scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Trade Diversification, Income, and Growth: What Do We Know?

TLDR
A survey of the empirical literature on export and import diversification and its linkages with growth is presented in this article, focusing on how export diversification relates to trade liberalization and economic development.
Abstract
This paper surveys the empirical literature on export and import diversification and its linkages with growth. We review widely used measures of diversification and the evidence about their evolution focusing on how export diversification relates to trade liberalization and economic development. We also discuss the linkages between trade diversification and productivity at the firm and industry level, highlighting new advances on the linkages between import diversification and productivity.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Article
Reference
Trade Diversification, Income, and Growth: What Do We Know?
CARRERE, Céline, STRAUSS‐KAHN, Vanessa, CADOT, Olivier
Abstract
This paper surveys the empirical literature on export and import diversification and its linkages
with growth. We review widely used measures of diversification and the evidence about their
evolution focusing on how export diversification relates to trade liberalization and economic
development. We also discuss the linkages between trade diversification and productivity at
the firm and industry level, highlighting new advances on the linkages between import
diversification and productivity.
CARRERE, Céline, STRAUSS‐KAHN, Vanessa, CADOT, Olivier. Trade Diversification, Income,
and Growth: What Do We Know? Journal of Economic Surveys, 2013, vol. 27, no. 4, p.
790-812
DOI : 10.1111/j.1467-6419.2011.00719.x
Available at:
http://archive-ouverte.unige.ch/unige:46655
Disclaimer: layout of this document may differ from the published version.
1 / 1

1
Trade Diversification, Income, and
Growth: What Do We Know?
April 2010
Céline Carrère+
Vanessa Strauss-Kahn§
Olivier Cadot
Keywords: Export diversification, International trade, Growth and
employment
JEL classification codes: F1, O11
+ CERDI-CNRS, Université d’Auvergne.
§ ESCP-EUROPE and CEPR.
The World Bank and HEC Lausanne, CERDI, CEPR and CEPREMAP.

2
1. Introduction
Policy interest in export diversification is not new but, as noted by Jose
Salazar-Xirinachs in his comment on Cimoli, Dosi and Stiglitz (2009), for
over two decades it was mired in an ideologically-loaded debate about the
role of the State. Old-time industrial policy having died of its own excesses,
the debate over what, if anything, the government should do to promote
export growth was contained to the fringe of the economics profession.
Mainstream economists were happy to believe that whatever market
failures there were out there, government failures were worse, and that
anyway most governments in developing countries lacked the means to do
anything. But by an ironic twist of history, years of (Washington-consensus
inspired) fiscal and monetary discipline have put a number of developing-
country governments back in a position to do something for export
promotion, having recovered room of maneuver in terms of both external
balance and budget position. So the question is back.
With limited guidance from theory, the economics profession’s answer to
the return of the industrial-policy debate has been to go back to descriptive
statistics (as opposed to the investigation of causal chains). The result is a
wealth of new stylized facts. For instance, surprising patterns of export
entrepreneurship have emerged from the use of increasingly disaggregated
data. Decompositions of export growth into intensive and extensive
margins have revealed interesting patterns, and so has the study of export
survival.
One area where theory has proved useful is in the exploration of the links
between productivity and trade. So-called “new-new” trade models
(featuring firm heterogeneity) have highlighted complex relationships
between trade diversification and productivity, with causation running one
way at the firm level and the other way around (or both ways) at the
aggregate level.
Even at the aggregate level, new issues have appeared. First, Imbs and
Wacziarg (2003) uncovered a curious pattern of diversification and re-
concentration in production, prompting researchers to explore whether the
same was true of trade. Second, a wave of recent empirical work has
questioned traditional views on the “natural-resource curse”, challenging
the notion that diversification out of primary resources is a prerequisite for
growth.
Thus, our current understanding of the trade diversification/
productivity/growth nexus draws on several theoretical and empirical

