scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

The role of perceived acceptability of alternatives in identifying and assessing choice set processing strategies in stated choice settings: The case of road pricing reform

TL;DR: This paper used an endogenous choice set model to investigate the influence that contextual effects and socioeconomic characteristics play in explaining variations in the choice sets considered by respondents when they reveal their preferences, which aligns with the idea of the "consideration set" which influences the choice of an alternative given the choice set of interest.
Abstract: In designing choice experiments, it is common to present a number of alternatives to a respondent and have them choose the most preferred alternative. However, respondents may ignore one or more alternatives which they deem unacceptable for various reasons. This possibility aligns with the idea of the ‘consideration set’ which influences the choice of an alternative given the choice set of interest. This paper uses an endogenous choice set model to investigate the influence that contextual effects and socioeconomic characteristics play in explaining variations in the choice sets considered by respondents when they reveal their preferences.

Summary (2 min read)

1. Introduction and Conceptual Context

  • Stated choice modelling focuses primarily on identifying the role of a set of attributes and attribute levels in establishing individual preference as an alternative/complementary approach to revealed preference modelling.
  • Regardless of what information is used to construct a choice set response, without such knowledge it is not possible to establish, from the full set of alternatives, which subset of alternatives are processed in making a preferred choice, and indeed in establishing a rank order for a behaviourally meaningful set of alternatives.
  • Asking whether an alternative is acceptable or not does not preclude the possibility that the alternative was actually considered when the final choice was made, and hence does not necessarily suggest that the alternative should be assigned a zero choice probability.
  • The attribute descriptions of each elemental alternative are embedded in the CCSPS model together with explanatory variables designed to capture process heuristics such as extremeness aversion and to identify other possible ways in which the attribute levels are processed in establishing the acceptability of particular alternatives in defining a CCSPS.

2. Conceptual Positioning of the Proposed Acceptability Approach

  • Hensher and Louviere (1983), in one of the very earliest choice experiments, show that an ‘ideal’ choice experiment is defined as one in which “… the basic elements of the choice process are abstracted and everything is controlled to permit unbiased estimates of choice strengths and choice probabilities.” (p.228).
  • For such popular choice experiments, when the authors only know which alternative is chosen (or the full ranking of the alternatives), the choice of an alternative is by implication conditional on the full set of potential availability choice sets as defined by the statistical design.
  • In total, seven candidate choice sets, each with a minimum of one acceptable alternative, can be defined and one of these candidate choice sets is considered by the respondent when they reveal their preference.
  • The authors use a random parameter with error components model to take account of preference heterogeneity (through random parameters) as well as the correlated errors due to the presence of common elemental alternative across the choice sets (through error components).
  • The model may approximate a covariance structures in a more accurate way than the typical nested logit model by forming complex covariance structures between alternatives.

3. Testing Choice Set Formation - The Empirical Illustration

  • The authors use a data set collected in Sydney in 2012 that focussed on investigating commuters’ preferences for a number of alternative road pricing reform packages.
  • After these choice responses, they were asked to indicate whether each of the three alternatives is acceptable or not acceptable.
  • Given that the empirical topic is road pricing reform (involving cordon-based and distancebased charging), there is likely to be a wide range of awareness (or lack thereof) within a sampled population.
  • The data includes personal income, age and gender.

4. Model Results

  • To estimate the endogenous choice set model of three alternatives, the authors need to create multiple elemental alternatives (one for each candidate choice set processing strategy or CCSPS) from each alternative shown to the respondent.
  • Thus, the observed utilities of elemental alternatives differ by either the CCSPS component (same initial alternative in different candidate choice sets) or the alternative component (different alternatives in the same nest).
  • At the elemental alternative level, the authors find that all of the pricing and cost attributes are statistically significant, as are three of the revenue allocation plans (namely allocation to public transport, roads, and reduced income tax relative to being contributed to general government revenue and to compensate toll road operators).
  • This suggests, for example, that a 10 percent increase in the range of the offered costs, ceteris paribus, will produce a 2.0 percent decrease in the probability of a respondent choosing the cordon-based charging scheme in a choice set where the acceptable alternatives are the cordon-based charge and a distance-based charge.

