scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Statistical physics of crime: A review

TL;DR: In this article, the authors review different approaches aimed at modeling and improving our understanding of crime, focusing on the nucleation of crime hotspots using partial differential equations, self-exciting point process and agent-based modeling, adversarial evolutionary games, and network science behind the formation of gangs and large-scale organized crime.
Abstract: Containing the spreading of crime in urban societies remains a major challenge. Empirical evidence suggests that, left unchecked, crimes may be recurrent and proliferate. On the other hand, eradicating a culture of crime may be difficult, especially under extreme social circumstances that impair the creation of a shared sense of social responsibility. Although our understanding of the mechanisms that drive the emergence and diffusion of crime is still incomplete, recent research highlights applied mathematics and methods of statistical physics as valuable theoretical resources that may help us better understand criminal activity. We review different approaches aimed at modeling and improving our understanding of crime, focusing on the nucleation of crime hotspots using partial differential equations, self-exciting point process and agent-based modeling, adversarial evolutionary games, and the network science behind the formation of gangs and large-scale organized crime. We emphasize that statistical physics of crime can relevantly inform the design of successful crime prevention strategies, as well as improve the accuracy of expectations about how different policing interventions should impact malicious human activity deviating from social norms. We also outline possible directions for future research, related to the effects of social and coevolving networks and to the hierarchical growth of criminal structures due to self-organization.

Summary (1 min read)

Jump to:  and [Summary]

Summary

  • This is particularly evident – even for microcriminality – in urban areas (in Europe and North America the percent of population living in urban areas is around 85%).
  • And the role of mathematical, statistical, and physical models has been steadily increasing.
  • Thus, the paper [6] appears to be extremely timely and useful.
  • Generally speaking, models are often more descriptive than predictive, in the sense that it is not expected that they predict e.g. the number of burglaries or car thefts that will occur in a given district over a given period of time.
  • Nevertheless, they can be instrumental in describing the mechanisms by which it can be foreseen that a concentration of crimes can appear in particular zones (hot spots), or the “contagion” that criminal behaviour can have on particular classes of individuals.
  • This description can in turn suggest how to contrast the phenomena.
  • Therefore, modelling the diffusion of criminal (or simply unlawful) behaviour in urban areas can be a tool that administrations and police authorities can use in order to choose optimal strategies to combat crime.
  • And this is particularly important in a horizon of budget cuts that impose the best use of the existing resources, optimization of strategies, logistics etc.
  • Of course “for complex phenomena as criminality (in its various guises), the goal is not to represent the whole reality, let alone generate precise predictions.
  • The enhanced understanding of “stylized facts” that characterise a system of interest by isolating elements of a theoretical model can shed new light on the subject and contribute to new insights into the more complex global picture.
  • With the aid of such models, one can then investigate the various effects implied by factors such as the severity of punishment, duration of imprisonment, different deterrence strategies, or the allocation of limited crime reduction resources in the most efficient way” [4].