3
literatures, all well developed and growing rapidly. It is easy to get lost in
the issues, and the present paper’s objective is to sort them out and take
stock of elements of answers to the basic questions.
Among those questions, the first are simply factual ones—how export
diversification is measured and what are the basic stylized facts about trade
export diversification, across time and countries, which we explore in
Section 2 and 3 respectively. The third one is about diversification’s drivers,
and is tackled in Section 4. In Section 5, we turn to the relationship between
diversification and growth. Section 6 focuses on the import side; we review
the evidence on import diversification and productivity and extend the
discussion to labor-market issues. In Section 7, we consider some tentative
policy implications and conclusions.
2. Measuring diversification
2.1 Overall indices
Although much of the talk is about trade diversification, quantitative
measures, most of them borrowed from the income-distribution literature,
are about concentration. We will review these measures taking the example
of export diversification (which has anyway been the focus of most papers)
keeping in mind that they apply equally well to imports. All concentration
indices basically measure inequality between export shares; these shares, in
turn, can be defined at any level of aggregation. Of course, the finer the
disaggregation, the better the measure.
The most frequently used concentration indices are the ones used in the
income-distribution literature: Herfindahl, Gini, and Theil. These indices
are formalized in the technical Appendix 8.1.1. All three indices can be
easily programmed but are also available as packages in Stata. Authors
have used one or several of these measures. Across the board, results are
not dependent on the index chosen.
The Theil index has decomposability properties that make it especially
useful. It can indeed be calculated for groups of individuals (export lines)
and decomposed additively into within-groups and between-groups
components (that is, the within- and between-groups components add up to

4
the overall index).
1
It is thus possible to distinguish an increased
concentration (diversification) that occurs mainly within groups from one
that occurred mainly across groups. We will see in the next section a useful
application of this property in our context.
2.2 Intensive and extensive margins
Export concentration measured at the intensive margin reflects inequality
between the shares of active export lines.2 Conversely, diversification at the
intensive margin during a period
t
0
to
t
1
means convergence in export
shares among goods that were exported at
t
0
. Concentration at the
extensive margin is a subtler concept. At the simplest, it can be taken to
mean a small number of active export lines. Then, diversification at the
extensive margin means a rising number of active export lines. This is a
widely used notion of the extensive margin (in differential form), and the
decomposition of Theil’s index can be usefully mapped into the intensive
and extensive margins thus defined.
Suppose that, for a given country and year, we partition the 5’000 or so
lines making up the HS6 nomenclature into two groups: group one is made
of active export lines for this country and year, and group “zero” is made of
inactive export lines (i.e., export lines for which there are no exports). This
partition can be used to construct within-groups and between-groups
components of the overall Theil index. As shown in the technical appendix
8.2, by distinguishing the Theil sub-index for the group of inactive line from
the Theil sub-index for the group of active lines, changes in
concentration/diversification within and between groups can be set apart.
More importantly, it can be shown that given this partition, changes in the
within-groups Theil index measure changes at the intensive margin
whereas changes in the between-groups Theil index measure changes at the
extensive margin. In sum, Theil’s decomposition makes it possible to
decompose changes in overall concentration into extensive-margin and
intensive-margin changes.
3
This is a particularly important feature as
changes at the intensive margin or extensive margin reflect very different
1
Appendix 8.1.2 presents the Theil index decomposition.
2
An active line corresponds to a non-zero export line of the HS6 nomenclature
(about 5000 lines) for a given year.
3
This mapping between the Theil decomposition and the margins was first
proposed by Cadot et al. (2009).

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Trade Liberalization, Exports, and Technology Upgrading: Evidence on the Impact of MERCOSUR on Argentinian Firms

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors studied the impact of a regional free trade agreement, MERCOSUR, on technology upgrading by Argentinean firms and showed that the increase in revenues produced by trade integration can induce exporters to upgrade technology.
Posted Content

Export Diversification: What’s behind the Hump?

