scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

The labour market and the distribution of earnings: an empirical analysis for Italy

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this paper, the authors address the question of earnings dispersion by applying a "nested" decomposition procedure of the Theil inequality measure, which combines into a unified framework the standard decompositions by population subgroups and income sources.
Abstract
Using four waves of data from the Participation Labour Unemployment Survey, a database of information on the Italian labour market supply, we address the question of earnings dispersion by applying a ‘nested’ decomposition procedure of the Theil inequality measure, which combines into a unified framework the standard decompositions by population subgroups and income sources. The empirical evidence obtained points to the key role played by the self-employees in shaping labour income inequality, especially at the upper extreme of the earnings distribution, and the emergence of non-standard forms of employment as an important feature of the contemporary workplace.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

This article was downloaded by: [Fabio Clementi]
On: 10 October 2013, At: 07:55
Publisher: Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered
office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK
International Review of Applied
Economics
Publication details, including instructions for authors and
subscription information:
http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cira20
The labour market and the distribution
of earnings: an empirical analysis for
Italy
Fabio Clementi
a
& Michele Giammatteo
b
a
University of Macerata, Department of Political Science,
Communication and International Relations, Piazza G. Oberdan 3,
62100 Macerata, Italy
b
Bank of Italy, Via Nazionale 91, 00184 Rome, Italy
Published online: 09 Oct 2013.
To cite this article: Fabio Clementi & Michele Giammatteo , International Review of Applied
Economics (2013): The labour market and the distribution of earnings: an empirical analysis for
Italy, International Review of Applied Economics, DOI: 10.1080/02692171.2013.838544
To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02692171.2013.838544
PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE
Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the
“Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis,
our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to
the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions
and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors,
and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content
should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources
of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims,
proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or
howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising
out of the use of the Content.
This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any
substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing,
systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms &

Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-
and-conditions
Downloaded by [Fabio Clementi] at 07:55 10 October 2013

The labour market and the distribution of earnings: an empirical
analysis for Italy
Fabio Clementi
a
* and Michele Giammatteo
b
a
University of Macerata, Department of Political Science, Communication and International
Relations, Piazza G. Oberdan 3, 62100 Macerata, Italy;
b
Bank of Italy, Via Nazionale 91,
00184 Rome, Italy
(Received 7 April 2012; nal version received 12 August 2013)
Using four waves of data from the Participation Labour Unemployment Survey,
a database of information on the Italian labour market supply, we address
the question of earnings dispersion by applying a nested decomposition
procedure of the Theil inequality measure, which combines into a unied
framework the standard decompositions by population subgroups and income
sources. The empirical evidence obtained points to the key role played by the
self-employees in shaping labour income inequality, especially at the upper
extreme of the earnings distribution, and the emergence of non-standard forms
of employment as an important feature of the contemporary workplace.
Keywords: labour income; size distribution; inequality
JEL Classications: D33, D63
1. Introduction
Since the mid-1990s, and at least up to the onset of the current economic crisis,
labour market outcomes improved substantially in Italy. Between 1995 and 2007,
the most recent year unaffected by the crisis, about 2.5 million jobs were created
(mostly in dependent employment) and almost 3 million people entered the work-
force (Checchi
2014). Spurred by the positive developments in employment and
labour force participation, the unemployment rate declined to around 6% in 2007,
about half its 1995 peak of over 12% (Schindler
2009).
1
However, such improve-
ments were accompanied by poor productivity growth (Lucidi
2007; Codogno 2009;
Lucidi and Kleinknecht
2010) and a structural deterioration of Italys competitive-
ness (Barca
2005; Faini and Sapir 2009; Codogno 2009). In particular, starting by
the end of the 1990s, growth in labour productivity has been modest, even negative
in some years, and as a result its level has recently come to be low compared to that
prevailing in the early 1990s and other industrialised countries.
2
At the same time,
the growth of jobs coincided with a modest real wage growth a yearly increase of
0.7% during 19962007 (Checchi
2014).
The trends outlined above coincided with a period of intense reforms entered by
the Italian labour market. Key among them were the reform of the bargaining system
of the early 1990s which introduced the collective bargaining framework still in
*Corresponding author. Email: fabio.clementi@unimc.it
© 2013 Taylor & Francis
International Review of Applied Economics, 2013
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/02692171.2013.838544
Downloaded by [Fabio Clementi] at 07:55 10 October 2013

