scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

What are the effects of monetary policy on output? Results from an agnostic identification procedure

01 Mar 2005-Journal of Monetary Economics (Elsevier)-Vol. 52, Iss: 2, pp 381-419
TL;DR: The authors proposed to estimate the effects of monetary policy shocks by a new agnostic method, imposing sign restrictions on the impulse responses of prices, nonborrowed reserves and the federal funds rate in response to a monetary policy shock.
About: This article is published in Journal of Monetary Economics.The article was published on 2005-03-01 and is currently open access. It has received 2058 citations till now. The article focuses on the topics: Credit channel & Monetary hegemony.

Summary (3 min read)

1 Introduction

  • In summary, this literature indeed reinforces the view emerging from the first simple look at the data as in figure 1.
  • While theories with different implications can fairly easily be constructed, these assumptions may enjoy broad support and in any case, are usually tacitly assumed in most of the VAR literature: their aim is to bring them directly out into the open and to make them subject to debate.
  • When imposing the sign restrictions, one needs to take a stand on for how long these restrictions ought to hold after a shock.
  • “Contractionary” monetary policy shocks have an ambiguous effect on real GDP.

2 The Method

  • There is not much disagreement about how to estimate5 VARs.
  • The disagreement starts when discussing, how to decompose the prediction error ut into economically meaningful or “fundamental” innovations.
  • Define the monetary policy impulse vector as that impulse vector a, which minimizes the total penalty Ψ(a) for prices, nonborrowed reserves and (after flipping signs) the federal funds rate at horizons k = 0, . . . , K, Ψ(a) = ∑ j∈ “GDP Deflator”, “Comm. Price Index”, “Nonborr. Reserves” “Federal Funds Rate”.
  • As a drawback, the pure-sign-restriction is, in effect, simultaneously an estimation of the reduced-form VAR alongside the impulse vector: VAR parameter draws, which do not permit any impulse vector to satisfy the imposed sign restrictions, are discarded as “impossible”.

3 Results

  • The authors present some results, using their method.
  • The authors have employed the data set used in Bernanke and Mihov (1996a,b), which contains the GDP, the GDP deflator, a commodity price index, total reserves, nonborrowed reserves and the federal funds rate for the U.S. at monthly frequencies from January 1965 to December 1996.
  • Here, the authors identify the monetary policy shock with the innovations in the Federal Funds Rate ordered last.
  • The results are fairly “reasonable” in that they confirm conventional undergraduate textbook intuition.
  • Without a good defense of the timing implicit in the particular Cholesky decomposition employed, the results of figure 2 may thus be tainted by the specification search described in the introduction.

3.1 Results for the pure-sign-restriction approach.

  • I.e., the responses of the GDP price deflator, the commodity price index and nonborrowed reserves have been restricted not to be positive and the federal funds rate not to be negative for the six months k, k = 0, . . . , 5 following the shock.
  • The results can be described as follows: 8A number of authors prefer two standard deviation bands, which would correspond to the 2.3% and the 97.7% quantiles.
  • After one to two years, a reversal sets in with reserves eventually expanding by around 0.4 percent.
  • The answer to the opening question is: the effects of monetary policy shocks on real output are ambiguous.

3.2 Results from the penalty-function approach.

  • Figures 5 and 6 provide the same results, now using the penalty-function approach rather than the pure-sign-restriction approach.
  • The magnitudes are slightly larger, and the confidence bands somewhat sharper, in particular immediately after the shock, compared to the pure-sign restriction approach.
  • While the pure-sign-restriction approach is very agnostic about the size of the impulse response away from the sign restriction, a larger responses is “rewarded” by the penalty-function approach at least as long as this does not generate sign-violations elsewhere.
  • Instead of a range of impulse vectors consistent with the sign restriction, the penalty function approach seeks a unique monetary policy impulse vector by searching e.g. for a large initial reaction of the Federal Funds Rate.
  • Indeed, this seems to be the case: the 64% range for the real GDP response, for example, never seems to venture outside the ±0.2 percent error band around zero calculated for the pure-sign-restriction approach.

