scispace - formally typeset
Search or ask a question

Showing papers in "Journal of Post Keynesian Economics in 1995"


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, Minsky's financial instability hypothesis interpretation of Keynes's General Theory is outlined and two stylized fact extensions are made to Goodwin's (1972) limit cycle model to incorporate the fundamentals of Minsky hypothesis.
Abstract: H. M. Minsky's financial instability hypothesis interpretation of Keynes's General Theory is outlined. Two stylized fact extensions are made to Goodwin's (1972) limit cycle model to incorporate the fundamentals of Minsky's hypothesis. The introduction of a 'real' finance sector converts Goodwin's stable system into a chaotic one, with the transition from stability to instability and breakdown determined by the level of interest rate and debt. A stylized government sector counterbalances capitalist tendencies towards euphoric investment and results in a cyclical but stable system. It is surmised that actual governments have developed away from this ideal of countercyclical behavior.

309 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the demand for endogenous money has been studied in the context of post-Keynesian economics, and the Demand for Endogenous Money has been discussed in detail.
Abstract: (1995). The Demand for Endogenous Money. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 18, No. 1, pp. 89-106.

88 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the cumulative causation and the new theories of economic growth are discussed, and the authors propose a new model for economic growth, which they call Cumulative Causation Theory of Economic Growth.
Abstract: (1995). Cumulative Causation and the “New” Theories of Economic Growth. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 17, No. 3, pp. 381-402.

57 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In a recent article as mentioned in this paper, Bahmani-Oskooee used the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test and a cointegration technique to detennine what variables have long-run relationships with the U.S. current account and trade balance.
Abstract: In a recent article in this joumal, Bahmani-Oskooee (1992) used the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test and a cointegration technique to detennine what variables have long-run relationships with the U.S. current account and trade balance. He finds that "ffie only variable that has a long-run relation with the current account or the trade balance is the full-employment budget" (p. 90). On the basis of this finding, the author concludes that there is strong support for the use of fiscal policy as a tool for coping with U.S. trade problems. Furthennore, he goes on, "our results indicate that a real ornominal effective exchange rate and tenns of trade do not have any long-run relation with the current account or the trade balance"' (p. 92). The purpose of this note is to point out that the statistical finding on which Bahmani-Oskooee bases his conclusion was derived on a particular method of hypothesis testing and econometric analysis. As I will show, these methods are somewhat outdated and inefficient, and had different and more powerful techniques been applied, the finding and conclusion would have been different. In fact, the research supported by these alternative and newer methodologies indicates that, contrary to the conclusions of Bahmani-Oskooee, (a) the current account (CA) and trade balance (TB), respectively, have long-run relationships with the M2 money supply, the tenns of trade (TOT), and the nominal exchange rate (NEX), and (b) TB is not

53 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, what Keynes really said about Deficit spending is discussed, and the authors present a survey of what he actually said about deficit spending in the post-Keynesian period.
Abstract: (1995). What Keynes Really Said about Deficit Spending. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 17, No. 3, pp. 341-355.

47 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The long-run determinants of the U.S. trade balance were discussed in this article. But the authors focused on the trade balance in the 1990s, not the present day.
Abstract: (1995). The Long-Run Determinants of the U.S. Trade Balance Revisited. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 17, No. 3, pp. 457-465.

45 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present a critical assessment of the concept of macroeconomic efficiency usually implicit in most mainstream analyses and, therefore, of the financial liberalization hypothesis, and this critical appraisal will be the basis upon which they will attempt to build an alternative Post Keynesian view of the role of financial system in economic development.
Abstract: For at least twenty years, mainstream development economists have argued that financial liberalization is the road to higher levels of domestic savings/investment and more efficient allocation of capital. Efficiency is thus clearly associated with a more liberalized, deregulated financial system. This argument, in turn, is implicitly based on the dominant view on the working of financial markets that is, that financial institutions can be pictured as mere intermediaries between savers and investors. Further, the argument also relies on the view that the prices of financial assets reflect the underlying conditions of the final issuers of such assets, a view that has more recently been formalized as the efficient market hypothesis. If financial markets are the loci of allocation of capital, and asset prices are shown to guide savers toward investment with the highest productivity, financial markets are efficient allocators of capital. The aim of this article is to present a critical assessment of the concept of macroeconomic efficiency usually implicit in most mainstream analyses, and, therefore, of the financial liberalization hypothesis. Furthermore, this critical appraisal will be the basis upon which we will attempt to build an alternative Post Keynesian view of the role of the financial system in economic development. Such a view is concerned not so much with answering established questions (such as, "Should we liberalize or not, and how rapidly?"), as with presenting a set of other relevant, but often forgotten, ques

36 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The question of central bank independence is one of degree as discussed by the authors, which is the degree of independence of a central bank from pressure to serve either the political motives of government officials or the financial interests of private individuals and organizations.
Abstract: The question of central bank independence is one of degree. A completely independent central bank is impossible as long as a country has provisions for altering central bank powers, even if that requires constitutional amendments. On the other hand, any central bank has at least some discretion in monetary policy is effectively determined by the currency board. In the United States and many other countries, people question the degree of central bankers from pressure to serve either the political motives of government officials or the financial interests of private individuals and organizations. This school of thought argues that the central bank should be left alone to pursue one monetary policy goal: price stability. It is feared that either government officials with too much influence over central bankers or laws setting inappropriate priorities for them undermine this independence. The federal Reserve already enjoys a good measure of independence, but many observers believe that it should have more. In particular, the advocates of greater Federal Reserve independence support reducing the statutory encumbrances on the Fed, especially the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. But problems arise...

