scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Journal ArticleDOI

Who bears the brunt? Distributional effects of climate change mitigation policies

16 Feb 2011-Critical Social Policy (Sage Publications)-Vol. 31, Iss: 2, pp 285-307
TL;DR: This article assess the claim that climate change policies have regressive effects by comparing different types of mitigation policies and argue that many of these are indeed likely to have a regressive distributional implications, but that there are several policy options to counteract these effects.
Abstract: Climate change scholars generally urge that CO2 emissions need to be cut rapidly if we are to avoid dangerous risks of climate change. However, climate change mitigation policies are widely perceived to have regressive effects – that is, putting a higher financial burden as a proportion of household income on poor than on rich households. This is one of several major barriers to the adoption of effective mitigation policies. They would also have considerable social justice implications requiring significant welfare state responses. We assess the claim that climate change policies have regressive effects by comparing different types of mitigation policies. We will argue that many of these are indeed likely to have regressive distributional implications but that there are several policy options to counteract regressive effects.

Summary (2 min read)

Introduction

  • There is long-standing interest in the distributional effects of climate change mitigation policies in the literatures on climate and energy policy, and economics.
  • The authors shall argue that the distributional effects of climate change mitigation policies will depend to a large extent on their exact design and on the area of emissions that they target (for example, emissions from home energy use as opposed to emissions from transport).
  • It needs to be stressed here that so-called ‘market-based’ climate change mitigation policies which define an overall cap on emissions for the economy (on any scale, e.g. nationally or globally) impose a strict ‘straitjacket’ on the market, in effect creating a highly regulated type of market.
  • The second section summarizes the findings regarding the distributional effects of different types of mitigation policies.

Types of mitigation policies

  • The two main alternative market-based tools are carbon taxes and cap and trade schemes which both put a price on energy use or greenhouse gas emissions in order to include ‘negative externalities’ resulting from economic activities (e.g. pollution) in the pricing mechanism.
  • Mitigation instruments can apply at different levels of economic activity: up-, mid- or downstream in the chain of production running from natural resource extraction down to the end user.
  • Within cap and trade schemes, several options exist as to how emission permits are allocated to the participants – all of which have different distributional impacts.
  • This approach is called ‘grandfathering’ in the literature.

Distributional effects

  • This expectation also carries through to various types of cap and trade schemes.
  • There is a general consensus that downstream taxses on home energy use are regressive if the revenue from those taxes or charges is not redistributed to the citizens (Baranzini et al., 2000; Barker and Köhler, 1998; Dresner and Ekins, 2006).
  • This means that low income households spend much higher shares of their income on home energy than richer households (Dresner and Ekins, 2006; Druckman and Jackson, 2008; Wier et al., 2005).
  • Several authors argue that environmental policies will be more effective if distributional aspects are dealt with separately (e.g. Johnstone and Serret, 2006: 5; Metcalf and Weisbach, 2009).
  • Studies using data from the United States report regressive effects of motoring taxes even if the whole population is included, because of high car dependency (Wadud et al., 2008; Walls and Hanson, 1999). at Freie Universitaet Berlin on April 24, 2015csp.sagepub.comDownloaded from.

Impact of methodological choices

  • The distributional effects of climate change mitigation policies presented in different studies also depend on several methodological choices, for example the type of measurement of distributional effects and whether or not behavioural responses are included in the model.
  • Behavioural models also estimate the distribution of financial burdens but include estimates of changes in people’s consumption behaviour in response to price increases.
  • In a Cap and Share or Cap and Dividend scheme, any individual who consumes less than the capped level of emissions will financially gain from the rebate/revenue (AEA and Cambridge Econometrics, 2008; Boyce and Riddle, 2007).
  • If poorer households gain more in absolute terms than richer households, the distributional effect will be strongly progressive in relative terms.

