scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question
Topic

Loss aversion

About: Loss aversion is a research topic. Over the lifetime, 2898 publications have been published within this topic receiving 115198 citations.


Papers
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI
Xianyong Xiao1, Yuan-Qian Ma1, Yi Zhang, Liu Yang1, Ying Wang1 
TL;DR: In this article, a valuation method of PPV based on customers' perceived power utility (PPU) and willingness to pay (WTP) is proposed in order to meet the customers' requirements for power quality, premium power is needed with a large amount of investment.
Abstract: Many devices and processes installed at the high-technology manufacturing customer side are very sensitive to voltage sags and short-time interruptions. To meet the customers' requirements for power quality, premium power is needed with a large amount of investment. The investment of premium power depends on the premium power value (PPV) perceived by the customers. One valuation method of PPV based on customers' perceived power utility (PPU) and willingness to pay (WTP) is proposed in this study. The quantitative method of the power utility and the PPU has been studied in detail. Taking customers' loss aversion psychology to economic losses into account, the quantitative assessment methods of the customer WTP and PPV have also been proposed. As a case study, one field investigation to five high-technology manufacturing customers located in one High Technology Park in Western China has been done. With the help of the field-recorded voltage sag data and customer economic losses data over the last 10 years, the proposed method was applied to valuate these five customers. The valuated results compared with investigated results proved that the proposed method is correct, rational, and feasible.

18 citations

Proceedings Article
01 Jan 2013
TL;DR: People’s risky decisions are best accounted for by a version of prospect theory that has a more elevated weighting function for losses than for gains but the same value function for both domains, contradict the common assumption that a kinked value function is necessary to model risky choices.
Abstract: Modeling Gain-Loss Asymmetries in Risky Choice: The Critical Role of Probability Weighting Thorsten Pachur (pachur@mpib-berlin.mpg.de) Center for Adaptive Rationality, Max Planck Institute for Human Development, Lentzeallee 94 14195 Berlin, Germany David Kellen (david.kellen@psychologie.uni-freiburg.de) Department of Psychology, Albert Ludwig University Freiburg, Engelbergerstr. 41 79085 Freiburg im Breisgau, Germany Abstract A robust empirical regularity in decision making is that the negative consequences of an option (i.e., losses) often have a stronger impact on people’s behavior than the positive consequences (i.e., gains). One common explanation for such a gain-loss asymmetry is loss aversion. To model loss aversion in risky decisions, prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979) assumes a kinked value function (which translates objective consequences into subjective utilities), with a steeper curvature for losses than for gains. We highlight, however, that the prospect theory framework offers many alternative ways to model gain-loss asymmetries (e.g., via the weighting function, which translates objective probabilities into subjective decision weights; or via the choice rule). Our goal is to systematically test these alternative models against each other. In a reanalysis of data by Glockner and Pachur (2012), we show that people’s risky decisions are best accounted for by a version of prospect theory that has a more elevated weighting function for losses than for gains but the same value function for both domains. These results contradict the common assumption that a kinked value function is necessary to model risky choices and point to the neglected role of people’s differential probability weighting in the gain and loss domains. Keywords: cognitive modeling; loss aversion; risky choice; prospect theory; probability weighting Introduction For many of our decisions we are unable to tell with certainty what consequence the decision will have—for instance, when deciding between different medications that potentially lead to some side effects. Ideally, we have knowledge of the nature of the possible consequences as well as some inkling of the chances that the consequences will occur, but our decisions must necessarily remain in the “twilight of probability” (Locke, 1690/2004). Elaborating how such risky decisions are made (and how they should be made) has engaged decision scientists at least since Bernoulli’s (1738/1954) seminal work on subjective utility. One of the most influential and successful modeling frameworks of risky decision making is prospect theory (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979; Tversky & Kahneman, 1992). A prominent feature of prospect theory is the assumption that the subjective disutility of a negative outcome is higher than the subjective utility of a positive outcome of the same size. In other words, prospect theory assumes an asymmetry between gains and losses in its value function, which translates objective outcomes into subjective magnitudes. This assumption of loss aversion can explain, for instance, that people dislike gambles in which one has a 50% chance to win a particular amount of money and a 50% can to lose the same amount. Similarly, loss aversion is invoked to account for the endowment effect—the phenomenon that people evaluate an object higher in a buyer perspective than in a seller perspective (e.g., Pachur & Scheibehenne, 2012; for a general overview of gain-loss asymmetries, see Peeters & Czapinski, 1990). However, the way prospect theory—more specifically, its mathematical formulation in cumulative prospect theory (CPT; Tversky & Kahneman, 1992)—is usually implemented allows for asymmetries in the evaluation of positive and negative prospects to be represented also in other ways than via the value function. For instance, the parameters of CPT’s weighting function, which translates objective probabilities into subjective decision weights, are typically estimated separately for the gain and the loss domain (e.g., Gonzalez & Wu, 1999). Furthermore, it has been argued that choice sensitivity (i.e., how accurately choices between two alternatives reflect their subjective valuations) differs between options involving losses and those involving gains only (Yechiam & Hochman, 2013a). Crucially, these possible representations of gain-loss asymmetries within CPT have never been directly pitted against each other in a model-comparison analysis (Linhart & Zucchini, 1986), where the descriptive power of a model is evaluated in light of its complexity (but see Harless & Camerer, 1994; Stott, 2006). Conducting such a model comparison is our goal in this paper. To that end, we use CPT to model data collected by Glockner and Pachur (2012), where 64 participants were asked to make choices between 138 two-outcome monetary gamble problems. 1 Fitting different implementations of CPT to this data also allows us to test specific predictions of how a gain-loss asymmetry should be reflected in specific parameter patterns, such as choice sensitivity (Yechiam & Hochman, 2013a) or probability sensitivity (Wu & Markle, 2008). Next we provide a detailed description of CPT’s parameter In Glockner and Pachur (2012) each participant made choices between 138 gamble problems at two separate sessions (separated by one week). Here we analyze the data from the first session.