use and several labour market reforms aimed to increase the employment rate by
means of expansion in labour market exibility.
The collective bargaining structure laid out in 1993 closed the period of
automatic wage indexation (the so-called Scala mobile) which dated back to the
mid-1970s. The new bargaining arrangements consist of a national-sectoral bargain-
ing level and a second one decentralised at regional or rm level. At the central
(national) level, rms and trade unions dene general employment conditions and
act for preservation of the purchasing power of real wages with periodic ination
compensations. At the local level, rm and unions negotiate possible rents redistri-
bution on the basis of productivity performances with the objective of enhancing
wage exibility. However, second-level agreements are optional and cannot dene
wages lower than the sectoral minimum. This has limited to some extent the use of
decentralised bargaining, especially among small rms characterised by a low degree
of trade unionisation. As a result, annual wage distributions have appeared more
compressed than was expected (see for example Casadio
2003, Checchi and Pagani
2005, and Dell Aringa and Pagani 2007).
3
With regards to the pursuit of labour market efciency, starting from the end of
the 1990s some legislative measures have been specically directed at fostering ex-
ibility through an increase of the so-called atypical or non-standard forms of
employment. More specically, the measures introduced by the Law 196/1997
(Legge Treu, named after then Labour Minister Tiziano Treu) amplied exibility by
extending the set of temporary contracts and providing incentives for part-time
work. The Law 30/2003 (Legge Biagi, named after the advisor on labour market
reforms under the 20012006 Berlusconi government) further deregulated the use of
temporary agency work
4
and introduced new forms of atypical work such as on-call
jobs, job sharing and occasional work. Moreover, the latter reform has given a great
thrust to the extensive use of collaboration workers namely, holders of continuous
and coordinated collaboration contracts (Collaborazioni coordinate e continuative, or
Co.co.co) and contracts linked to a specic project (Collaborazioni continuative a
progetto, or Co.co.pro) who, although formally self-employed, often work as if
they were normal employees.
5
The large adoption (abuse) of such labour relation-
ships beneted of their more protable compulsory pension contributions with
respect to both standard and xed-term employment. Furthermore, if on one hand
collaboration works allow employers to save labour costs, on the other hand, being
a real Italian peculiarity, their inclusion in the category of temporary employment
makes the incidence of atypical workers substantially higher in the Italian labour
market than in other European countries (Ballarino et al.
2013).
The changes in institutional framework embraced by the Italian labour market
during the last two decades certainly contributed to the growth in aggregate employ-
ment. However, the crisis has shown that this employment growth has been just a
transitional honeymoon, growthless job creating effect (Boeri and Garibaldi
2007):
since most of the new positions created were temporary and part-time works, almost
800,000 jobs disappeared in the 2009 crisis (Checchi
2014). Indeed, the number of
workers in temporary work arrangements more than doubled between 1995 and
2007, and part-time employment increased by 65% during that time; permanent and
full-time jobs, instead, grew respectively by only 7% and 9% over the same years
(Schindler
2009).
6
Furthermore, the employment gains since 1995 occurred at the
expense of real wage growth: in fact, a phase of relevant wage moderation took
place since the change of the contractual arrangements, causing real wages to
2 F. Clementi and M. Giammatteo
Downloaded by [Fabio Clementi] at 07:55 10 October 2013

