scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question

Showing papers on "Diffusion of innovations published in 1985"


Journal ArticleDOI

18,643 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
Gershon Feder1, Roger Slade1
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors consider both knowledge diffusion and adoption, assuming that a relevant and viable new technology is available, and discuss the rationale for and scope of public sector involvement in these processes.
Abstract: Two centuries ago, Malthus published his gloomy predictions for the future of mankind on the basis of his assessment of the limited potential for food production growth relative to population growth. As we are all aware, the projections have proven false, essentially because the growth of agricultural productivity was faster than Malthus expected. Over time, agricultural output grew not only because of the incorporation of more cultivated land and the expansion of irrigation and drainage facilities but also through the generation of new or improved technology. Such technology allowed the production of more output per unit of land, or production of the same output with less variable inputs. The generation of new technology is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition for increased farm productivity with given natural resources. In the short run, it is not even a necessary condition if there is a gap between available knowledge and typical farmer practices. A crucial element in the process linking the generation of new technology to increased farm productivity is the diffusion of the new knowledge among its potential users, the farmers. The other element in this process is the actual adoption of the new technology, or parts of it, by the farmers. The present paper considers both knowledge diffusion and adoption, assuming that a relevant and viable new technology is available. The focus is on the rationale for and scope of public sector involvement in these processes. Such involvement includes publicly sponsored information dissemination, intervention in output and input markets, intervention in the credit market, and investment in infrastructure. These issues are discussed below.

51 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Reanalysis of data for five innovations using an estimator with desirable statistical properties results in a considerably revised estimate of the impact of prospective reimbursement on diffusion.

41 citations


Book
01 Jan 1985
TL;DR: Innovation in the public sector: An Introduction On Theory and Research In Innovation - Karl W Deutsch Part 1: INNOVATION: A CROSS-SYSTEMS PERSPECTIVE Cultural Creativity and Political Leadership - Dean Keith Simonton The Lesson of Historiometry Groups and the Innovation Process - Joseph E McGrath Diffusion of Innovations in public organizations - Everett M Rogers and Joung-Im Kim PART 2: Innovation in PRACTICE: WEST GERMANY Innovation in West Germany's Public Sector - Thomas Ellwein
Abstract: Innovation in the Public Sector - Richard L Merritt An Introduction On Theory and Research In Innovation - Karl W Deutsch PART ONE: INNOVATION: A CROSS-SYSTEMS PERSPECTIVE Cultural Creativity and Political Leadership - Dean Keith Simonton The Lesson of Historiometry Groups and the Innovation Process - Joseph E McGrath Diffusion of Innovations in Public Organizations - Everett M Rogers and Joung-Im Kim PART TWO: INNOVATION IN PRACTICE: WEST GERMANY Innovation in West Germany's Public Sector - Thomas Ellwein Innovation in West Germany - Herbert Konig Retrospect and Prospects Comment on the Chapters by Ellwein and Konig - Wolfgang Zeh Technology Policy in the Federal Republic of Germany - Frieder Naschold PART THREE: INNOVATION IN PRACTICE: COMPARATIVE STUDIES Politics of Educational Reform - Hans N Weiler Comment on the Chapter by Weiler - Dietrich Goldschmidt, Karl W Deutsch, and Theodor Hanf Legal Culture and the Chances for Legal Innovation - Erhard Blankenburg Large-Scale Policy Innovation in East and West European Agriculture - Ronald A Francisco PART FOUR: PROSPECTS FOR INNOVATION IN THE PUBLIC SECTOR Trends and Perspectives in Innovation Policies - Gerhard O Mensch Social Know-How and its Role in Invention and Innovation - Manfred Kochen

20 citations



Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Mattingly et al. as mentioned in this paper studied the disappearance of milk cows from farms in Illinois and found that disasopter (abandonment) groups are the devolutional counterparts to the groups of adopters in a diffusion process and for evidence of the applicability of the wave-like model that depicts the diffusion of some phenomena.
Abstract: Our concern in this paper is to extend some models that are descriptive of diffusion processes to the devolution of phenomena. Specifically, we search for disasopter (abandonment) groups who are the devolutional counterparts to the groups of adopters in a diffusion process and for evidence of the applicability to devolution of the wave-like model that depicts the diffusion of some phenomena. We find that extension of these diffusion concepts to the inverse of diffusion, devolution, is appropriate in the disappearance of milk cows from farms in Illinois. In the development of general theories of socioeconomic change, much attention has been given to the adoption and diffusion of innovations (Brown, 1981; Hudson, 1972). A considerable amount of time also has been spent on the devolution of phenomena, which may be viewed as the inverse of diffusion processes from both a temporal and a spatial perspective. Two examples of devolutional studies are an investigation of the demise of cotton production on the Piedmont (Prunty and Aiken, 1972) and a study of land use in Carroll County, Georgia (Hart, 1980). These latter works seldom, however, link diffusion theory per se to devolution, a notable exception being an examination of the disappearance of dairy farming in east central Illinois (Frederic, 1973). Another exception is an article which extends the logistics model of temporal diffusion processes to the disadoption and devolution of phenomena (Mattingly, 1984). As a part of what could be a first step to the development of a general model of spatial devolution and diffusion, we seek to develop two further devolutional similarities to the diffusion process. Specifically, we argue that the wave model analogy that sometimes describes the movement of innovation adoption across a surface has a spatial inverse, that is, waves of disadoption. Secondly, we attempt to identify the disadoption counterparts to the innovators, early majority, late majority, and laggards of the adoption process. In order effectively to model these presumed inverses of diffusion, our investigation will be limited to the disadoption of milk cows by farmers in Illinois. A reason for this limitation is that it has already been demonstrated that the logistics model is a good fit to the rate of disadoption of this animal in Illinois (Mattingly, 1984), and such a fit is required if one is to identify groups of disadopters who are the equivalents to the groups of innovation adopters. A further reason for this limitation is the spatial pattern associated with the disadoption of these animals in Illinois. Rather than a type that is random or more regular than random, the pattern appears to be a clustered one in which the composition of the most rapidly changing group (cluster) varies with time (Mattingly, 1984). If devolution waves exist, such a pattern appears to be a prerequisite to detecting them, and these waves would depict the opposite of a diffusion wave i.e., contracting or disappearing instead of spreading. Our attempt to extend these two aspects of the diffusion process to spatial devolution is complicated by several matters: the available data are by counties rather than by individual farmer; the exact point in time, if one exists, when disadoption may be said to have become an ongoing process is difficult to detect as there have long been some farmers who did not have milk cows, and the proportion of such farmers has differed from time to time and from one place to another even within Illinois; the individuals composing the population of farmers and the number of farmers change with time; and the U.S. Bureau of the Census data are available only on a periodic basis. These complications, however, merely make it more difficult to detect the sought for features than would otherwise be the case. The groups of disadopters In any area in which an innovation diffuses, some persons, identified in the diffusion literature as innovators or early innovators, adopt first. They are followed by a much larger group of adopters, the early majority, who, in turn, are followed by an equally large group called the late majority. Near the end of the process, only a few persons, lag* Professor Paul F. Mattingly and Assistant Professor George Aspbury, Department of Geography-Geology, Ilinois State University, Normal, Illinois 61761, USA. GEOGRAFISKA ANNALER ? 67 B (1985). 1 1 This content downloaded from 157.55.39.180 on Mon, 25 Apr 2016 07:05:30 UTC All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

3 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors examined empirical evidence of the mechanism by which elementary schools acted as diffusion agencies during a circumscribed epidemic of variola minor, the mild form of smallpox.

1 citations