5. Conclusions

  • The objective of this paper is to show how additional information on the perceived acceptability of an alternative, aligned with the literature on consideration sets, can be used to inform the relevance of specific choice sets that respondents find acceptable (up to a probability), given an imposed or offered set in a stated choice experiment.
  • The authors use a random utility maximisation mixed logit error components model to consider the role of contextdependency, amongst other possible effects, in influencing the acceptable alternatives processed by the respondent.
  • The empirical study which analyses the level of support for road pricing reform from car commuters, illustrates how researchers can take the imposed set of alternatives offered in a stated choice experiment, and use an acceptability response as a candidate choice set processing strategy to identify which set of alternatives are processed as the considered choice set.
  • The authors found that accounting for the consideration sets of alternatives (akin to choice set generation) results in varying sensitivities to changes in attribute levels which differ from the findings when the choice of choice sets is not taken into account.
  • What the authors have is a potentially important additional candidate criterion for segmenting markets just like they do with trip purpose, time of day, income, trip length and the like.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

1
The role of perceived acceptability of alternatives in identifying and assessing choice set
processing strategies in stated choice settings: the case of road pricing reform
David A. Hensher
Chinh Ho
Institute of Transport and Logistics Studies
The University of Sydney business School
The University of Sydney NSW Australia
David.Hensher@sydney.edu.au
Chinh.Ho@sydney.edu.au
Version: 1 July 2015 (revised 24 August 2015) accepted 29 September 2015
To appear in Transportation Research Part E
Abstract
In designing choice experiments, it is common to present a number of alternatives to a
respondent and have them choose the most preferred alternative. However, respondents may
ignore one or more alternatives which they deem unacceptable for various reasons. This
possibility aligns with the idea of the ‘consideration set’ which influences the choice of an
alternative given the choice set of interest. This paper uses an endogenous choice set model to
investigate the influence that contextual effects and socioeconomic characteristics play in
explaining variations in the choice sets considered by respondents when they reveal their
preferences.
Keywords choice of choice sets, processing strategies, acceptable alternatives, random
parameters, stated choice, road pricing, elasticities.
Acknowledgment The research contribution is linked to an Australian Research Council grant DP140100909
(2014-2016) on ‘Integrating Attribute Decision Heuristics into Travel Choice Models that accommodate Risk
Attitude and Perceptual Conditioning’. The comments of Bill Greene are appreciated as are the very useful
comments of four referees and the editor-in-chief Jiuh-Biing Sheu on various versions of this paper.