Socio-demographic factors

  • The previous section was confined to a consideration of the distributional effects of mitigation policies across income bands.
  • An analysis of distributional effects that only focuses on income groups disguises considerable variations of the distribution of burdens and benefits within income groups, because of such additional factors.
  • The trend towards smaller household sizes is therefore a driving factor behind increasing per capita emissions in many rich countries, particularly if indirect emissions are included (Druckman and Jackson, 2008: 3184).
  • So far, relatively few studies use multivariate regression analysis to examine the relative impact of different socio-economic factors (Baiocchi et al., 2010; Brand and Preston, 2010; DEFRA, 2008a; Lenzen et al., 2006; Weber and Matthews, 2008).

Conclusions

  • The literature exhibits a broad consensus that climate change mitigation policies usually have regressive effects in the absence of compensatory revenue recycling.
  • Study results also depend on methodological choices, such as the measure that is used to examine distributional effects and whether or not behavioural responses are included in the model.
  • Policy options of mitigating those effects need to be further investigated.
  • Of course, revenue can only arise from carbon reduction policies as long as there are emissions left that can be reduced – once net-emissions have reached zero, the revenue stream from those policies will run dry.

Did you find this useful? Give us your feedback

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

285
© The Author(s), 2011. Reprints and permissions: http://www.sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav
Critical Social Policy, 0261-0183 101; Vol. 31(2): 285–307; 396036 10.1177/0261018310396036
http://csp.sagepub.com
M I L E N A B Ü C H S
University of Southampton
N I C H O L A S B A R D S L E Y
University of Reading
S E B A S T I A N D U W E
Free University Berlin
Who bears the brunt? Distributional effects of climate
change mitigation policies
Abstract
Climate change scholars generally urge that CO
2
emissions need to be cut
rapidly if we are to avoid dangerous risks of climate change. However,
climate change mitigation policies are widely perceived to have regres-
sive effects – that is, putting a higher financial burden as a proportion of
household income on poor than on rich households. This is one of several
major barriers to the adoption of effective mitigation policies. They would
also have considerable social justice implications requiring significant
welfare state responses. We assess the claim that climate change policies
have regressive effects by comparing different types of mitigation poli-
cies. We will argue that many of these are indeed likely to have regressive
distributional implications but that there are several policy options to
counteract regressive effects.
Key words: emissions, environment, fairness, inequality, taxation
Introduction
There is long-standing interest in the distributional effects of climate
change mitigation policies in the literatures on climate and energy
policy, and economics. Hitherto, though, this debate has not impacted
much on mainstream social policy debates (however, see Gough et al.,
2008). This needs to change because climate policy will have an imme-
diate impact on social policy through various channels, in particular
at Freie Universitaet Berlin on April 24, 2015csp.sagepub.comDownloaded from

286 C R I T I C A L S O C I A L P O L I C Y 3 1 ( 2 )
redistribution effects. Those effects are important for two reasons. First
of all, they raise questions about fairness. For instance, how do the bur-
dens of climate change mitigation policy on citizens relate to household
income? Are such burdens proportional to the impact on the environ-
ment of different lifestyles? And how can climate change policies be
designed such that unjust distributional effects are avoided? Secondly,
the public acceptability of such policies will influence the likelihood
that governments adopt them. Little empirical research has been done
in this area so far but it seems plausible that the (perceived) fairness
of those policies will play an important role for public acceptability
(Bristow et al., 2010). The potential power of adverse public reactions
to policies is evident in the UK, for example, in the abandonment of the
poll tax and more recently the fuel tax escalator. This does not neces-
sarily imply that governments will adopt policies which are fairest and/
or most accepted by the broader public. Existing power asymmetries
in society and politics mean that governments frequently respond to
considerable pressure from corporate interests to adopt designs favour-
able to them as evidenced in relation to the European Union Emissions
Trading scheme (Michaelowa and Butzengeiger, 2005). However, the
fairness of climate change mitigation policies remains important from
a normative point of view and their public acceptability will be one
of several factors that governments take into account in the course
of policy-making as, for example, DEFRA’s recent research into the
public acceptability of a Personal Carbon Trading scheme illustrates
(DEFRA, 2008b).
This article
1
analyses arguments and evidence concerning regarding
the distributional impacts of a range of climate change mitigation poli-
cies. We will conclude that a range of currently debated and applied
economic policy tools to mitigate climate change are likely to have
regressive effects, meaning that households in lower income brackets
bear a (considerably) higher burden of the cost as a percentage of their
income than those in higher brackets.
However, we shall argue that the distributional effects of climate
change mitigation policies will depend to a large extent on their exact
design and on the area of emissions that they target (for example, emis-
sions from home energy use as opposed to emissions from transport).
As we are particularly interested in the question of how regressive
effects of emissions reduction policies can be avoided for reasons that
we explained above, we will compare different policy options that can
be used to mitigate or at least limit those effects.
at Freie Universitaet Berlin on April 24, 2015csp.sagepub.comDownloaded from