increase on average less than labour productivity and leading to a decline of the
labour share on national income (Tronti
2007; Pugliese 2008).
7
Several authors have
also demonstrated how the prolonged period of wage moderation and the increased
exibility translated into small labour productivity growth, as the reduction of rms
wage bill makes worthwhile the preservation of low-productive jobs and labour-
intensive productive processes, thereby reducing the incentives for rms to innovate
and their scope for training activities and high quality human resource management
practices (e.g. Lucidi
2007; but see also Stirati 2008, Lucidi and Kleinknecht 2010,
Cappellari et al.
2012, and Cutuli and Guetto 2013).
Under a distributional perspective, while paying out in terms of employment
growth, the increased labour market mainly achieved through a series of reforms
at the margin that liberalised the use of temporary contracts but left largely
unchanged the legislation applying to permanent workers has led to a strong
segmentation of the Italian labour market, where highly protected and well-paid
permanent jobs coexist along with risky and low-paid temporary occupations
(Barbieri and Scherer
2009).
8
This has exacerbated existing earnings inequalities
between standard and non-standard forms of employment:
9
recent econometric
studies have indeed shown the existence of a wage differential between temporary
and regular employees that has been estimated to range between 7% and 25%
(Picchio
2006; Cutuli 2008; Lucidi and Raitano 2009a,b; OECD 2012).
Another major factor of inequality in the Italian labour market is related to work-
ers condition as employees and self-employed: Italys self-employment rate stands
out among the industrialised countries (Barbieri and Bison
2004) and the role of
self-employment income in explaining the recent Italian inequality trend has been
documented by several studies (see, among others, Torrini
2005, 2006, Quintano
et al.
2006, Rani 2008, Fiorio 2011, and Ballarino et al. 2013). Moreover, the Italian
distribution of labour earnings showed a persistent increasing pattern in top income
shares since the mid-1980s, mainly driven by top wages and self-employment
income (Alvaredo and Pisano
2010). Recently, the OECD (2011, p. 3) stated that in
Italy changes in self-employment income were important drivers of increased earn-
ings inequality: their share in total earned income has increased by 10% since the
mid-1980s, and self-employment income seems more predominant among high earn-
ers, to the contrary of many other OECD countries.
Drawing from these recent labour market developments, in the present work we
provide new empirical evidence on the distribution of earnings in Italy, focusing in
particular on the inequality consequences of the Italian employment composition as
dominated by a large share of self-employment and recently affected by labour mar-
ket exibility reforms. In order to avoid using partial measures that only focus on
limited parts of the overall distribution, or average wage differentials arising
between speci c subpopulations, we apply a nested decomposition of the Theil
inequality index by population subgroups and income sources, which allows us to
investigate how much of the dispersion in earnings concentrated in different parts of
the distribution might be accounted for by alternative sources of labour income
(standard, self-employment and atypical). There are indeed many reasons to explore
inequality in different parts of the distribution. For example, the same degree
of inequality can lead to different economic outcomes, depending on whether the
inequality is more pronounced in the lower tail of the distribution or in the top end
(Morris et al.
1994; Voitchovsky 2005). Additionally, using wage differentials at
International Review of Applied Economics 3
Downloaded by [Fabio Clementi] at 07:55 10 October 2013

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Working from home and income inequality: risks of a 'new normal' with COVID-19.

TL;DR: In this article, the authors explored the potential consequences in the labour income distribution related to a long-lasting increase in working from home feasibility among Italian employees and found that a positive shift in WFH feasibility would be associated with an increase in average labour income, but this potential benefit would not be equally distributed among employees.
Journal ArticleDOI

Geographical spread of global emissions: Within-country inequalities are large and increasing

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors measured the extent of within-country inequalities for two major greenhouse gases, CO2 and CH4, over the 1970-2008 period, and showed that between-sector inequalities matter more than between-country inequality, and between sector inequalities become the dominant source of global inequality at the end of the sample period in the CO2 case.
Journal ArticleDOI

All that glitters is not gold. Influence of working from home on income inequality at the time of Covid - 19

TL;DR: In this article, the authors explored the role of working from home attitude across labour income distribution in italy and found that increasing wfh attitudes of occupations would lead to a rise of wage inequality among italian employees.
Journal Article

Informal employment in Ukraine and European Union transition countries

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present l'etat actuel de l'emploi informel en Ukraine and les pays en transition and elaborate the fonction des gains du capital humain for le marche du travail en appliquant la fonoction de repartition des gains de Mincer.
Posted Content

Estimating the marginal rate of substitution between wage and employment protection

TL;DR: In this paper, a survey on workers from the Italian public employment service showed that workers actually require a monetary compensation to trade a non-standard job for a standard one, and that they display lexicographic preferences over contracts.
References
More filters
Book

An introduction to the bootstrap

TL;DR: This article presents bootstrap methods for estimation, using simple arguments, with Minitab macros for implementing these methods, as well as some examples of how these methods could be used for estimation purposes.
Journal ArticleDOI

Power-Law Distributions in Empirical Data

TL;DR: This work proposes a principled statistical framework for discerning and quantifying power-law behavior in empirical data by combining maximum-likelihood fitting methods with goodness-of-fit tests based on the Kolmogorov-Smirnov (KS) statistic and likelihood ratios.
Journal ArticleDOI