2
1. Introduction and Conceptual Context
Stated choice modelling focuses primarily on identifying the role of a set of attributes and
attribute levels in establishing individual preference as an alternative/complementary
approach to revealed preference modelling. In stated preference studies, a choice experiment
is designed to ensure that the combinations of attribute levels that describe alternatives are
optimal in a statistical sense; however, the number of alternatives is usually pre-defined in
stated choice experiment and this carries forward to the modelling stage without sufficient
consideration of the behavioural implications of the relevant choice set. Typically, the
number of alternatives presented in a choice experiment (i.e., the size of the choice set) is
fixed and individuals are asked to choose the best alternative amongst this set of alternatives
or to rank the full set as if all alternatives are relevant. This includes experiments where the
number of alternatives is varied across choice scenarios or across respondents but fixed
within each choice scenario for each respondent.
In contrast to this common practice in stated choice modelling, respondents may not consider
some alternatives imposed in a choice task, and thus assuming all designed alternatives are
relevant to each respondent may not reflect the way in which respondents process the
information and reveal their preference. This paper proposes the use of an additional response
question related to the perceived acceptability of each alternative on offer in establishing
individual preference. This approach is along similar lines of supplementary questions that
reveal the extent to which specific attributes are attended to or not in attribute processing (see
e.g., Hensher 2010, 2014). The inclusion of the acceptability of an alternative in choice
models is effectively an additional endogenous choice response (Hess et al. (in progress) and
Rose et al. (2015)). Most importantly, the acceptability of each alternative provides a
response metric that can guide us in establishing the subset of alternatives that matter in
narrowing down the preferred alternative. This is known as the ‘choice of choice sets’
problem (as mentioned by Louviere and Hensher in 1983) and is typically neglected in choice
modelling. Regardless of what information is used to construct a choice set response, without
such knowledge it is not possible to establish, from the full set of alternatives, which subset
of alternatives are processed in making a preferred choice, and indeed in establishing a rank
order for a behaviourally meaningful set of alternatives. The small but growing literature on
the perceived acceptability of each alternative posits that when making decisions, people first
identify an acceptable set of alternatives, known as a consideration set in the broader
literature (especially in marketing research), and it is from this reduced set that the final
choice is made1. This is also in line with the literature on choice set formation set out in the
context of revealed preference data (see Manski 1977 and Swait and Ben Akiva 1987).
Despite frequent mention of these features of choice modelling, the great majority of applied
choice modelling (using stated choice data in particular) ignores this stage of the choice
making process. This might suggest that there is a view that modelling choices with
endogenous choice set is either too difficult or that it has little significance in the
determination of the choice outcomes of interest. Evidence from a recent study by Rose et al.
1
In stated choice studies which impose a set of alternatives it is normal practice to ask which alternative is
preferred. What we have done however is to proceed with that question but to add in the addition question to
identify which alternatives in the set are acceptable. We could have asked these questions in the reverse order
but did not do so, and although the reverse order might be interesting, we are of the view that the responses for
only three alternatives are likely to be the same (at least for the majority of respondents). A sequence test is a
good topic for future research.

3
(2015) rejects the latter explanation. Using an acceptability response to define choice sets of
interest, Rose et al. find a large number of differences between parameters associated with
the alternatives deemed to be acceptable and those deemed to be unacceptable by the
respondent. They show that joint estimation allows the modeller to overcome potential
endogeneity bias that may exist between the final choice made and the acceptability
responses, where the latter conditions the relevance of an alternative. The authors also
conclude that what might be thought of as preference heterogeneity may be linked to the
overall acceptability of an alternative.
What concerns us in the contribution of Rose et al. (2015) is that the acceptability of each
alternative is combined with its rank order to define the set of elemental alternatives for
jointly estimating alternative acceptability and choice. This modelling technique does not
account for the role that choice set formation plays in arriving at the selection of an
alternative. This paper focuses on the higher level of choice set formation which conditions
the lower level in a ‘nested’ structure of choosing a particular alternative. It differs from the
choice set generation methods proposed by authors such as Ben Akiva and Boccara (1995) in
that we treat the choice of choice sets as integral to the overall utility maximising framework
and not a conditioning set of exogenous rules.
2
The approach presented in this paper differs from previous contributions in that we use the
responses on the acceptability of each alternative to identify a choice set considered by the
respondent and formulate a model to predict both responses: the subset of alternatives
considered and the final choice. From a choice task of J alternatives imposed on the
respondent, we may construct up to 2
J
subsets of alternatives with different combinations of
acceptable alternatives. These subsets are referred to as outcomes of candidate choice set
processing strategies (CCSPSs), and only one of these subsets is considered by the
respondent when they make their final choice. This is in line with the idea of consideration
sets.
3
Previous studies combined each alternative on offer with an acceptability response in
defining a universal choice set and estimating parameters which can be generic or specific
across an acceptability/certainty scale. These studies are interested in establishing different
sets of parameters for different levels of acceptability/certainty, assuming the relevance of all
alternatives offered in the experiment. In contrast, the current paper focuses on likely reasons
for each imposed alternative being processed (up to a probability) where the sub-set of
alternatives together with the alternative itself defines a choice response. The growing
literature on process heuristics offers up many possible explanations for choice set selection,
but one of particular interest in the context of choice experiments is the application of
context-dependent heuristics such as extremeness aversion and compromise (proposed by
Simonson and Tversky (1992) and Tversky and Simonson (1993)), that take into account the
variations in attribute levels across a set of alternatives predefined in a choice experiment
(Hensher 2014). Such context-dependent heuristics are an important feature of the empirical
2
We are not able to conclude that our joint approach is empirically better than approaches in which exogenous
rules are imposed to define eligible alternatives in choice set generation, but it has the appeal of being more
general than approaches which select a few criteria to screen alternatives.
3
Another way of including the acceptability of an alternative at the time of modelling is to assign a zero
probability to alternatives that have been deemed to be out of the acceptable consideration set (Gilbride and
Allenby 2004, Horowitz and Louviere 1995). However, asking whether an alternative is acceptable or not does
not preclude the possibility that the alternative was actually considered when the final choice was made, and
hence does not necessarily suggest that the alternative should be assigned a zero choice probability. Although, if
at least one other alternative is deemed to be acceptable, then any unacceptable alternative would be expected to
have a probability close to zero, and its treatment as outside of the final choice set has greater behavioural merit
than maintaining its presence.