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors explore the evolution of export diversification patterns along the economic development path using a large database with 156 countries over 19 years at the HS6 level of disaggregation (4'991 product lines).
Journal ArticleDOI

Export Diversification: What's behind the Hump?

TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that the Heckscher-Ohlin model implies that export patterns are largely determined by endowments, so, if anything, we should worry about factor accumulation, not diversification.
Journal ArticleDOI

Endogenous Variety and the Gains from Trade

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors explore the implications of models with increasing returns, endogenous variety and …rm-level heterogeneity for the quantification of the gains from trade, and show that although liberalization triggered a sizable increase in variety, the resulting welfare gains were small.
Journal ArticleDOI

Success and Failure of African Exporters

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors focus on the questions of what determines success and survival beyond the first year and find that survival probability rises with the number of firms exporting the same product to the same destination from the same country, pointing towards the existence of cross-firm synergies.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity

TL;DR: This paper developed a dynamic industry model with heterogeneous firms to analyze the intra-industry effects of international trade and showed how the exposure to trade will induce only the more productive firms to enter the export market (while some less productive firms continue to produce only for the domestic market).
Book

Innovation and growth in the global economy

TL;DR: Grossman and Helpman as discussed by the authors developed a unique approach in which innovation is viewed as a deliberate outgrowth of investments in industrial research by forward-looking, profit-seeking agents.
Posted Content

Greed and Grievance in Civil War

TL;DR: Collier and Hoeffler as discussed by the authors compare two contrasting motivations for rebellion: greed and grievance, and show that many rebellions are linked to the capture of resources (such as diamonds in Angola and Sierra Leone, drugs in Colombia, and timber in Cambodia).
Posted Content

Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present a simple formal analysis which incorporates these elements, and show how it can be used to shed some light on some issues which cannot be handled in more conventional models.
Journal ArticleDOI

Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration

TL;DR: The World Trade Organization (WTO) was established by agreement of more than 120 economies, with almost all the rest eager to join as rapidly as possible as mentioned in this paper, and the agreement included a codification of basic principles governing trade in goods and services.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (10)
Q1. What are the contributions in this paper?

This paper surveys the empirical literature on export and import diversification and its linkages with growth. The authors review widely used measures of diversification and the evidence about their evolution focusing on how export diversification relates to trade liberalization and economic development. The authors also discuss the linkages between trade diversification and productivity at the firm and industry level, highlighting new advances on the linkages between import diversification and productivity. 

rising intermediate imports may impact income inequality between skilled and unskilled workers if it reflects a substitution of domestic labor by foreign labor for cost purposes. 

He finds that about 20% of the productivity of a domestic industry can be attributed to foreign R&D, accessed through imports of intermediate goods. 

Amurgo-Pacheco and Pierola (2008) found that extensive-margin growth accounts for only 14% of export at the HS6 level for a panel of 24 countries over 1990-2005. 

Other studies (e.g., Yeaple (2005) or Verhoogen (2008)) argue that exporting to developed countries entail quality upgrading and adoption of new technologies that could explain the increase demand in skilled labor and increase wage inequality in developing countries. 

The direction of causation between income and diversification is unclear, perhaps because of the observation just outlined—namely, that diversification is driven by the extensive margin whereas growth is driven by the intensive margin. 

Using Indian data, Goldberg et al. (2008) find that lower input tariffsreduced the conventional import price index of intermediate inputs by reducing the price of existing imported inputs, but also reduced the exact price index by adding new varieties; as a result, the exact price index is a modest 4.7% lower that the conventional one on average. 

All evidenced that international sourcing had a large and significant impact on relative wages and/or employment, the growth in imported inputs accounting for 11% to 30% of the observed increase in the skill premium. 

A variety of secondary sources was also used, particularly to identify when export marketing boards were abolished and multiparty governance systems replaced Communist Party rule. 

Tornell and Lane (1999), among many others, argued that deficient protection of property rights would lead, through a common-pool problem, to over-depletion of natural resources.