (positive) performance. Underestimating the complex and interdependent nature of these activities can lead to bias‐for‐action and contribute to implementation failures, such as cost overruns, schedule delays, and a post‐merger integration process that fails to realize expected synergies.

14 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: The authors examines from a comparative perspective some of the issues like unemployment, role of the state and market, domestic versus foreign market, degree of openness in trade, investment and finance, industrial and technology policy, and economic and social inequality.
Abstract: Macroeconomic strategies and policies have differed significantly among Asian countries over the last fifty years, and yet some common issues recur despite their immense diversity in inherited historical initial conditions, differences in political systems, geo-political situations, location and size, and natural resource endowments. The present paper examines from a comparative perspective some of the issues like unemployment, role of the state and market, domestic versus foreign market, degree of openness in trade, investment and finance, industrial and technology policy, and economic and social inequality. We attempt to ascertain why some countries have been more successful in dealing with these issues through policy and institutional innovations.Our comparative perspective presents developmental choices and challenges as moving targets requiring flexible institutional and policy response at each stage of development, which makes uniform guidelines misleadingly over-simplistic.

5 citations

References
More filters
Book
01 Jan 1990
TL;DR: Douglass C. North as discussed by the authors developed an analytical framework for explaining the ways in which institutions and institutional change affect the performance of economies, both at a given time and over time.
Abstract: Continuing his groundbreaking analysis of economic structures, Douglass North develops an analytical framework for explaining the ways in which institutions and institutional change affect the performance of economies, both at a given time and over time. Institutions exist, he argues, due to the uncertainties involved in human interaction; they are the constraints devised to structure that interaction. Yet, institutions vary widely in their consequences for economic performance; some economies develop institutions that produce growth and development, while others develop institutions that produce stagnation. North first explores the nature of institutions and explains the role of transaction and production costs in their development. The second part of the book deals with institutional change. Institutions create the incentive structure in an economy, and organisations will be created to take advantage of the opportunities provided within a given institutional framework. North argues that the kinds of skills and knowledge fostered by the structure of an economy will shape the direction of change and gradually alter the institutional framework. He then explains how institutional development may lead to a path-dependent pattern of development. In the final part of the book, North explains the implications of this analysis for economic theory and economic history. He indicates how institutional analysis must be incorporated into neo-classical theory and explores the potential for the construction of a dynamic theory of long-term economic change. Douglass C. North is Director of the Center of Political Economy and Professor of Economics and History at Washington University in St. Louis. He is a past president of the Economic History Association and Western Economics Association and a Fellow, American Academy of Arts and Sciences. He has written over sixty articles for a variety of journals and is the author of The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History (CUP, 1973, with R.P. Thomas) and Structure and Change in Economic History (Norton, 1981). Professor North is included in Great Economists Since Keynes edited by M. Blaug (CUP, 1988 paperback ed.)

27,080 citations

Posted Content
TL;DR: In this article, the authors examine the role that institutions, defined as the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction, play in economic performance and how those institutions change and how a model of dynamic institutions explains the differential performance of economies through time.
Abstract: Examines the role that institutions, defined as the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction, play in economic performance and how those institutions change and how a model of dynamic institutions explains the differential performance of economies through time. Institutions are separate from organizations, which are assemblages of people directed to strategically operating within institutional constraints. Institutions affect the economy by influencing, together with technology, transaction and production costs. They do this by reducing uncertainty in human interaction, albeit not always efficiently. Entrepreneurs accomplish incremental changes in institutions by perceiving opportunities to do better through altering the institutional framework of political and economic organizations. Importantly, the ability to perceive these opportunities depends on both the completeness of information and the mental constructs used to process that information. Thus, institutions and entrepreneurs stand in a symbiotic relationship where each gives feedback to the other. Neoclassical economics suggests that inefficient institutions ought to be rapidly replaced. This symbiotic relationship helps explain why this theoretical consequence is often not observed: while this relationship allows growth, it also allows inefficient institutions to persist. The author identifies changes in relative prices and prevailing ideas as the source of institutional alterations. Transaction costs, however, may keep relative price changes from being fully exploited. Transaction costs are influenced by institutions and institutional development is accordingly path-dependent. (CAR)

26,011 citations

Book
20 Mar 2012
TL;DR: Acemoglu and Robinson as discussed by the authors argue that incentives and institutions are what separate the have and have-nots, and that if they work hard, they can make money and actually keep it, the key to ensuring these incentives is sound institutions.
Abstract: In the West are the 'haves', while much of the rest of the world are the 'have-nots'. The extent of inequality today is unprecedented. Drawing on an extraordinary range of contemporary and historical examples, Why Nations Fail looks at the root of the problems facing some nations. Economists and scientists have offered useful insights into the reasons for certain aspects of poverty, such as Jeffrey Sachs (it's geography and the weather), and Jared Diamond (it's technology and species). But most theories ignore the incentives and institutions that populations need to invest and prosper: they need to know that if they work hard, they can make money and actually keep it - and the key to ensuring these incentives is sound institutions. Incentives and institutions are what separate the have and have-nots. Based on fifteen years of research, and stepping boldly into the territory of Ian Morris's Why the West Rules - For Now, Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson blend economics, politics, history and current affairs to provide a new, persuasive way of understanding wealth and poverty. And, perhaps most importantly, they provide a pragmatic basis for the hope that those mired in poverty can be placed on the path to prosperity.