4
inquiry into some rules that might be adopted in ‘screening’ hypothetical alternatives,
especially in the context of a reference or status quo alternative that reflects real market
experience. We examine these possible processing rules through innovative ways of
introducing attributes into the utility expression of each ‘alternative’ as defined by a choice
set, such as the attribute range across the alternatives in a choice set.
Extremeness aversion or the compromise effect can be explained as follows. If an extreme
alternative is defined as one with both the best value on a subset of attributes, and the worst
value on other attributes, then a specific form of extremeness aversion known as the
compromise effect is said to occur (see also Leong and Hensher 2015). That is, the inclusion
of an extreme alternative in the choice set causes the pair-wise choice share of the
compromise or the in-between alternative to increase, relative to the other extreme
alternative.
4
It is also normally supposed that a “betweenness inequality” holds in choice
making, in which the middle alternative (for example, in a three alternative choice set) loses
relatively more than an existing extreme alternative when another extreme alternative is
introduced (Tversky and Simonson 1993). Under this condition, the compromise effect can
be seen as a violation of the betweenness inequality and its existence is generally attributed to
a consequence of loss-aversive behaviour (Kivetz et al. 2004, 2008). There is a hint here of
the nature of acceptability of an alternative in preference revelation and the refinement of
choice set selection. The statistical design of choice experiments does not account for the
possible set of underlying behavioural processing strategies that respondents adopt in choice
revelation, something that has to be taken into account in modelling.
Given the interest in incorporating the endogenous acceptability response into choice models,
we assess model options within the random utility maximisation (RUM) framework. A
number of models have been developed at the alternative-level, allowing for the estimation of
non-random parameters or random parameters. Candidate methods of interest are mixed logit
and latent class models. The latent class model offers a framework within which to
investigate many forms of attribute processing (Hensher 2010); however, the latent class
approach is limiting when the focus is on understanding the role of specific alternatives in
establishing acceptable choice sets. This is because it is not feasible to associate latent classes
in a behaviourally meaningful way with combinations of alternatives that define potential
choice sets considered by the respondent. In order to give some behavioural structure to each
class (similar to imposing constraints of attributes in specific classes), this model form would
have to be interpreted as a probabilistic decision process (see Hensher 2014). Given all
possible candidate choice sets (or classes), we are interested in estimating the probability that
each of the candidate choice sets is adopted (i.e., the class assignment probability) as opposed
to treating the consideration set as known (i.e., probability =1) and the probability that each
of the alternatives is ranked as most preferred given the class they belong to (conditional
alternative probability). To do so, we would have to specify a latent class model with a
number of restrictions based on the presence or absence of an alternative in each candidate
choice set. This model will result in a singular variance matrix of parameters, as might be
expected, since it involves an exact mapping of the restrictions imposed on the utility
function of the same alternative that belongs to multiple candidate choice sets. A more
appealing way to do this is a standard random (or fixed) parameter logit model with error
components applied in this paper in which the error components are used to capture the
correlation across overlapping choice sets (i.e., subsets with common alternatives).
4
This notion of “extremeness” might be distinguished from “dominating/dominated” alternatives, in which all
attributes of an alternative are better/worse than a competing alternative.