35 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The Independence of Central Banks: A Critical Assessment of the Arguments as mentioned in this paper is a critical assessment of the arguments of the independence of central banks in the post-Keynesian setting.
Abstract: (1995). The Independence of Central Banks: A Critical Assessment of the Arguments. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 18, No. 2, pp. 159-175.

35 citations


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, the authors argue that public assistance should not be targeted, and they propose a public assistance target strategy based on post-Keynesian economics, which they call "post Keynesian economics".
Abstract: (1995). Should Public Assistance Be Targeted? Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 18, No. 1, pp. 3-28.

27 citations



Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: The Determination of Industrial Prices in India: A Post Keynesian Approach Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics: Vol 18, No 1, pp 29-52 as mentioned in this paper.
Abstract: (1995) The Determination of Industrial Prices in India: A Post Keynesian Approach Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol 18, No 1, pp 29-52

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this article, Divergent Trends in Gender Segregation by Occupation in the United States: 1970-92, Vol. 17, No. 3, pp. 357-378.
Abstract: (1995). Divergent Trends in Gender Segregation by Occupation in the United States: 1970–92. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 17, No. 3, pp. 357-378.

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Many of the greatest economic evils of our time are the fruits of risk, uncertainty, and ignorance as mentioned in this paper, and the cure lies outside the operations of individuals; it may even be to the interest of individuals to aggravate the disease.
Abstract: Many of the greatest economic evils of our time are the fruits of risk, uncertainty, and ignorance. It is because particular individuals, fortunate in situations or in abilities, are able to take advantage of uncertainty and ignorance, and also because for the same reason big business is often a lottery, that great inequalities of wealth come about; and these same factors are also the cause of the unemployment of labour, or the disappointment of reasonable business expectations, and of the impairment of efficiency and production. Yet the cure lies outside the operations of individuals; it may even be to the interest of individuals to aggravate the disease. [The End of Laissez Faire]

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Arestis et al. as mentioned in this paper showed that after 1983 consumer borrowing became a vital component in bank loan portfolios, while at the same time a decline in the share of bank advances going to corporations or industrial and commercial companies (ICCs) was observed.
Abstract: The purpose of this paper is twofold. First, we update in the second section the credit segment of a Post Keynesian macro model, the detailed features of which will already be familiar to the readers of this journal (Arestis, 1987-88). What the updating is especially anxious to capture is the sharp increase in the share of U.K. bank debt held by the personal sector since we should expect the personal sector's demand for bank lending to be more interest-sensitive than the demand for bank lending from finns.' Figure 1 demonstrates the essential fact for this study: after 1983 consumer borrowing became a vital component in bank loan portfolios, while at the same time a decline in the share of bank advances going to corporations or industrial and commercial companies (ICCs) was observed. Figure 1 clearly shows that consumer and ICC shares of bank lending combined accounted for over 86 percent of the total in 1979(3). After the "crossover" during 1983, their combined shares held briefly at 85 percent but by 1988(3) they accounted for only 78 percent of total bank debt. Over the same period, (nonbank) financial institutions increased their share of total bank debt from 0.14 in 1979(3) to 0.15 in 1983(3) and then to 0.22 by 1988(3). Since 1988(3), the shares have


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: A rich theoretical and empirical tradition exists in the economics liter- ature that argues that business cycle volatility is strongly and positively correlated with real per-capita economic growth.
Abstract: A rich theoretical and empirical tradition exists in the economics liter- ature that argues that business cycle volatility is strongly and positively correlated with real per-capita economic growth. Joseph Schumpeter (1961) argues that economic development critically depends on the introduction and adoption of new technology which occurs in waves, and is therefore a main cause of business cycle volatility. Simon Kuznets (1967), addressing both the empirical and theoretical literature of his time (including Schumpeter's), concludes that business cycle volatility and economic growth are both statistically and causally related, with those variables that cause increased cyclical volatility increasing the rate of economic growth. The Schumpeter-Kuznets tradition maintains that a fall in business cycle volatility should result in a fall in the rate of economic growth. And, given the rate of population growth, this would invariably reduce the rate of per-capita economic growth. An important component of real business cycle theory, which incor- porates some of the most recent literature on business cycles, follows the Schumpeter-Kuznets tradition in arguing that real shocks to the economy, largely embodied in technical change, play the detennining role both in affecting business cycle volatility and in determining the rate of economic growth. Technological shocks take the form of a random walk with drift, thereby affecting the pace of economic growth.


