scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal Article

History of Economic Thought

Lisa Boily
- 01 Jul 2012 - 
- Vol. 135, Iss: 7, pp 58
TLDR
In this article, the authors make a distinction between historical and historical analysis in the context of neoclassical economics, arguing that historical analysis is limited to the goods and services that were typical products of competitive capitalism.
Abstract
individuals. In a classical paradigm, the concept of class is more useful than individual agents in analyzing social phenomena. In this way, classical economy has roots in holism, and accommodates social categories like class. Usually the neoclassical economics is firmly grounded on a research program of methodological individualism, which generally posits that individuals with given preferences and endowments, and firms with given technologies, enter the market process as autonomous entities. Indeed, the adherence to the tradition of methodological individualism has an important bearing on the nature of the neoclassical model. For neoclassical economists, society is the collection of individuals. Individual wants, thoughts, and deeds combine to make society what it is. To understand an economy is then to make sense of the aggregate effects of individual wants and acts. Neoclassical theory does this by demonstrating how individuals maximize their material self-interests by utilizing their resources and the available technology in market transactions. What happens in an economy is always explained as the result of individuals acting in this way. The economy, as neoclassical economists theorize it, is the aggregate end product of individuals. Historical vs. Ahistorical In classical economics tradition, historical analysis is called for and mathematical models and statistical investigations are of limited usefulness. The classical economists have made consistent efforts to explain the rise of the capitalist mode of production in terms of historical analysis. They from the beginning have sensed that it was the essence of capitalist production to generate an accumulating surplus, and that the manner of this accumulation was crucially related to the character of the newly emerging social relations of capitalist society. The classical theory of value would be limited to the goods and services that were typical products of competitive capitalism. They regarded the explanation of this historical phenomenon as their primary task. Instead of the characteristic features of a given socioeconomic system, the starting point of neoclassical economics is the ahistorical individual and therefore the neoclassical theories are expressed in mathematical models which exclude the concept of history. For example, in neoclassical traditions, there are only factors of production, namely, labour, land and capital, each of which receives a reward commensurate with its productivity. There are no essential differences among them. This shows the lack of the notion of class which is unique to the stage of capitalist society. This methodological features arises from the fact that though the great themes of classical economy are dynamic and developmental, the great themes of neoclassical economy are static and allocational.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The theory of unequal ecological exchange: a Marx-Odum dialectic

TL;DR: In this article, a new approach is provided, based on a critical appropriation of systems ecologist Howard Odum's emergy analysis, which offers key elements of a wider dialectical synthesis, made possible in part by his intensive studies of Marx's political-economic critique of capitalism and by Marx's own theory of metabolic rift.
Journal ArticleDOI

Globalization and Modernity

TL;DR: The authors argue that these changes are part of a economic transition to post-industrialism associated with risks and inequalities that shape human experience in the midst of a formidable global financial climate, and they argue that the propagation of free market mindsets in emerging economies has created collective network connections with considerable good but pervasive inequalities as well.

The origins of the economics of Innovation

Mario Coccia
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors suggest that the origins of the economics of technical change go back to many years before Schumpeter's contributions and that the Scottish philosopher John Rae with his book Statement of Some New Principles on the Subject of Political Economy, issued in 1834, put forward the basis of the Economics of innovation individuating the nature, causes of technological innovations and effects of technological progress on economic growth of nations.
Dissertation

Disciplined reasoning: Styles of reasoning and the mainstream-heterodoxy divide in Swedish economics

Anders Hylmö
TL;DR: The authors argue that the mainstream-heterodoxy divide is fruitfully understood in terms of the institutionalised stabilisation of a disciplinary style of reasoning, and show how economists understand their scientific approach and its merits.
Dissertation

'Nature's coyn must not be hoorded' : Milton and the economics of salvation, 1634-1674

Adam Swann
TL;DR: Milton's use of economic tropes has attracted very little critical attention, and the connections between economics and theology in his thought have not yet been explored as mentioned in this paper, but neither scholar has pursued these connections into Milton's theology.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The theory of unequal ecological exchange: a Marx-Odum dialectic

TL;DR: In this article, a new approach is provided, based on a critical appropriation of systems ecologist Howard Odum's emergy analysis, which offers key elements of a wider dialectical synthesis, made possible in part by his intensive studies of Marx's political-economic critique of capitalism and by Marx's own theory of metabolic rift.
Journal ArticleDOI

Globalization and Modernity

TL;DR: The authors argue that these changes are part of a economic transition to post-industrialism associated with risks and inequalities that shape human experience in the midst of a formidable global financial climate, and they argue that the propagation of free market mindsets in emerging economies has created collective network connections with considerable good but pervasive inequalities as well.

The origins of the economics of Innovation

Mario Coccia
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors suggest that the origins of the economics of technical change go back to many years before Schumpeter's contributions and that the Scottish philosopher John Rae with his book Statement of Some New Principles on the Subject of Political Economy, issued in 1834, put forward the basis of the Economics of innovation individuating the nature, causes of technological innovations and effects of technological progress on economic growth of nations.
Dissertation

Disciplined reasoning: Styles of reasoning and the mainstream-heterodoxy divide in Swedish economics

Anders Hylmö
TL;DR: The authors argue that the mainstream-heterodoxy divide is fruitfully understood in terms of the institutionalised stabilisation of a disciplinary style of reasoning, and show how economists understand their scientific approach and its merits.
Dissertation

'Nature's coyn must not be hoorded' : Milton and the economics of salvation, 1634-1674

Adam Swann
TL;DR: Milton's use of economic tropes has attracted very little critical attention, and the connections between economics and theology in his thought have not yet been explored as mentioned in this paper, but neither scholar has pursued these connections into Milton's theology.