5
The CCSPS approach proposed in this paper enables efficient implementation of RUM for
any choice set size since the emphasis at the upper level of the decision structure is on the
choice of CCSPSs, and not of alternatives; however this is jointly estimated with the choice
of best elemental alternative amongst those imposed in the experiment. The attribute
descriptions of each elemental alternative are embedded in the CCSPS model together with
explanatory variables designed to capture process heuristics such as extremeness aversion
and to identify other possible ways in which the attribute levels are processed in establishing
the acceptability of particular alternatives in defining a CCSPS. Examples are the range,
maximum and minimum levels and deviation of levels from the best or worst level of an
attribute across the full set of alternatives on offer, and the set deemed acceptable. Such an
approach (aligned with context dependency) is a way of identifying the role of particular
attribute processing strategies within and between alternatives in defining choices sets for
subsequent model estimation.
The paper is organised as follows. We begin with the conceptual positioning of the proposed
acceptability approach, followed by the context in which we empirically develop the CCSPS
model. We then present the model findings, followed by an assessment of the main
behavioural outputs. The paper concludes with the main findings and suggestions for ongoing
research.
2. Conceptual Positioning of the Proposed Acceptability Approach
Hensher and Louviere (1983), in one of the very earliest choice experiments, show that an
‘ideal’ choice experiment is defined as one in which “… the basic elements of the choice
process are abstracted and everything is controlled to permit unbiased estimates of choice
strengths and choice probabilities.” (p.228). Such an experiment would normally consist of a
set of J alternatives (j=1,2,…,J) and different subsets of these J alternatives which simulate
“availability” (although not strictly acceptability) or variance in choice sets. To ensure that
the choice of alternatives is independent of the presence or absence of alternatives in choice
sets (a condition satisfied when all alternatives appear equally often) and are also balanced
with respect to the presence and absence of all other alternatives, we would need to design
the choice experiment to satisfy this condition. A complete factorial design is likely to be too
large, but a 2
J
fractional factorial design can ensure a balanced occurrence of the
presence/absence of alternatives in choice sets.
A choice set designed under these conditions will be one of all universal finite choice sets
where each alternative appears equally often, 2
J
/2 or 2
J-1
times, and each other alternative
occurs 2
J-1
/2 or 2
J-2
times when each other alternative occurs (or does not occur). Each
individual is likely to have a different rank ordering of the alternatives which results in a
distribution of choices over any sample of individuals. This distribution is assumed to be
explained by the utility version of Luce’s choice axiom (McFadden 1974). A discrete choice
model that is estimated on such data will obtain a distribution of choice probabilities
associated with each choice set that sum to 1.0 across all choice sets for an individual.
Although the theoretical and methodological merits of such a design that is capable of
studying the ‘choice of choice sets’ are appealing, the design of the great majority of choice
experiments typically results in a fixed choice set or partial structuring of alternatives which
not only induces correlation across offered choice sets (the latter is not a concern when

