scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question

Showing papers on "Potential output published in 1979"


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The concept of the full employment surplus was introduced by the Council of Economic Advisers in their 1962 report, although its roots go back to World War II as mentioned in this paper, and has been widely used in the literature.
Abstract: PROBABLY the single most important statistic measuring the impact of government fiscal policy on the economy is the magnitude of the government surplus or deficit. Justifiably or not, this single figure has taken on such importance that the Congressional Budget and Impoundment Control Act of 1974 established a process whereby the Congress is forced to consider overall receipts and outlays and commit itself under a binding resolution to these totals. Because of the importance of the budget figure, economists have continually sought to modify the raw data to better assess the impact of the government on aggregate demand. A major breakthrough was the concept of the " FullEmployment Surplus," which was popularized by the Council of Economic Advisers in their 1962 report, although its roots go back to World War II. I This concept recognized that due to the endogeneity of expenditures and particularly tax receipts, the actual budget deficit or surplus, uncorrected for the level of output, gives a biased indication of the stance of fiscal policy. Although the concept of the full employment surplus was an improvement, dissatisfaction with the single summary statistic remained. Several economists have experimented with different weights on the components of taxes and spending, recognizing the differential spending propensities out of the different sources of income.2 This approach has not been successful due to the difficulty of reaching a consensus on a weighting scheme. Another problem with the full employment surplus was the failure to adjust for changing price levels or rates of inflation. Fixed nominal income tax brackets, specific taxes, and taxes on nominal interest and capital gains all suggest that the impact of the budget should allow for the behavior of price level variables.3 Although standardization to an exogenous level of potential output seems plausible (given normal "growth" or "frictional" unemployment), there is no "normal" price level associated with any given level of output. Furthermore, with the breakdown of the Phillip's Curve relationship in recent years, there appears to be no normal rate of inflation associated with a full employment level of output. This paper attempts to demonstrate that price level changes are important for measuring fiscal impact apart from any attempt to determine what price level behavior would exist at full employment. Since the deficit is equivalent to the amount of government bonds sold to the public,4 analysis of the impact of the supply of bonds is incomplete without allowing for changes in the real value of the debt caused by inflation or deflation. Real value accrual accounting, which is making considerable headway in private sector accounts, can also be employed in the public sector.5 A redefinition of the deficit along these lines can be integrated easily with the full employment surplus or any variant definition to yield a better measure of fiscal impact. Section II of this paper presents a brief theoretical discussion of real value accrual accounting. Section III Received for publication April 4, 1977. Revision accepted for publication April 28, 1978. * University of Pennsylvania. I would like to thank Milton Friedman, Ben McCallum, and the members of the University of Chicago's and University of Virginia's Money and Banking Workshops for their helpful comments on earlier versions of this work. Steve Thompson provided valuable research assistance and computer programming. 1 Initial references to the concept were Ruml and Sonne (1944), Committee for Economic Development (1947), and Friedman (1948). For an excellent discussion of the concept, see Okun and Teeters (1970). 2 In particular see Gramlich (1966), Musgrave (1964), Okun and Teeters (1970), and Hymans and Wernette (1970). Warren Smith in Okun and Teeters (1970) gives yet another impact statistic. 3 See Committee for Economic Development (1947), Gramlich (1968) and Okun and Teeters (1970) for attempts at price level standardization. 4 For simplicity it is assumed throughout this paper that the money supply is held constant. One can alternatively regard the profits (seigniorage) from steady-state monetary expansion as tax revenue, so that monetary financing is considered only as an inflationary tax on real cash balances. 5 For an excellent summary of purchasing-power accrual accounting as applied to the corporate sector, see Shoven and Bulow (1975, 1976).

50 citations



Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The authors decompose the output gap in order to estimate cyclical fluctuations of inputs and their contributions to output gap, while preserving the simplicity of Okun's Law, and the decomposition of output gap proved to be helpful in explaining cyclical variations of labor productivity.
Abstract: T HE rate of aggregate output a nation's economy can produce under the conditions of full employment depends on, among other things, the available man-hours, capital stock, and technology. Previous studies on the output gap and potential output, however, have not directly introduced into their models underutilization of capital input caused by the fluctuations of demand. To cite a few of the more important studies, Okun's (1962) work was launched exclusively from the labor standpoint with no regard given to the contribution the underutilization of Capital made to the output gap. The entire output gap was measured and analyzed in conjunction with the unemployment rate. Other studies that have introduced more sophisticated models of cyclical fluctuations have again tended to emphasize the role which the labor force plays. For example, the works of Thurow and Taylor (1966), Kuh (1966), Friedman and Wachter (1974), and Perry (1971 and 1977) have aimed at elaborate estimates of labor force participation rate, average hours of work, and productivity in order to analyze the component parts of potential output, however, clouding in the process the underutilization of capital. In other words, although the underutilization of capital is indirectly accounted for in these models, numerical weights cannot be placed upon that part of the output gap generated by the underutilization of capital. In this paper we attempt to decompose the output gap in order to estimate cyclical fluctuations of inputs and their contributions to the output gap, while preserving the simplicity of Okun's Law. Our hypothesized relationship between the output gap and employment rate is the same as Okun's elasticity specification, but a more precise specification of potential and actual output is made by the use of an aggregate production function. The use of aggregate production function and additional hypotheses on the behavior of the capital utilization rate and man-hours enables us to estimate the input gap as well as the output gap. The decomposition of the output gap proved to be helpful in explaining cyclical variations of labor productivity.

14 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Perloff and Wachter as discussed by the authors made a contribution to the literature both in terms of its conclusions and its technical analysis, and the most relevant conclusion is the 1977:4 GNP gap of about $22 billion, which is far below the gap estimated by several other studies.

6 citations