3.3 How much variation do monetary policy shocks explain?

  • Having identified the monetary policy shock, it is then interesting to find out, how much of the variation these shocks explain.
  • These questions are answered by figure 7 for the benchmark experiment, i.e. using a pure sign restriction approach with a 6-months restriction (K=5).
  • The figure shows the fraction of the k−step ahead variance in the six variables explained by monetary policy shocks, with the variables ordered as in figure 3.
  • The remaining variations in prices and interest rates may still be due to monetary policy, but then it needs to be due to the endogenous part of monetary policy: by systematically responding to shocks elsewhere, monetary policy may end up being responsible for 100% of the movements in prices.
  • These results are rather similar to the results found in the empirical VAR literature so far, see the surveys cited in the introduction.

3.4 A summary.

  • The results could be paraphrased as a new Keynesian-new classical synthesis: even though the general price level is sticky for a period of about a year (see also Blinder, 1994), monetary policy has ambiguous real effects.
  • These observations largely confirm the results found in the empirical VAR literature so far, see in particular Leeper, Sims and Zha (1996), except for the ambiguity regarding the effect on output: this exception is, of course, a rather important difference.
  • The authors also agree with these authors that it makes sense that variation in monetary policy accounts only for a small fraction of the variation in any of these variables: good monetary policy should be predictable policy, and from that perspective, monetary policy in the US during this time span has been successful indeed.

4 The Volcker recessions, which weren’t.

  • In light of the well-known Lucas Critique (1976), one obviously needs to interpret the results with some caution.
  • Rounding up the other usual suspects is something which the authors have explicitely not focussed on in this exercise.
  • It is admittedly hard to also explain the large interest rate movements this way.
  • The authors believe that the analysis here supports a “not guilty” verdict for monetary policy shocks as a cause for the 1980 recession, in contrast to the conventional consensus view, also known as Whatever the truth.

5 Conclusions

  • This paper proposed to estimate the effects of monetary policy by a new “agnostic” method, imposing sign restrictions on the impulse responses of prices, nonborrowed reserves and the federal funds rate in response to a monetary policy shock.
  • Monetary policy shocks accounts for probably less than twentyfive percent of the k-step ahead prediction error variance of real output, and may easily account for less than three percent.
  • The commodity price index falls more quickly.
  • They account for about one third of the variation in prices at longer horizons.
  • While these observations confirm some of the results found in the empirical VAR literature so far, there are also some potentially important differences in particular with respect to their key question.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Figures (8)
Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, monetary policy and the private sector behavior of the US economy are modeled as a time varying structural vector autoregression, where the sources of time variation are both the coefficients and the variance covariance matrix of the innovations.
Abstract: Monetary policy and the private sector behavior of the US economy are modeled as a time varying structural vector autoregression, where the sources of time variation are both the coefficients and the variance covariance matrix of the innovations. The paper develops a new, simple modeling strategy for the law of motion of the variance covariance matrix and proposes an efficient Markov chain Monte Carlo algorithm for the model likelihood/posterior numerical evaluation. The main empirical conclusions are: 1) both systematic and non-systematic monetary policy have changed during the last forty years. In particular, systematic responses of the interest rate to inflation and unemployment exhibit a trend toward a more aggressive behavior, despite remarkable oscillations; 2) this has had a negligible effect on the rest of the economy. The role played by exogenous non-policy shocks seems more important than interest rate policy in explaining the high inflation and unemployment episodes in recent US economic history.

1,737 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors extend the standard new Keynesian model to allow for the presence of rule-of-thumb consumers and show how the interaction of the latter with sticky prices and deficit financing can account for the existing evidence on the effects of government spending.
Abstract: Recent evidence suggests that consumption rises in response to an increase in government spending. That finding cannot be easily reconciled with existing optimizing business cycle models. We extend the standard new Keynesian model to allow for the presence of rule-of-thumb consumers. We show how the interaction of the latter with sticky prices and deficit financing can account for the existing evidence on the effects of government spending. (JEL: E32, E62)

1,542 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the joint dynamics of bond yields and macroeconomic variables in a vector autoregression, where identifying restrictions are based on the absence of arbitrage, are described.
Abstract: This paper describes the joint dynamics of bond yields and macroeconomic variables in a vector autoregression, where identifying restrictions are based on the absence of arbitrage. Using a term structure model with inflation and economic growth factors, we investigate how macro factors affect bond prices and the dynamics of the yield curve. Higher order autoregressive lags and moving-average error terms for macro factors are accommodated. The macro factors are augmented by traditional unobserved term-structure factors. Models that incorporate macro factors give better forecasts than traditional term-structure models with only unobservable factors. Variance decompositions show that macro factors explain up to 30\% of the variation in bond yields. Macro factors primarily explain movements at the short end and middle of the yield curve while unobservable factors still account for most movement at the long end of the yield curve.