Citations
More filters
Posted Content
01 Jan 2003
TL;DR: In this article, the authors proposed four context-dependent choice models that can conceptually capture the compromise effect, which is the finding that brands gain share when they become the intermediate rather than an extreme option in a choice set (Simonson 1989). Despite the robustness and importance of this phenomenon, choice modelers have neglected to incorporate the compromising effect within formal choice models and to test whether such models outperform the standard value maximization model.
Abstract: The compromise effect denotes the finding that brands gain share when they become the intermediate rather than an extreme option in a choice set (Simonson 1989). Despite the robustness and importance of this phenomenon, choice modelers have neglected to incorporate the compromise effect within formal choice models and to test whether such models outperform the standard value maximization model. In this article, we suggest four context-dependent choice models that can conceptually capture the compromise effect. Although these models are motivated by theory from economics and behavioral decision research, they differ with respect to the particular mechanism that underlies the compromise effect (e.g., contextual concavity vs. loss aversion). Using two empirical applications, we (1) contrast the alternative models and show that incorporating the compromise effect by modeling the local choice context leads to superior predictions and fit relative to the traditional value maximization model and a stronger (naive) model that adjusts for possible biases in utility measurement; (2) generalize the compromise effect by demonstrating that it systematically affects choice in larger sets of products and attributes than previously shown; (3) show the theoretical and empirical equivalence of loss aversion and local (contextual) concavity; and (4) demonstrate the superiority of models that use a single reference point over "tournament models" in which each option serves as a reference point. We discuss the theoretical and practical implications of this research, as well as the ability of the proposed models to predict other behavioral context effects.

21 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the distribution of predicted choice probabilities associated with a set of alternatives defining a given choice set might provide strong evidence on the strategies that agents appear to use when choosing a preferred alternative.
Abstract: Stated choice experiments are designed optimally in a statistical sense but not necessarily in a behavioural choice making sense Statistical designs, and consequently model estimation, assume that the set of alternatives offered in the experiment are processed by respondents with a specific processing strategy Much has been studied about attribute processing using discrete choice methods in travel choice studies, but this paper focuses more broadly on processing of alternatives in the choice set offered in the experiment This paper is motivated by the primary idea that the distribution of predicted choice probabilities associated with a set of alternatives defining a given choice set might provide strong evidence on the strategies that agents appear to use when choosing a preferred alternative In an empirical setting of a choice set of size three, four model specifications are considered including a model for the selection of the best alternative in the full choice set and three variants of a best–worst regime Using state choice data on road pricing reform, the empirical analysis examines which model specification delivers the most accurate prediction of the chosen alternative The results suggest which alternatives really matter in choice making and hence the alternatives that might be included in a choice set for model specification

13 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors developed a model capable of evaluating the societal impact of rail infrastructure investment in Argentina, using a Multiple Discrete Extreme Value Model (MDCEV) estimated on Stated and Revealed preference data.
Abstract: The main objective of the paper is to develop a model capable of evaluating the societal impact of rail infrastructure investment in Argentina, using a Multiple Discrete Extreme Value Model (MDCEV) estimated on Stated and Revealed preference data. The decision modelled is the mode and port choice at a planning level, where multiple alternatives can be chosen simultaneously. The relevant variables were the Free Alongside Ship (FAS) price, freight transport cost, travel time and lead time, including non-observed heterogeneity in the modelling. As a consequence, the willingness to pay measures that are used for the cost benefit analysis become non-deterministic. To include this effect simulated WTP measurements were included and compared to a deterministic and risk based approach. Two projects were tested and both showed that the deterministic approach gives higher Benefit/Cost ratio. This paper raises the concern that if non-observed heterogeneity is not considered in project evaluation it may provide misleading results and potentially lead to wrong investment priorities for the public sector.

10 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors investigate the role consideration of the alternatives plays in mode choice models and propose two model specifications, in which consideration for the slower alternatives is measured using both sets of supplementary questions, are proposed and contrasted against a model which assumes all alternatives are considered.
Abstract: In this paper, we investigate the role consideration of the alternatives plays in mode choice models. On the Rome-Milan corridor, in Italy, where seven alternative modes of transport are available, we administered a stated choice (SC) experiment. Responses to supplementary questions on consideration of the different modes of transport and the presence of thresholds for the travel time attribute indicate travellers are less likely to consider the slower modes. Two model specifications, in which consideration for the slower alternatives is measured using both sets of supplementary questions, are proposed and contrasted against a model which assumes all alternatives are considered. Our results suggests that some of the unobserved preference heterogeneity could potentially be due to consideration effects. Accounting for consideration of alternatives also has direct impacts on choice probabilities, parameter estimates and willingness-to-pay measures.