Income Inequality in the United States, 1913–1998

TL;DR: The authors showed that the large shocks that capital owners experienced during the Great Depression and World War II have had a permanent effect on top capital incomes and argued that steep progressive income and estate taxation may have prevented large fortunes from fully recovering from these shocks.
Journal ArticleDOI

A Simple General Approach to Inference About the Tail of a Distribution

Bruce M. Hill
- 01 Sep 1975 - 
TL;DR: In this paper, a simple general approach to inference about the tail behavior of a distribution is proposed, which is not required to assume any global form for the distribution function, but merely the form of behavior in the tail where it is desired to draw inference.
Frequently Asked Questions (16)
Q1. What are the contributions mentioned in the paper "The labour market and the distribution of earnings: an empirical analysis for italy" ?

Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. 

36More in general, minimum wage protection policies, purchasing power preservation systems, as well as the adoption of contrast measures for preventing various discrimination and irregular practices could contribute to reducing earnings differences. 

Because of the additive property of equation (4), the absolute values sum up both vertically and horizontally; the percent values are calculated with respect to total inequality (‘Source dec.’) as well as ‘Within’ and ‘Between’ components. 

The large adoption (abuse) of such labour relationships benefited of their more profitable compulsory pension contributions with respect to both standard and fixed-term employment. 

The within-group component of labour income inequality increased from more than 49% in 2005 to around 57% in 2008, while it reduced in 2010. 

In addition, as maintained by Codogno (2009), since the mid-1990s – and especially in the early 2000s – the reduction in the contribution of labour productivity to GDP growth more than offset the positive contribution of labour utilisation, hence resulting in weak overall GDP growth. 

Despite the Gini-based multi-decomposition of inequality proposed by Mussard (2004, 2006), the choice of the Theil index as the reference measure of inequality is motivated by two main reasons: (i) it allows perfect (subgroups) decomposability22and (ii) satisfies the fundamental property of uniform addition for source-based decomposition. 

The standard decomposition by income sources highlights the fundamental role played by the selfemployed in shaping total income inequality, even though their relative impact decreased steadily from 112% to less than 68%. 

Since the mid-1990s, and at least up to the onset of the current economic crisis, labour market outcomes improved substantially in Italy. 

The importance of executive compensations to explain theInternational Review of Applied Economics 17D ownl oade dby [Fa bio Cle men ti]a t 07: 551 0O ctob er2 013rise in top income shares during the last quarter of the twentieth century has been a standard result in all the studies analysing income concentration within the top groups in Anglo-Saxon countries. 

A tentative explanation explored by Piketty and Saez (2003, 2006) but see also Lemieux 2008 and Lemieux et al. 2009) is that the growth in performance-related schemes – which affect the compensation of high executives – and the change in social norms – regarding inequality and the acceptability of very high wages – have removed some implicit barriers to the rise of incomes for the very highest earners. 

for each possible xmin the authors first obtain the estimate of the shape parameter a over the data x xmin by using the conditional maximum likelihood estimator introduced by Hill (1975)âH ¼ 1m Xm 1 i¼1ðln xn iþ1 ln xn mþ1Þ " # 1(2)where m ¼ n k þ 1 is the number of extreme sample values above the threshold, n is the sample size and k is the rank of the order statistic xn–m+1, and then the authors compute the Kolmogorov-Smirnov (K-S) goodness-of-fit statisticD ¼ maxx xmin jF̂ðxÞ 

The authors are also grateful to Stéphane Mussard for help with his GAUSS code on the Gini multi-decomposition by population subgroups and income sources. 

All t-ratios were indeed significant at the 0.1% level and relatively large – for example, the smallest t-ratio for any estimate of xmin was slightly less than 4 and was typically at least seven times larger for a. 

ownl oade dby [Fa bio Cle men ti]a t 07: 551 0O ctob er2 013use – and several labour market reforms aimed to increase the employment rate by means of expansion in labour market flexibility. 

Sst atis tic(D )Dmin = 0.074 k∗ = 15,505Number of observations in the upper tail (m)0 6α̂H ∗ = 1.916m∗ = 1,083 C om pl em en ta ry c um ul at iv e di st rib ut io n100 1000 10000 100000 10000000.