B Ü C H S E T A L . W H O B E A R S T H E B R U N T ? 287
This article focuses on ‘economic instruments rather than ‘pure’
regulation because they are generally regarded as more ‘efficient’ in
the literature on climate change mitigation (see section below). How-
ever, it needs to be stressed here that so-called ‘market-basedclimate
change mitigation policies which define an overall cap on emissions for
the economy (on any scale, e.g. nationally or globally) impose a strict
‘straitjacket’ on the market, in effect creating a highly regulated type of
market. This does not mean that there are no ethical concerns in rela-
tion to economic emission reduction instruments. One common point
of contention is that economic instruments put a price on a commons –
‘propertizing’ the earth’s atmosphere. Another is that some rich people
will be able to maintain their high carbon lifestyles as they are able to
pay a higher price for their consumption. However, within schemes that
set a strict overall cap on emissions this will not be possible for the gen-
erality of the rich. This is because the bulk of emission reductions would
need to be based on a cutback of their consumption, which is currently
responsible for the high emission levels of rich countries. In short, we
acknowledge considerable ethical concerns about, and potential short-
comings of, market-based mitigation policies. However, we find it
plausible that they form a part of any viable plan to avoid dangerous
climate change, since emissions cannot be regulated away overnight.
The first section of this article provides a brief overview of different
types of economic mitigation policies. The second section summarizes
the findings regarding the distributional effects of different types of
mitigation policies. Here we will focus on emission and energy taxes
and different types of cap and trade schemes. We will also discuss the
impact that different methodological choices have on study results. The
third section describes the different policy options for using revenues
stemming from mitigation policies, and their distributional effects.
The fourth section discusses the distributional impact of mitigation
policies across a wider range of socio-economic factors. The conclusion
summarizes the findings and identifies points for further discussion.
Types of mitigation policies
Mitigation policies can take a variety of forms, with different advan-
tages and disadvantages [...] from environmental, economic and distri-
butional perspectives. Generally, one can distinguish regulation, taxes
or charges, subsidies and trading schemes (Helm, 2005; OECD, 1994).
at Freie Universitaet Berlin on April 24, 2015csp.sagepub.comDownloaded from

288 C R I T I C A L S O C I A L P O L I C Y 3 1 ( 2 )
Regulatory instruments set legally binding emission, energy use or
efficiency targets which all addressees have to adhere to – or otherwise
face financial and possibly penal penalties. It is frequently argued that
regulation is less cost-efficient than market-based instruments because
it does not reflect differing abatement costs of the various polluters.
That is, it does not exploit the fact that some entities will be able to
make large emissions savings at relatively low cost whilst others will
find it very difficult and costly to adjust to lower emission targets.
This is one reason why economic instruments – which include vari-
ous regulatory aspects have gained prominence in the literature on
environmental policy.
2
These instruments essentially use price incen-
tives and market mechanisms to generate environmentally beneficial
behaviour.
The two main alternative market-based tools are carbon taxes and
cap and trade schemes which both put a price on energy use or green-
house gas emissions in order to include ‘negative externalities’ result-
ing from economic activities (e.g. pollution) in the pricing mechanism.
In theory, both schemes create financial incentives to switch to low-
impact lifestyles and production methods. The key difference between
the two is that environmental taxes in economics named ‘Pigovian
taxes’ establish a fixed price for environmentally damaging behav-
iours, whereas cap and trade fixes the amount of pollution by establish-
ing an emissions cap.
Environmental taxes are therefore believed to enhance economic
security, but at the expense of environmental security, because the
environmental improvement depends on actors’ responses to the tax.
The opposite holds true for cap and trade schemes which fix the maxi-
mum amount of pollution but let the market set the price. Consider
petrol for cars, for example. Both instruments would influence the price
of petrol. In the case of a tax, a fixed charge is added to the ‘regular’
price of every litre of petrol, whilst the additional cost under a cap and
trade scheme depends on the emissions cap and the overall demand for
petrol. With the cap it is certain that only the amount of petrol associ-
ated with the allowed pollution target is sold in the economy, whilst
the amount of petrol sold under a fuel or carbon tax may still increase
if consumers are prepared to pay a higher price.
Mitigation instruments can apply at different levels of economic
activity: up-, mid- or downstream in the chain of production running
from natural resource extraction down to the end user. An upstream
scheme would apply a tax or emissions cap to the production or import
at Freie Universitaet Berlin on April 24, 2015csp.sagepub.comDownloaded from