7 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors discuss a number of ways of gaining an increased understanding of behavioural response and discuss a thought piece in line with the role played as a plenary presentation at the Travel Survey Methods Conference.
Abstract: The study of traveller behaviour has blossomed into a multi-disciplinary array of theories, methods and data paradigms aimed at improving our understanding of drivers of passenger and freight movement. While progress continues unabated, there remains the challenge of extracting more behavioural richness out of the way in which we work to understand the nuances of preference revelation and hence choice making. In this paper we discuss a number of ways of gaining an increased understanding of behavioural response. The paper is a thought piece in line with the role played as a plenary presentation at the Travel Survey Methods Conference.

7 citations


Cites background or result from "The role of perceived acceptability..."

  • ...…used by the respondents in revealing their preferences, there has been a limited amount of inquiry into the overall relevance of imposed alternatives in stated choice studies in contrast to the literature on choice set formation, especially in revealed preference studies (Hensher and Ho 2015)....

    [...]

  • ...Hensher and Ho (2015) investigate the relationship between the attribute levels associated with an alternative offered in a choice experiment and the construction of a respondent’s choice set based on the alternatives considered through the acceptability response dummy variable....

    [...]

References
More filters
01 Jan 1972

15,741 citations


"The role of perceived acceptability..." refers background in this paper

  • ...This distribution is assumed to be explained by the utility version of Luce’s choice axiom (McFadden 1974)....

    [...]

Book
01 Jan 2003
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors describe the new generation of discrete choice methods, focusing on the many advances that are made possible by simulation, and compare simulation-assisted estimation procedures, including maximum simulated likelihood, method of simulated moments, and methods of simulated scores.
Abstract: This book describes the new generation of discrete choice methods, focusing on the many advances that are made possible by simulation. Researchers use these statistical methods to examine the choices that consumers, households, firms, and other agents make. Each of the major models is covered: logit, generalized extreme value, or GEV (including nested and cross-nested logits), probit, and mixed logit, plus a variety of specifications that build on these basics. Simulation-assisted estimation procedures are investigated and compared, including maximum simulated likelihood, method of simulated moments, and method of simulated scores. Procedures for drawing from densities are described, including variance reduction techniques such as anithetics and Halton draws. Recent advances in Bayesian procedures are explored, including the use of the Metropolis-Hastings algorithm and its variant Gibbs sampling. No other book incorporates all these fields, which have arisen in the past 20 years. The procedures are applicable in many fields, including energy, transportation, environmental studies, health, labor, and marketing.

7,768 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors discuss the benefits of the U.S. Department of Transportation's grant DOT-OS-4006 for the development of a train-to-vehicle communication system.
Abstract: I am grateful to Joseph B. Kadane for numerous constructive suggestions offered during discussions of this research. The financial sponsorship of the U.S. Department of Transportation through grant DOT-OS-4006 is also acknowledged. The opinions and conclusions expressed herein are solely those of the author.

1,682 citations


"The role of perceived acceptability..." refers result in this paper

  • ...This is also in line with the literature on choice set formation set out in the context of revealed preference data (see Manski 1977 and Swait and Ben Akiva 1987)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, two hypotheses about the effect of context on choice are proposed, one hypothesis is that consumer choice is often influenced by the context, defined by the set of alternatives under consideration.
Abstract: Consumer choice is often influenced by the context, defined by the set of alternatives under consideration. Two hypotheses about the effect of context on choice are proposed. The first hypothesis, ...