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com
ScienceDirect
Physics of Life Reviews 12 (2015) 34–35
www.elsevier.com/locate/plrev
Comment
The role of mathematical modelling in modern criminology
Comment
on “Statistical physics of crime: A review” by
M.R. D’Orsogna and M. Perc
Mario Primicerio
Dipartimento di Matematica “U. Dini”, Università di Firenze, Viale Morgagni 67/A, 50141 Firenze, Italy
Received 2
December 2014; accepted 3 December 2014
Available
online 5 December 2014
Communicated by L.
Peliti
Criminality is a big challenge at several different levels. This is particularly evident even for microcriminality
in urban areas (in Europe and North America the percent of population living in urban areas is around 85%). It is
considered by sociologists among the most important indexes affecting the (perception of the) quality of life in a gi
ven
place.
Starting from the seminal paper by G. Beck
er [3], the study of crime and criminality from the point of view of
economics has been developed in several directions. And the role of mathematical, statistical, and physical models
has been steadily increasing. Thus, the paper [6] appears to be extremely timely and useful.
Generally speaking, models are often more descriptive than pr
edictive, in the sense that it is not expected that
they predict e.g. the number of burglaries or car thefts that will occur in a given district over a given period of time.
Nevertheless, they can be instrumental in describing the mechanisms by which it can be foreseen that a concentration
of crimes can appear in particular zones (hot spots), or the “contagion” that criminal beha
viour can have on particular
classes of individuals. This description can in turn suggest how to contrast the phenomena.
Therefore, modelling the dif
fusion of criminal (or simply unlawful) behaviour in urban areas can be a tool that
administrations and police authorities can use in order to choose optimal strategies to combat crime. And this is par-
ticularly important in a horizon of budget cuts that impose the best use of the existing (scarce) resources, optimization
of strate
gies, logistics etc.
Another feature of the models is the fact that they allow to perform simulations to mimic the response of the system
to changes of parameters, of external inputs or constraints. Of course “for complex phenomena as criminality (in its
various guises), the goal is not to represent the whole reality, let alone generate precise predictions. However, the
enhanced understanding of “stylized facts” that characterise a system of inter
est by isolating elements of a theoretical
model can shed new light on the subject and contribute to new insights into the more complex global picture. With the
aid of such models, one can then investigate the various effects implied by factors such as the severity of punishment,
dur
ation of imprisonment, different deterrence strategies, or the allocation of limited crime reduction resources in the
most efficient way” [4].
DOI of original article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.plrev.2014.11.001.
E-mail
address: primicer@math.unifi.it.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.plrev.2014.12.001
1571-0645/© 2014
Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

M. Primicerio / Physics of Life Reviews 12 (2015) 34–35 35
The review by M.R. D’Orsogna and M. Perc [6] shows how rich is the panorama of the methods that can be of
help.
A special attention is devoted to agent-based models in which the time-varying attractiveness of a given target (for
instance in burglary) is modelled, biasing the movement of a burglar over a grid simulating the city; the consequent
probability of occurrence of crime is evaluated, thus influencing in turn the attractiveness of the target. Possible
mean-field approximations are discussed, leading to models based on population dynamics and on reaction–dif
fusion
equations. Perhaps, from this point of view, the bibliography of the review could be successfully complemented with
the one that can be found in the paper by M. Gordon [7] and by the papers published in a special issue of EJAM [11]
in 2010.
Among the agent-based models, one could also include the methods based on cellular automata that can take into
account the influence that “neighbours” can have in the diffusion of unlawful behaviour (e.g. tax evasion), see for
instance [9].
Another important class of models is based on “space–time point processes”. These are particularly rele
vant to
the crimes that appear to be clustered in time and space, so that a methodology similar to that applied in studying
earthquake swarms and clusters can be used. This is a typical example in which a technique that has pro
ved efficient
in a context that is far from sociology and criminology appears to be successful not only in describing the occurrence
of an offence, but also, in some cases, to locate the home base of criminals.
It is well-kno
wn, and properly outlined in the paper, that evolutionary game theory has proved to be apt to model
some basic phenomena connected with crime and criminology, including the role of social control in discouraging
criminality: the category of “informants” plays a major role in the desirable transition from a criminal-controlled
society to an almost crime-free situation. And this is clearly described by an e
volutionary game with four possible
strategies (criminal, informants, guards, and “blinds”). Inspection games are another category of techniques that are
used in this context, although some counter-intuitive results could be obtained (see e.g. [1]).
An emer
ging line of investigation is also reviewed by the paper, with several hints of possible new areas of research:
the development of networks of criminality. The increasing interconnectivity of our societies suggests that, besides of
the classical cases of geographically localized networks such as street gangs, one could have to deal with or
ganized
criminal networks [8] that have a worldwide domain of action (drug dealers, money laundering [2,10] etc.); but another
topic that deserves further investigation concerns the way criminal or unlawful behaviour can proliferate just because
of the existence of social networks [5].
A final remark on the paper: the bibliograph
y is so rich that it would have been desirable that the references are
ordered by the alphabetical order of the first author, or by the date of publication.
References
[1] Andreozzi L. Rewarding policemen increases crime. Some more surprising results from the inspection game. Public Choice 2004;121:69–82.
[2] Araujo
RA. An evolutionary game theory approach to combat money laundering. J Money Laund Control 2010;13:70–8.
[3] Beck
er G. Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J Polit Econ 1968;76:169–217.
[4] Berestycki
H, Johnson SD, Ockendon JR, Primicerio M. Foreword to the special issue of EJAM on crime modelling. Eur J Appl Math
2010;21:271–4.
[5] Calvò-Armengol
A, Zenou Y. Social networks and crime decisions: the role of social structure in facilitating delinquent behaviour. Int Econ
Rev 2004;45:939–58.
[6] D’Orsogna
MR, Perc M. Statistical physics of crime: a review. Phys Life Rev 2015;12:1–21 [in this issue].
[7] Gordon
MB. A random walk in the literature on criminality: a partial and critical view on some statistical analysis and modeling approaches.
Eur J Appl Math 2010;21:283–306.
[8] McIll
wain JS. Organized crime: a social network approach. Crime Law Soc Change 1999;32:301–23.
[9] Meacci
L, Nuno JC, Primicerio M. Fighting tax evasion: a cellular automata approach. Adv Math Sci Appl 2012;22:597–610.
[10] Wa
lker J, Unger B. The Walker gravity model. Int Rev Law Econ 2009;5:821–53.
[11] http://journals.cambridge.or
g/action/displayIssue?jid=EJM&volumeId=21&seriesId=0&issueId=4-5.
Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The field of social physics has been a hot topic in the last few decades as mentioned in this paper , with many researchers venturing outside of their traditional domains of interest, but also taking from physics the methods that have proven so successful throughout the 19th and the 20th century.