B Ü C H S E T A L . W H O B E A R S T H E B R U N T ? 289
of fossil fuels into the economy, thus achieving broadest coverage
whilst minimizing the number of actors included in the scheme and the
related administrative costs. Examples are the proposals for upstream
carbon taxes (Hansen, 2009), Cap and Dividend (Barnes, 2003), Cap
and Share (AEA and Cambridge Econometrics, 2008; FEASTA, 2008)
or the Kyoto2 scheme (Tickell, 2008). A mid-stream scheme would
apply to companies in specific economic sectors; the largest existing
cap scheme, the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS)
is an example. Downstream schemes apply to individuals, and in some
variants businesses, who would have carbon accounts and trade permits
themselves (DEFRA, 2008a; Fleming, 2007).
Within cap and trade schemes, several options exist as to how emis-
sion permits are allocated to the participants all of which have dif-
ferent distributional impacts. Initial emission budgets can be allocated
to the participants in the scheme free of charge, through auctioning,
or through a mix. For example, in the European Union Emissions
Trading Scheme (EU ETS), emission permits have largely been given
away for free to companies in the participating sectors, depending on
their previous and estimated future emissions. This approach is called
‘grandfathering’ in the literature. It is widely believed that this type
of ‘grandfathering’ leads to windfall profits for companies as they can
pass the additional costs on to customers or sell a considerable volume
of their allocated permits. In other words, ‘grandfathering’ is likely to
have regressive effects (Shammin and Bullard, 2009; Sijm et al., 2006).
In contrast, auctioning the permits makes the polluters pay whilst the
distributional effects depend on the capabilities of the targeted indus-
tries to pass on the cost to the consumer and the availability of alterna-
tives to these goods for consumers. Furthermore, auctioning emission
permits to the participants creates a revenue stream for the government
or organization that issues the permits. We will discuss below how
those revenues can be used to counter-balance possible regressive effects
of mitigation policies.
Distributional effects
Regressivity is a general feature of taxes on consumption, and therefore
one would expect carbon taxes to be regressive. This expectation also
carries through to various types of cap and trade schemes. Overall, the
literature on the distributional effects of mitigation policies confirms
at Freie Universitaet Berlin on April 24, 2015csp.sagepub.comDownloaded from