1,408 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the joint dynamics of bond yields and macroeconomic variables in a vector autoregression, where identifying restrictions are based on the absence of arbitrage, are described, and the forecasting performance of a VAR improves when no-arbitrage e restrictions are imposed.

1,215 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors developed a structural model of the global market for crude oil that for the first time explicitly allows for shocks to the speculative demand for oil as well as shocks to flow demand and flow supply.
Abstract: SUMMARY We develop a structural model of the global market for crude oil that for the first time explicitly allows for shocks to the speculative demand for oil as well as shocks to flow demand and flow supply. The speculative component of the real price of oil is identified with the help of data on oil inventories. Our estimates rule out explanations of the 2003–2008 oil price surge based on unexpectedly diminishing oil supplies and based on speculative trading. Instead, this surge was caused by unexpected increases in world oil consumption driven by the global business cycle. There is evidence, however, that speculative demand shifts played an important role during earlier oil price shock episodes including 1979, 1986 and 1990. Our analysis implies that additional regulation of oil markets would not have prevented the 2003–2008 oil price surge. We also show that, even after accounting for the role of inventories in smoothing oil consumption, our estimate of the short-run price elasticity of oil demand is much higher than traditional estimates from dynamic models that do not account for for the endogeneity of the price of oil. Copyright © 2013 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

1,156 citations


Cites background or methods from "What are the effects of monetary po..."

  • ...In August of 1990, the global production of crude oil from all                                                              13 For a similar point also see Canova and De Nicolo (2002), Uhlig (2005), and Canova and Paustian (2007)....

    [...]

  • ...…set of identifying restrictions and consistent estimates of the reduced-form VAR model, the construction of the set of admissible structural models follows the standard approach in the literature on VAR models identified based on sign restrictions (see, e.g., Canova and De Nicolo 2002; Uhlig 2005)....

    [...]

  • ...For a similar point also see Canova and De Nicolo (2002), Uhlig (2005) , and Canova and Paustian (2007)....

    [...]

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that the style in which their builders construct claims for a connection between these models and reality is inappropriate, to the point at which claims for identification in these models cannot be taken seriously.
Abstract: Existing strategies for econometric analysis related to macroeconomics are subject to a number of serious objections, some recently formulated, some old. These objections are summarized in this paper, and it is argued that taken together they make it unlikely that macroeconomic models are in fact over identified, as the existing statistical theory usually assumes. The implications of this conclusion are explored, and an example of econometric work in a non-standard style, taking account of the objections to the standard style, is presented. THE STUDY OF THE BUSINESS cycle, fluctuations in aggregate measures of economic activity and prices over periods from one to ten years or so, constitutes or motivates a large part of what we call macroeconomics. Most economists would agree that there are many macroeconomic variables whose cyclical fluctuations are of interest, and would agree further that fluctuations in these series are interrelated. It would seem to follow almost tautologically that statistical models involving large numbers of macroeconomic variables ought to be the arena within which macroeconomic theories confront reality and thereby each other. Instead, though large-scale statistical macroeconomic models exist and are by some criteria successful, a deep vein of skepticism about the value of these models runs through that part of the economics profession not actively engaged in constructing or using them. It is still rare for empirical research in macroeconomics to be planned and executed within the framework of one of the large models. In this lecture I intend to discuss some aspects of this situation, attempting both to offer some explanations and to suggest some means for improvement. I will argue that the style in which their builders construct claims for a connection between these models and reality-the style in which "identification" is achieved for these models-is inappropriate, to the point at which claims for identification in these models cannot be taken seriously. This is a venerable assertion; and there are some good old reasons for believing it;2 but there are also some reasons which have been more recently put forth. After developing the conclusion that the identification claimed for existing large-scale models is incredible, I will discuss what ought to be done in consequence. The line of argument is: large-scale models do perform useful forecasting and policy-analysis functions despite their incredible identification; the restrictions imposed in the usual style of identification are neither essential to constructing a model which can perform these functions nor innocuous; an alternative style of identification is available and practical. Finally we will look at some empirical work based on an alternative style of macroeconometrics. A six-variable dynamic system is estimated without using 1 Research for this paper was supported by NSF Grant Soc-76-02482. Lars Hansen executed the computations. The paper has benefited from comments by many people, especially Thomas J. Sargent