133 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
10 Jan 2022-Fractals
TL;DR: In this article , the authors proposed a fractional-order crime transmission model by categorizing the existing population into four clusters: law-abiding citizens, criminally active individuals who have not been imprisoned, prisoners, and prisoners who completed the prison tenure.
Abstract: Due to the alarming rise in types of crime committed and the number of criminal activities across the world, there is a great need to amend the existing policies and models adopted by jurisdictional institutes. The majority of the mathematical models have not included the history of the crime committed by the individual, which is vital to control crime transmission in stipulated time. Further, due to various external factors and policies, a considerable number of criminals have not been imprisoned. To address the aforementioned issues prevailing in society, this research proposes a fractional-order crime transmission model by categorizing the existing population into four clusters. These clusters include law-abiding citizens, criminally active individuals who have not been imprisoned, prisoners, and prisoners who completed the prison tenure. The well-posedness and stability of the proposed fractional model are discussed in this work. Furthermore, the proposed model is extended to the delayed model by introducing the time-delay coefficient as time lag occurs between the individual’s offense and the judgment. The endemic equilibrium of the delayed model is locally asymptotically stable up to a certain extent, after which bifurcation occurs.

12 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper , a comprehensive investigation of corruption networks related to political scandals in Spain and Brazil over nearly three decades is presented, showing that corruption networks of both countries share universal structural and dynamical properties, including similar degree distributions, clustering and assortativity coefficients, modular structure, and a growth process that is marked by the coalescence of network components due to a few recidivist criminals.
Abstract: Corruption crimes demand highly coordinated actions among criminal agents to succeed. But research dedicated to corruption networks is still in its infancy and indeed little is known about the properties of these networks. Here we present a comprehensive investigation of corruption networks related to political scandals in Spain and Brazil over nearly three decades. We show that corruption networks of both countries share universal structural and dynamical properties, including similar degree distributions, clustering and assortativity coefficients, modular structure, and a growth process that is marked by the coalescence of network components due to a few recidivist criminals. We propose a simple model that not only reproduces these empirical properties but reveals also that corruption networks operate near a critical recidivism rate below which the network is entirely fragmented and above which it is overly connected. Our research thus indicates that actions focused on decreasing corruption recidivism may substantially mitigate this type of organized crime.