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors compared the macro-structural welfare and sustainability indicators of thirty countries and raised the issue of whether differences in the institutional and organisational capabilities of combining welfare with environmental policies are reflected in people's attitudes and opinions.
Abstract: Authors such as Dryzek, Gough and Meadowcroft have indicated that social-democratic welfare states could be in a better position to deal with development of the ‘green’ or ‘eco’state, and the intersection of social and environmental policies, than conservative or liberal welfare regimes (synergy hypothesis). However, this hypothesis has as yet not been examined in comparative empirical research. Based on comparative empirical data from EUROSTAT, the World Bank, the OECD, the Global Footprint Network and the International Social Survey Programme, we are carrying out two research operations: First, by applying correspondence analysis, we contrast the macro-structural welfare and sustainability indicators of thirty countries and ask whether clusters largely follow the synergy hypothesis. Second, we raise the issue of whether differences in the institutional and organisational capabilities of combining welfarewith environmental policies are reflected in people’s attitudes and opinions. With regard to the first issue, our results suggest that there is no ‘automatic’ development of the ecostate based on already existing advanced welfare institutions. Representatives of all welfare regimes are spread across established, deadlocked, failing, emerging and endangered ecostates. As for the second issue, the results are mixed. While responses to the statements ‘economic growth always harms the environment’ and ‘governments should pass laws to make ordinary people protect the environment, even if it interferes with people’s rights to make their own decisions’did not vary according to welfare regimes, people from social-democratic countries expressed more often than average their willingness to accept cuts in their standard of living in order to protect the environment. (Less)

86 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors explore the recent expansion of energy poverty across different demographic and income groups and develop a framework that highlights the different ways in which inadequate access to energy services has resulted in the emergence of new political reconfigurations among a variety of actors.
Abstract: This paper focuses on the embeddedness of energy poverty – understood as the inability to secure a socially and materially necessitated level of energy services in the home – in the socio-technical legacies inherited from past development trajectories, as well as broader economic and institutional landscapes. Using Hungary as an example, we explore the recent expansion of energy poverty across different demographic and income groups. While much of the mainstream literature focuses on cases where energy poverty affects distinct social groups and issues, our analyses examine the systemic implications of a form of deprivation that involves a much wider range of social and spatial strata. We develop a framework that highlights the different ways in which inadequate access to energy services has resulted in the emergence of new political reconfigurations among a variety of actors, while prompting the articulation of household strategies with far-reaching structural consequences.

70 citations


Cites background from "Who bears the brunt? Distributional..."

  • ...Social justice perspectives have often been considered in conjunction with such debates, for example, by emphasising distributional questions in climate change policy (Büchs et al. 2011) or exploring the structural inequalities that underpin fuel poverty (Walker and Day 2012)....

    [...]

  • ...Social justice perspectives have often been considered in conjunction with such debates, for example, by emphasising distributional questions in climate change policy (Büchs et al. 2011) or exploring the structural inequalities that underpin fuel poverty (Walker and Day 2012)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that carbon markets do not have a role to play in a policy scenario that requires radical emissions reductions in order to avoid dangerous greenhouse gas concentrations, and they put forward 10 reasons why carbon markets should not be the preferred climate policy choice, which have collated from positions taken by grassroots social movement organizations, think tanks, NGOs and other stakeholders.
Abstract: Almost two decades since the Kyoto Protocol was adopted, global greenhouse gas emissions are still rising rapidly. We argue that the global climate policy focus on carbon markets has played a significant role in the failure to reduce emissions. There are 16 compliance carbon markets in operation across the world. Many more are planned, although there have been numerous problems with carbon trading, including ineffectiveness, weak regulation and implementation, instances of fraud, little to no emissions reduction and major legitimacy issues for governments and the private sector. In this paper we take a “strong” position, arguing that carbon markets do not have a role to play in a policy scenario that requires radical emissions reductions in order to avoid dangerous greenhouse gas concentrations. We put forward 10 reasons why carbon markets should not be the preferred climate policy choice, which we have collated from positions taken by grassroots social movement organizations, think tanks, NGOs and other ...

68 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors identify the main components and implications of energy vulnerability frameworks, whereby the driving forces of domestic energy deprivation are seen through a dynamic heuristic predicated upon issues of resilience and risk.
Abstract: This paper charts the emergent body of new approaches towards the research and amelioration of energy deprivation in the home. It starts from the premise that all forms of energy and fuel poverty – in developed and developing countries alike – are underpinned by a common condition: the inability to attain a socially- and materially-necessitated level of domestic energy services. Emphasizing the functionings and capabilities provided by energy use in the residential domain has led us to question binary divisions between the fields of ‘fuel poverty’ and ‘energy poverty’ within, respectively, the global North and South. In order to move towards an integrated understanding of energy service poverty, we rely on ‘systems of provision’ paradigms to highlight the multiple socio-technical pathways that prevent the effective fulfilment of household energy needs. Based on such approaches, the paper identifies the main components and implications of ‘energy vulnerability’ frameworks, whereby the driving forces of domestic energy deprivation are seen through a dynamic heuristic predicated upon issues of resilience and risk. Using recent developments in Hungary as an example, we employ energy vulnerability thinking to illustrate the systemic driving forces and implications of domestic energy deprivation.