4,454 citations


Additional excerpts

  • ...See also, Acemoglu and Robinson (2012)....

    [...]

MonographDOI
TL;DR: Wade's Governing the market quickly established itself as a standard in contemporary political economy as discussed by the authors, and the synergy between markets and public administration and the way allocation decisions were divided between markets, public administration, and corporations was examined.
Abstract: Published originally in 1990 to critical acclaim, Robert Wade's Governing the Market quickly established itself as a standard in contemporary political economy In it, Wade challenged claims both of those who saw the East Asian story as a vindication of free market principles and of those who attributed the success of Taiwan and other countries to government intervention Instead, Wade turned attention to the way allocation decisions were divided between markets and public administration and the synergy between them Now, in a new introduction to this paperback edition, Wade reviews the debate about industrial policy in East and Southeast Asia and chronicles the changing fortunes of these economies over the 1990s He extends the original argument to explain the boom of the first half of the decade and the crash of the second, stressing the links between corporations, banks, governments, international capital markets, and the International Monetary Fund From this, Wade goes on to outline a new agenda for national and international development policy

4,104 citations


Additional excerpts

  • ...See, for example, Amsden (1989), Lall (1997), Wade (1990), and Chang (1996)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Wade as mentioned in this paper reviewed the debate about industrial policy in East and Southeast Asia and chronicles the changing fortunes of these economies over the 1990s, and extended the original argument to explain the boom of the first half of the decade and the crash of the second, stressing the links between corporations, banks, governments, international capital markets and the International Monetary Fund.
Abstract: Published originally in 1990 to critical acclaim, Robert Wade's Governing the Market quickly established itself as a standard in contemporary political economy. In it, Wade challenged claims both of those who saw the East Asian story as a vindication of free market principles and of those who attributed the success of Taiwan and other countries to government intervention. Instead, Wade turned attention to the way allocation decisions were divided between markets and public administration and the synergy between them. Now, in a new introduction to this paperback edition, Wade reviews the debate about industrial policy in East and Southeast Asia and chronicles the changing fortunes of these economies over the 1990s. He extends the original argument to explain the boom of the first half of the decade and the crash of the second, stressing the links between corporations, banks, governments, international capital markets, and the International Monetary Fund. From this, Wade goes on to outline a new agenda for national and international development policy.

3,863 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (15)
Q1. What are the contributions mentioned in the paper "Rethinking asian drama" ?

Nayyar et al. this paper presented the UNU-WIDER study of economic development in Asia spanning half a century. 

In the earlier stages, it was about reconstructing initial conditions through the creation of physical infrastructure, the spread of education in society, and institutional reform, particularly in the agricultural sector. 

25 Ultimately, efficient markets needed effective governments, so that success in development was, in important part, attributable to the effectiveness of state interventions, which varied significantly across countries. 

In the pursuit of industrialization and development, the role of governments in evolving policies, nurturing institutions, and making strategic interventions, whether as a catalyst or a leader, was central to the process everywhere. 

Asian countries that were success stories in development used heterodox or unorthodox polices for orthodox objectives, such as strategic trade, industrial, and technology policies in the pursuit of industrialization. 

The spread of education in society and the delivery of health services to people contributed directly to the wellbeing of people and were thus constitutive of development. 

Economic growth had a greater impact on living conditions of ordinary people where employment creation was rapid or where initial income distribution was less unequal. 

The object of the study is to analyse the development experience of Asia and its associated transformations over the past 50 years. 

In 1965, almost four-fifths of the total population of Asia lived in rural areas, whereas by 2016 this proportion was just over one-half, showing how rapid urbanization has been. 

But sustained rapid growth in Asia did not reduce absolute poverty as much as it could have, in part because the initial income distribution was unequal and in part because of rising income inequality. 

But education and health were also drivers of economic growth in so far as they increased the productivity of the most abundant resource in Asian economies— labour—and were thus instrumental in development. 

All the same, it is clear that Asian development in this era was driven by economic growth based on high investment, savings rates, and rapid industrialization, often export-led, associated with structural change in the composition of output and employment, which reinforced the process. 

But the ratio of GDP per capita in Asia to GDP per capita in industrialized countries, in current prices at market exchange rates, increased far less from 1:20 in 1970 to 1:8 in 2016. 

The share of Asia in world exports of manufactured goods almost doubled in just two decades, from 21 per cent in 1995 to 39 per cent in 2016. 

this rapid growth was not always transformed into meaningful development that improved the wellbeing of people, particularly in countries where employment creation was slow or where income inequality was high to start with.