11,195 citations


"What are the effects of monetary po..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Thus, many researchers have followed the lead of Sims (1972,1980,1986) and proceeded to analyze the key question in the title with the aid of vector autoregressions....

    [...]

Book ChapterDOI
01 Jan 1995
TL;DR: There is wide agreement about the major goals of economic policy: high employment, stable prices, and rapid growth as discussed by the authors.There is less agreement that these goals are mutually compatible or, among those who regard them as incompatible, about the terms at which they can and should be substituted for one another.
Abstract: There is wide agreement about the major goals of economic policy: high employment, stable prices, and rapid growth. There is less agreement that these goals are mutually compatible or, among those who regard them as incompatible, about the terms at which they can and should be substituted for one another. There is least agreement about the role that various instruments of policy can and should play in achieving the several goals.

5,289 citations

Posted Content

3,101 citations


"What are the effects of monetary po..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Thus, many researchers have followed the lead of Sims (1972,1980,1986) and proceeded to analyze the key question in the title with the aid of vector autoregressions....

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (10)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "What are the effects of monetary policy on output? results from an agnostic identification procedure" ?

This paper proposes to estimate the effects of monetary policy shocks by a new “ agnostic ” method, imposing sign restrictions on the impulse responses of prices, nonborrowed reserves and the federal funds rate in response to a monetary policy shock. The authors provide a counterfactual analysis of the early 80 ’ s, setting the monetary policy shocks to zero after December 1979, and recalculating the data. 

Monetary policy shocks account for probably less than twentyfive percent of the k-step ahead prediction error variance of real output, and may easily account for less than three percent. 

The remaining variations in prices and interest rates may still be due to monetary policy, but then it needs to be due to the endogenous part of monetary policy: by systematically responding to shocks elsewhere, monetary policy may end up being responsible for 100% of the movements in prices. 

A one-standard deviation monetary policy shock may leave output unchanged or may drive output up or down by up to 0.2 percent in most cases, thus possibly triggering fairly sizeable movements of unknown sign. 

4. The Federal Funds Rate reacts large and positively immediately, typically rising by 30 basis points, then reversing course within a year, ultimately dropping by 10 basis points. 

The GDP price deflator reacts very sluggishly, with prices dropping by about 0.2 percent within a year, and dropping by 0.5 percent within five years. 

To identify the impulse vector corresponding to monetary policy shocks, the authors impose, that a contractionary policy shock does not lead to an increase in prices or in nonborrowed reserves and does not lead to a decrease in the federal funds rate. 

For interest rates, the largest fraction of variation explained by monetary policy is at the short horizon, providing further support to the view, that11monetary policy shocks are accidental errors by the Federal Reserve Bank, which are quickly reversed. 

As a drawback, the pure-sign-restriction is, in effect, simultaneously an estimation of the reduced-form VAR alongside the impulse vector: VAR parameter draws, which do not permit any impulse vector to satisfy the imposed sign restrictions, are discarded as “impossible”. 

a is an impulse vector if and only if there are coefficients αi, i = 1, . . . ,m with5∑m i=1 α 2 i = 1, so thata = m∑ i=1 ( αi √ λi ) xi (3)Given an impulse vector a, it is easy to calculate the appropriate impulse response, see appendix B for details. 

Trending Questions (1)
What are the effects of monetary policy on output?Results from an agnostic identification procedure?

The paper finds that "contractionary" monetary policy shocks have no clear effect on real GDP.