68 citations


Cites background from "Who bears the brunt? Distributional..."

  • ...In addition, it should be pointed out that ‘schemes that put a price on carbon emissions further upstream … have an effect not only on downstream energy prices but also on all other goods and services owing to the higher price of the energy used in their production’ (Büchs et al., 2011 p. 291)....

    [...]

Book
24 Dec 2017
TL;DR: In this article, the authors introduce the political and scientific context in which the book is situated and define the terms "energy poverty" and "infrastructural divide" while discussing the purpose and structure of the book.
Abstract: This chapter introduces the political and scientific context in which the book is situated. It defines the terms ‘energy poverty’ and ‘infrastructural divide’ while discussing the purpose and structure of the book. The book’s central aim is the consolidation and development of debates on European and global energy poverty, by exploring the political and infrastructural drivers and implications of the condition across a variety of spatial scales.

66 citations

References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors analyzed the implications of the EU ETS for the power sector, notably the impact of free allocation of CO2 emission allowances on the price of electricity and the profitability of power generation.

642 citations


"Who bears the brunt? Distributional..." refers background in this paper

  • ...In other words, ‘grandfathering’ is likely to have regressive effects (Shammin and Bullard, 2009; Sijm et al., 2006)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a socio-economically disaggregated framework for attributing CO2 emissions to people's high level functional needs is presented, based on a quasi-multi-regional input-output (QMRIO) model.

531 citations


"Who bears the brunt? Distributional..." refers background in this paper

  • ...For indirect emissions comprise a considerable share of households’ overall emissions, in some cases more than 50% (Druckman and Jackson, 2009: 2074; Reinders et al., 2003) whilst overall expenditure including consumer goods generally increases less than proportionally with income (see, for…...

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: This paper analyzed the global and distributional aspects of American household carbon footprint and found that 30% of total US household CO 2 impact in 2004 occurred outside the US and that households vary considerably in their CO 2 responsibilities: at least a factor of ten difference exists between low and high-impact households.

496 citations


"Who bears the brunt? Distributional..." refers background in this paper

  • ...So far, relatively few studies use multivariate regression analysis to examine the relative impact of different socio-economic factors (Baiocchi et al., 2010; Brand and Preston, 2010; DEFRA, 2008a; Lenzen et al., 2006; Weber and Matthews, 2008)....

    [...]

  • ...…the relative impact of different variables on household energy requirements (Lenzen et al., 2006: 192) or CO 2 emissions (Baiocchi et al., 2010: 63; Weber and Matthews, 2008: 384) found that expenditure or income was the most significant variable with positive effects on the dependent variable....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors explore patterns of UK household energy use and associated carbon emissions at national level and also at high levels of socio-economic and geographical disaggregation, showing that different segments have widely differing patterns of consumption.

473 citations


"Who bears the brunt? Distributional..." refers background in this paper

  • ...Households with ‘economically inactive’(8) representatives (for example lone parents, unemployed people or pensioners) are also generally estimated to have low emissions (Brand and Preston, 2010; Druckman and Jackson, 2008)....

    [...]

  • ...The trend towards smaller household sizes is therefore a driving factor behind increasing per capita emissions in many rich countries, particularly if indirect emissions are included (Druckman and Jackson, 2008: 3184)....

    [...]

  • ...Households with ‘economically inactive’8 representatives (for example lone parents, unemployed people or pensioners) are also generally estimated to have low emissions (Brand and Preston, 2010; Druckman and Jackson, 2008)....

    [...]

  • ...This means that low income households spend much higher shares of their income on home energy than richer households (Dresner and Ekins, 2006; Druckman and Jackson, 2008; Wier et al., 2005)....