7 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper , structural properties of political corruption, police intelligence, and money laundering networks can be used to recover missing criminal partnerships, distinguish among different types of criminal and legal associations, as well as predict the total amount of money exchanged among criminal agents.
Abstract: Recent research has shown that criminal networks have complex organizational structures, but whether this can be used to predict static and dynamic properties of criminal networks remains little explored. Here, by combining graph representation learning and machine learning methods, we show that structural properties of political corruption, police intelligence, and money laundering networks can be used to recover missing criminal partnerships, distinguish among different types of criminal and legal associations, as well as predict the total amount of money exchanged among criminal agents, all with outstanding accuracy. We also show that our approach can anticipate future criminal associations during the dynamic growth of corruption networks with significant accuracy. Thus, similar to evidence found at crime scenes, we conclude that structural patterns of criminal networks carry crucial information about illegal activities, which allows machine learning methods to predict missing information and even anticipate future criminal behavior.

6 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The present study indicates that, for all reasonably regular initial data and any corresponding Neumann initial-boundary value problem possesses a global generalized solution, which becomes bounded and smooth at least eventually.
Abstract:

We consider a chemotaxis system over a bounded domain \begin{document}$ \Omega\subset \mathbb R^2 $\end{document} of the following form

with \begin{document}$ \chi>0 $\end{document}, \begin{document}$ a\geq0 $\end{document} and \begin{document}$ b>0 $\end{document}. The particular version of (\begin{document}$ \star$\end{document}) with \begin{document}$ \chi = 2 $\end{document} was proposed by Pitcher to describe the evolution of population dynamics of criminal agents. Recent results reveal that the system (\begin{document}$ \star$\end{document}) associated with Neumann boundary conditions admits a global classical solution, under appropriate smallness conditions on both the initial data and the parameter \begin{document}$ \chi $\end{document}.

The present study indicates that nevertheless, for all reasonably regular initial data and any \begin{document}$ \chi>0 $\end{document}, the corresponding Neumann initial-boundary value problem possesses a global generalized solution. Furthermore, it also demonstrates that, whenever \begin{document}$ a = 0 $\end{document}, such global generalized solution becomes bounded and smooth at least eventually. In particular, it approaches the spatial equilibria at exponential rate in the large time limit.

4 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a mathematical framework based on reaction-diffusion partial differential equations for studying the dynamics of crime hotspots, which is based on empirical evidence for how offenders move and mix with potential victims or targets.
Abstract: The mechanisms driving the nucleation, spread, and dissipation of crime hotspots are poorly understood. As a consequence, the ability of law enforcement agencies to use mapped crime patterns to design crime prevention strategies is severely hampered. We also lack robust expectations about how different policing interventions should impact crime. Here we present a mathematical framework based on reaction-diffusion partial differential equations for studying the dynamics of crime hotspots. The system of equations is based on empirical evidence for how offenders move and mix with potential victims or targets. Analysis shows that crime hotspots form when the enhanced risk of repeat crimes diffuses locally, but not so far as to bind distant crime together. Crime hotspots may form as either supercritical or subcritical bifurcations, the latter the result of large spikes in crime that override linearly stable, uniform crime distributions. Our mathematical methods show that subcritical crime hotspots may be permanently eradicated with police suppression, whereas supercritical hotspots are displaced following a characteristic spatial pattern. Our results thus provide a mechanistic explanation for recent failures to observe crime displacement in experimental field tests of hotspot policing.