18 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors employed a choice experiment using choice-based conjoint analysis to examine consumer preferences for electricity tariffs that apply a combination of rewards and/or penalties for electricity consumption.

18 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, a single-period inventory problem with random yield and demand is studied, where the loss-averse preferences are adopted to describe the retailer's decision-making behavior.
Abstract: This paper studies a single-period inventory problem with random yield and demand, where the loss-averse preferences are adopted to describe the retailer’s (newsvendor’s) decision-making behavior. When the loss-averse retailer orders, the fraction of good units in a batch is stochastic. He will choose an order quantity to maximize his expected utility. Both shortage cost and no shortage cost are considered, respectively. The retailer’s optimal ordering policies are obtained, then the impacts of loss aversion, price and cost on the optimal order quantity are analysed. For the model without shortage cost, the loss-averse retailer’s optimal order quantity is always less than the risk-neutral retailer’s, and decreasing in the loss aversion level. While for the model with shortage cost, the loss-averse retailer’s optimal order quantity may be larger than the risk-neutral retailer’s, and increasing in the loss aversion level. Moreover, it may be decreasing in selling price and increasing in purchasing cost, whi...

18 citations

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors present some results from these experiments and investigate their implications for pay systems in the public sector, and conclude that the results have important implications for the management of pay systems.
Abstract: During recent decades, new pay systems have been widely introduced in Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries. Experiments draw attention to some aspects which are normally not included in analyses of pay systems, namely fairness and reciprocity. Furthermore, the experiments indicate a different understanding of what are perceived as gains and losses than what is assumed in conventional economic theory, and they also indicate an asymmetric evaluation of gains and losses. The aim of the article is to present some results from these experiments and to investigate their implications for pay systems in the public sector. The conclusion is that the results have important implications for the management of pay systems, and due to some specific characteristics of the public sector, for management of pay systems in the public sector in particular.Points for practitionersInsights gained from experiments concerning fairness, reciprocity and perceived gains and losses shed a new light...

18 citations


Network Information
Related Topics (5)
Empirical research
51.3K papers, 1.9M citations
77% related
Volatility (finance)
38.2K papers, 979.1K citations
77% related
Incentive
41.5K papers, 1M citations
76% related
Interest rate
47K papers, 1M citations
75% related
Unemployment
60.4K papers, 1.3M citations
75% related
Performance
Metrics
No. of papers in the topic in previous years
YearPapers
2023105
2022178
2021178
2020184
2019189
2018197