    [...]

  • ...…energy use is relatively evenly distributed across income deciles (at least in industrialized countries).3 This means that low income households spend much higher shares of their income on home energy than richer households (Dresner and Ekins, 2006; Druckman and Jackson, 2008; Wier et al., 2005)....

    [...]

Journal ArticleDOI
01 Feb 2006-Energy
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors focus on the importance of income growth in a cross-country analysis of sustainable household consumption from a global perspective, using per capita energy requirements as an indicator of environmental pressure.

441 citations


"Who bears the brunt? Distributional..." refers background in this paper

  • ...So far, relatively few studies use multivariate regression analysis to examine the relative impact of different socio-economic factors (Baiocchi et al., 2010; Brand and Preston, 2010; DEFRA, 2008a; Lenzen et al., 2006; Weber and Matthews, 2008)....

    [...]

  • ...Three studies examining the relative impact of different variables on household energy requirements (Lenzen et al., 2006: 192) or CO 2 emissions (Baiocchi et al., 2010: 63; Weber and Matthews, 2008: 384) found that expenditure or income was the most significant variable with positive effects on the…...

    [...]

Frequently Asked Questions (14)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Who bears the brunt? distributional effects of climate change mitigation policies" ?

The authors assess the claim that climate change policies have regressive effects by comparing different types of mitigation policies. 

However, there are several issues related to this which require further debate and research: i. Further research is required to identify the characteristics of low income groups at risk of losing out under lump-sum recycling arrangements. One possibility could be the application of ‘ contraction and convergence ’ ( Meyer, 2000 ) frameworks which envisage equal per capita allowances at a later point in time, thus implying less immediate redistributions between rich and poor nations. The literature indicates that, for a variety of reasons, there will still be a substantial proportion of lower income losers owing to high direct or indirect fossil fuel energy use under lump-sum recycling arrangements. 

Study results are often influenced by the choice of country as climatic conditions, energy efficiency of the housing stock, level of car-ownership, public transport infrastructure, levels of poverty and income inequality and so on all make a difference to potential distributional effects. 

DEFRA (2008a: 4) claims, for example, that less access to mains gas (which has lower emissions per energy unit than any other fossil fuel) and less well insulated houses in rural areas are the main reasons for higher rural emissions, rather than greater dependency on cars. 

Initial emission budgets can be allocated to the participants in the scheme free of charge, through auctioning, or through a mix. 

Several studies also report that even with full and equal per capita revenue recycling, that is an equal per capita payment to all citizens financed through the revenue from the emissions reduction policy, a substantial proportion of low income households would still lose out under such a scheme (DEFRA, 2008a: 3; Dresner and Ekins, 2004: 4; 2006: 55). 

The trend towards smaller household sizes is therefore a driving factor behind increasing per capita emissions in many rich countries, particularly if indirect emissions are included (Druckman and Jackson, 2008: 3184). 

If the entire revenue is earmarked to decrease/remove other taxes, the tax reform is termed ‘revenue neutral’, meaning that the costs of the new source of revenue are completely compensated through the reduction of other taxes or charges. 

It is frequently argued that regulation is less cost-efficient than market-based instruments because it does not reflect differing abatement costs of the various polluters. 

The potential power of adverse public reactions to policies is evident in the UK, for example, in the abandonment of the poll tax and more recently the fuel tax escalator. 

For indirect emissions comprise a considerable share of households’ overall emissions, in some cases more than 50% (Druckman and Jackson, 2009: 2074; Reinders et al., 2003) whilst overall expenditure including consumer goods generally increases less than proportionally with income (see, for example, ONS, 2009, table A9, for the UK case). 

auctioning emission permits to the participants creates a revenue stream for the government or organization that issues the permits. 

This is because international equal allowance and lump-sum rebate schemes would be regressive in rich countries, and trigger an enormous transfer of resources from the developed to the less developed world. 

Whilst lump-sum rebates are likely to attract wide public support, they are likely to be opposed by (high emitting) wealthier people and businesses.