200 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A mathematical framework for the evolution of in-group favoritism from a continuum of strategies is proposed, not based on explicit intergroup conflict, but instead uses evolutionary set theory.
Abstract: In-group favoritism is a central aspect of human behavior. People often help members of their own group more than members of other groups. Here we propose a mathematical framework for the evolution of in-group favoritism from a continuum of strategies. Unlike previous models, we do not pre-suppose that players never cooperate with out-group members. Instead, we determine the conditions under which preferential in-group cooperation emerges, and also explore situations where preferential out-group helping could evolve. Our approach is not based on explicit intergroup conflict, but instead uses evolutionary set theory. People can move between sets. Successful sets attract members, and successful strategies gain imitators. Individuals can employ different strategies when interacting with in-group versus out-group members. Our framework also allows us to implement different games for these two types of interactions. We prove general results and derive specific conditions for the evolution of cooperation based on in-group favoritism.

199 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: By combining computational modeling and social network analysis with unique criminal network intelligence data from the Dutch Police, it is discovered, in contrast to common belief, that criminal networks might even become ‘stronger’, after targeted attacks.
Abstract: Researchers, policymakers and law enforcement agencies across the globe struggle to find effective strategies to control criminal networks. The effectiveness of disruption strategies is known to depend on both network topology and network resilience. However, as these criminal networks operate in secrecy, data-driven knowledge concerning the effectiveness of different criminal network disruption strategies is very limited. By combining computational modeling and social network analysis with unique criminal network intelligence data from the Dutch Police, we discovered, in contrast to common belief, that criminal networks might even become ‘stronger’, after targeted attacks. On the other hand increased efficiency within criminal networks decreases its internal security, thus offering opportunities for law enforcement agencies to target these networks more deliberately. Our results emphasize the importance of criminal network interventions at an early stage, before the network gets a chance to (re-)organize to maximum resilience. In the end disruption strategies force criminal networks to become more exposed, which causes successful network disruption to become a long-term effort.

195 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A mathematical framework aimed at analyzing repeat and near-repeat effects in crime data is developed, which model repeat victimization as a series of random events, the likelihood of which changes each time an offense occurs.
Abstract: We develop a mathematical framework aimed at analyzing repeat and near-repeat effects in crime data. Parsing burglary data from Long Beach, CA according to different counting methods, we determine the probability distribution functions for the time interval τ between repeat offenses. We then compare these observed distributions to theoretically derived distributions in which the repeat effects are due solely to persistent risk heterogeneity. We find that risk heterogeneity alone cannot explain the observed distributions, while a form of event dependence (boosts) can. Using this information, we model repeat victimization as a series of random events, the likelihood of which changes each time an offense occurs. We are able to estimate typical time scales for repeat burglary events in Long Beach by fitting our data to this model. Computer simulations of this model using these observed parameters agree with the empirical data.

189 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The evolution of opportunism (the readiness to be swayed by incentives) and the evolution of trust (the propensity to cooperate in the absence of information on the co-players) are studied.
Abstract: Cooperation in public good games is greatly promoted by positive and negative incentives. In this paper, we use evolutionary game dynamics to study the evolution of opportunism (the readiness to be swayed by incentives) and the evolution of trust (the propensity to cooperate in the absence of information on the co-players). If both positive and negative incentives are available, evolution leads to a population where defectors are punished and players cooperate, except when they can get away with defection. Rewarding behaviour does not become fixed, but can play an essential role in catalysing the emergence of cooperation, especially if the information level is low.

184 citations

Frequently Asked Questions (1)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "The role of mathematical modelling in modern criminology.comment on “statistical physics of crime: a review” by m.r. d'orsogna and m. perc" ?

Starting from the seminal paper by G. Becker [ 3 ], the study of crime and criminality from the point of view of economics has been developed in several directions. Thus, the paper [ 6 ] appears to be extremely timely and useful. Therefore, modelling the diffusion of criminal ( or simply unlawful ) behaviour in urban areas can be a tool that administrations and police authorities can use in order to choose optimal strategies to combat crime. This description can in turn suggest how to contrast the phenomena.