1,461 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors present a context-dependent model that expresses the value of each option as an additive combination of two components: a contingent weighting process that captures the effect of the background context, and a binary comparison process that describes the local context.
Abstract: The standard theory of choice—based on value maximization—associates with each option a real value such that, given an offered set, the decision maker chooses the option with the highest value. Despite its simplicity and intuitive appeal, there is a growing body of data that is inconsistent with this theory. In particular, the relative attractiveness of x compared to y often depends on the presence or absence of a third option z, and the “market share” of an option can actually be increased by enlarging the offered set. We review recent empirical findings that are inconsistent with value maximization, and present a context-dependent model that expresses the value of each option as an additive combination of two components: a contingent weighting process that captures the effect of the background context, and a binary comparison process that describes the effect of the local context. The model accounts for observed violations of the standard theory and provides a framework for analyzing context-dependent p...

1,281 citations


"The role of perceived acceptability..." refers background in this paper

  • ...…is also normally supposed that a “betweenness inequality” holds in choice making, in which the middle alternative (for example, in a three alternative choice set) loses relatively more than an existing extreme alternative when another extreme alternative is introduced (Tversky and Simonson 1993)....

    [...]

  • ...…is the application of context-dependent heuristics such as extremeness aversion and compromise (proposed by Simonson and Tversky (1992) and Tversky and Simonson (1993)), that take into account the variations in attribute levels across a set of alternatives predefined in a choice…...

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (11)
Q1. What are the contributions in "The role of perceived acceptability of alternatives in identifying and assessing choice set processing strategies in stated choice settings: the case of road pricing reform" ?

This paper uses an endogenous choice set model to investigate the influence that contextual effects and socioeconomic characteristics play in explaining variations in the choice sets considered by respondents when they reveal their preferences. 

Stated choice modelling focuses primarily on identifying the role of a set of attributes and attribute levels in establishing individual preference as an alternative/complementary approach to revealed preference modelling. 

The evidence suggests that the attribute dimensionality across the choice sets and within choice sets (i.e., the context-dependent effects) has a statistically significant role in sanitising the full choice set offered. 

In the choice set in which CB and DB are acceptable this becomes a positive effect, with a 1 percent increase in personal income resulting in a 0.80 and 0.87 increase in the probability of choosing the CB and DB alternatives respectively. 

A behaviourally more informative way of presenting the findings is through a set of direct elasticities which indicate the impact of a unit change in the level of an attribute on the probability of choosing a particular alternative conditional on a CCSPS and the probability of choosing a CCSPS (i.e., ∂lnPin/∂lnxikn). 

If as a consequence of road pricing reform, for example, the authors find that the behavioural responses identified through direct elasticities for specific attributes vary across subsets of alternatives that define the choice making set, then this suggests that there are segmentation effects (or heterogeneous responses conditioned on relevant choice sets) that should be recognised, and the evidence herein hints that this does make a difference to the overall behavioural response (once the incidence of membership of each segment is known). 

The suggestion in a growing number of studies, cited above, that a respondent’s perception of the acceptability of an alternative might be a way forward to narrow down the subset of alternatives that define the domain in which the probability of choosing an alternative is maximised, has merit and is worthy of further consideration. 

The authors examine these possible processing rules through innovative ways of introducing attributes into the utility expression of each ‘alternative’ as defined by a choice set, such as the attribute range across the alternatives in a choice set. 

A suite of elasticities offer behaviourally rich evidence on the sensitivity of behavioural responses to changing attribute levels when account is taken of the probability of subsets of alternatives being chosen in eliciting preferences for specific alternatives, given the acceptability or otherwise on each alternative in the full set of fixed offered alternatives common in stated choice experiments. 

Another way of including the acceptability of an alternative at the time of modelling is to assign a zero probability to alternatives that have been deemed to be out of the acceptable consideration set (Gilbride and Allenby 2004, Horowitz and Louviere 1995). 

In the choice set in which all alternatives are acceptable, the authors see a 1.9 percent increase in the probability of a respondent choosing the cordon-based charging scheme; however this increases to 5.3 percent where the only acceptable alternative is the cordon-based charge (CCSPS3).