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In the United States, monetary functions were undertaken by the Treasury and by private organizations of banks before the establishment of the Federal Reserve, and some would argue with better results.
Abstract: In the United States, monetary functions were undertaken by the Treasury and by private organizations of banks before the establishment of the Federal Reserve, and some would argue with better results. There is no reason to believe that, under current conditions, a central bank, however desirable as an alternative, is "necessary" and, therefore, that an independent central bank is necessary. However, there is in the United States a central bank with some degree of independence that is not likely to disappear in the foreseeable future. The practical question is how much independence is desirable? A related consideration is, what kind? These questions involve political as well as economic factors that, in recent years, have generated a good deal of heat and some light. (For relatively recent compilations of relevant articles, see Mayer, 1990, and Van Hoose, 1995). International comparisons indicate that the Federal Reserve is a relatively "independent" central bank that has delivered anti-inflationary "services" (Alesina and Summers, 1993). Monetarists, however, have argued that Federal Reserve independence is an almost insurmountable barrier to effective monetary policy and have long proposed "rules" as a substitute for "discretion." Keynesians and others, without a belief in a rigid linkage between money and aggregate economic activity, but with a concern about systemic processes and unpredictable events that connect the financial system to fluctuations in real output, have been less sanguine about tying the Federal Reserve's hands. The issue of independence has, consequently, fused with the economic


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examined the paradoxical coexistence of high unemployment rates and real-wage flexibility in Australia during the period 1966-1992 and found that the nonreversal of the unemployment rate to the natural rate and consequent persistence of unemployment has a vague similarity to the well-defined properties of remanence and selective memory associated with the concept of hysteresis in physics.
Abstract: This study examines the paradoxical coexistence of high unemployment rates and real-wage flexibility in Australia during the period 196692. The neoclassical paradigm postulates that real-wage flexibility is a prerequisite for the economy to operate at the natural rate or full employment level of output. The Keynesian paradigm blames tfie downward stickiness of nominal wages for the prevalence of unemployment in an economy. However, both paradigms agree that the divergence of the unemployment rate from the natural rate is only a short-run phenomenon and that in the long run it reverts to the natural rate. New Keynesians and Neo-Keynesians, while dissenting on the speed of reversal, agree with the long-run natural rate outcome postulated by the dominant paradigms (Cross, 1988; Davidson, 1993). The concept of NAIRU (nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment) attempts to synthesize the conflicting paradigms and to explain the nonreversal to the natural rate in terms of socioeconomic policy variables (Layard et al., 1991). The nonreversal of the unemployment rate to the natural rate and consequent persistence of unemployment has a vague similarity to the well-defined properties of remanence and selective memory associated with the concept of hysteresis in physics. These properties of hysteresis are generated by loading and unloading of nonlinear multibranch inputoutput systems with heterogeneous elements (Krasonsel'skii and Pokorovoskii, 1989; Mayergoyz, 1991). The presence of unit roots or zero eigenvalue dynamics in the unemployment rate time series shows, first, that the current unemployment rate depends on the past rates; second, that a shock can lead to a permanent change or nonmean reversion because of the absence of a unique equilibrium. Such characteristics of unit roots are consistent with

Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: Weintraub was the founder of Post Keynesian economics in the United States, suffering a substantial drop in status, reputation, and influence as discussed by the authors, which was attributed to the isolation and insecurity of the margins.
Abstract: What makes an established scholar question the foundations of his discipline, break with the great majority of his profession, and abandon a respected position in the scientific mainstream for the isolation and insecurity of the margins? What intellectual difficulties does such a heretic encounter, and how can they be overcome? These questions are posed very sharply by the career of Sidney Weintraub, who moved in the course of a few years after 1958 from being a distinguished practitioner of orthodox Keynesianismto become in effect the founder of Post Keynesian economics in the United States, suffering in the process a substantial drop in status, reputation, and influence. Born in Brooklyn in 1914, Weintraub' graduated from New York University, spending 1938-39 at the London School of Economics. Returning to the United States on the eve of the Second World War, he worked on his doctorate, on "Monopoly and the Economic System," which would have appeared as a book but for the untimely death of his prospective publisher in the war. Weintraub then entered the federal bureaucracy and subsequently enlisted in the army. After demobilization, he taught for several years at the (Catholic) St. John's University in New York before moving to the University of Pennsylvania in




Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present Autonomous and Accountable, a model for post Keynesian economics that is both autonomous and accountable in the sense that it is self-sufficient and accountable.
Abstract: (1995). Autonomous and Accountable. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 18, No. 2, pp. 177-187.


Journal ArticleDOI
TL;DR: In this paper, the determinants of Tariff Policy in a Developing Economy: Costa Rica, 1963-92. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 636-644.
Abstract: (1995). Macroeconomic Determinants of Tariff Policy in a Developing Economy: Costa Rica, 1963–92. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics: Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 636-644.