scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

“Antitrust’s Least Glorious Hour”: The Robinson-Patman Act

Roger D. Blair, +1 more
- 01 Aug 2014 - 
- Vol. 57, Iss: 4, pp 12
Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this article, the authors explore Bork's criticism of the Robinson-Patman Act along with those of other legal scholars and economists and analyze the central prohibitions of the act and explore their competitive implications.
Abstract
In The Antitrust Paradox, Robert Bork explored many of antitrust’s misadventures. Specifically, Bork severely criticized the Robinson-Patman Act, which he characterized as “antitrust’s least glorious hour.” In this paper, we explore Bork’s criticism of the Robinson-Patman Act along with those of other legal scholars and economists. We analyze the central prohibitions of the act and explore their competitive implications. We also show that the act’s unfortunate prohibitions have been muted by the antitrust agencies’ benign neglect and three recent Supreme Court decisions.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

University of Florida Levin College of Law University of Florida Levin College of Law
UF Law Scholarship Repository UF Law Scholarship Repository
UF Law Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship
2014
Antitrust's Least Glorious Hour”: The Robinson-Patman Act Antitrust's Least Glorious Hour”: The Robinson-Patman Act
Roger D. Blair
University of Florida
, roger.blair@warrington.u=.edu
Christina DePasquale
Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarship.law.u=.edu/facultypub
Part of the Antitrust and Trade Regulation Commons
Recommended Citation Recommended Citation
Roger D. Blair & Christina DePasquale,
Antitrust’s Least Glorious Hour”: The Robinson-Patman Act
, 57
J.L. & Econ. 201 (2014)
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at UF Law Scholarship
Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in UF Law Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of UF
Law Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact kaleita@law.u=.edu.

S201
[ Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 57 (February 2014)]
© 2014 by e University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-2186/2014/5701-0034$10.00
“Antitrust’s Least Glorious Hour”:
e Robinson-Patman Act
Roger D. BlairUniversity of Florida
Christina DePasqualeEmory University
Abstract
In e Antitrust Paradox, Robert Bork explored many of antitrust’s misadven-
tures. Specically, Bork severely criticized the Robinson-Patman Act, which he
characterized as “antitrust’s least glorious hour.” In this paper, we explore Bork’s
criticism of the Robinson-Patman Act along with those of other legal scholars
and economists. We analyze the central prohibitions of the act and explore their
competitive implications. We also show that the act’s unfortunate prohibitions
have been muted by the antitrust agencies’ benign neglect and three recent Su-
preme Court decisions.
1. Introduction
In e Antitrust Paradox, Robert Bork explored many of antitrust’s misadven-
tures. At the time, not everyone agreed with his assessment of merger policy and
the whole array of vertical restraints. When it came to the Robinson-Patman Act,
however, Bork was neither rst nor alone in his condemnation. He severely crit-
icized the Robinson-Patman Act, which he characterized as “antitrust’s least glo-
rious hour” (Bork 1978, p. 382). He referred to the act as “the misshapen progeny
of intolerable drasmanship coupled to wholly mistaken economic theory” (Bork
1978, p. 382).
1
Bork found this ill-advised statute to be beyond repair and called
for its repeal.
In this paper, we explore Bork’s criticism of the Robinson-Patman Act along
with those of other legal scholars and economists. We analyze the central prohi-
bitions of the act and explore their competitive implications. We also show that
Without blaming them for what follows, we thank Dennis Carlton, Kenneth Elzinga, Herbert
Hovenkamp, Keith Hylton, and Daniel Sokol for helpful advice. We also thank the participants in
the symposium e Inuence of Robert H. Bork on Antitrust Law: A Retrospective, which was held
at the Yale Law School (September 27–28, 2013), for their comments. Finally, we thank an anony-
mous referee for constructive suggestions. We are grateful for nancial support from our respective
institutions.
1
Although other critics may have been less colorful, Bork acknowledges that there were plenty of
them. He contends that “no other antitrust statute has been subject to so steady a barrage of hostile
commentary as the Robinson-Patman Act” (Bork 1978, p. 385).
This content downloaded from
128.227.143.74 on Mon, 30 Mar 2020 17:01:47 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

S202 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
the act’s unfortunate prohibitions have been muted by the antitrust agencies’ be-
nign neglect and three recent Supreme Court decisions.
In Section 2, we examine the Robinson-Patman Act’s concern with protecting
competitors rather than competition, which puts it at variance with the central
focus of antitrust policy. In Section 3, we explore Bork’s views on the Robinson-
Patman Act along with those of other commentators. In Section 4, we turn our
attention to primary-line cases. Here we explain how the Supreme Court has now
muted the eects of earlier decisions. In Section 5, we examine the secondary-line
cases and explain the still-present mischief of earlier decisions. In Section 6, we
explore future prospects for the Robinson-Patman Act. Finally, we close with
some concluding remarks in Section 7.
2. The Robinson-Patman Act
In 1914, the Clayton Antitrust Act (15 U.S.C. sec. 12) was enacted in an eort
to provide some specicity that the Sherman Act’s broad language lacked. In the
wake of Standard Oil Company v. United States (221 U.S. 1 [1911])
2
and United
States v. American Tobacco Company (221 U.S. 106 [1911]),
3
section 2 of the
Clayton Act took dead aim at predatory pricing. Rightly or wrongly, Congress en-
visioned large multimarket rms that could use predatory prices in isolated mar-
kets to bankrupt single-market rivals as a means of extending monopoly power
into those markets. By the 1930s, however, the aim was protectionism. Chain
stores began to make life dicult for small, inecient, locally owned stores. e
source of this “problem” of low prices allegedly was the purchasing power of the
chains. In 1936, the Robinson-Patman Act (15 U.S.C. sec. 13) amended section
2 of the Clayton Act in an eort to protect mom-and-pop stores from the large
retail chains. Such protectionism was ill-advised since consumers obviously pre-
ferred the lower prices of the more ecient chains to the higher prices oered by
smaller, owner-operated stores. (e premise of the act is that free markets were
rife with unfair and anticompetitive practices
4
that threatened competition, small
business, and consumers [Bork 1978].)
5
As amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, section 2a of the Clayton Act pro-
vides that
2
On the basis of a searching review and analysis of the trial record, McGee (1958) argues that
predatory pricing did not occur.
3
Burns (1986) argues that sustained bouts of very aggressive, perhaps predatory, pricing were
used by American Tobacco to soen up small rivals and reduce their acquisition cost.
4
Bork observes that superior eciency is not popular with those who must compete against it,
and it never seems well understood by lawmakers. On the origins of Robinson-Patman, see Sokol
(2009).
5
Ironically, the act largely failed to protect small businesses. Scherer and Ross (1990) report that,
of the 564 companies named in Federal Trade Commission complaints about the Robinson-Patman
Act violations between 1961 and 1974, only 36, or 6.4 percent, had annual sales of $100 million or
more at the time of complaint. More than 60 percent had sales below $5 million. us, the brunt of
the commission’s eort fell upon the same businesses that Congress sought to protect. See Hoven-
kamp (2011).
This content downloaded from
128.227.143.74 on Mon, 30 Mar 2020 17:01:47 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

Robinson-Patman Act S203
[i]t shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the course of such com-
merce, either directly or indirectly, to discriminate in price between dierent purchasers
of commodities of like grade and quality, where either or any of the purchases involved
in such discrimination are in commerce, where such commodities are sold for use, con-
sumption, or resale within the United States and where the eect of such discrimina-
tion may be substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line
of commerce, or to injure, destroy or prevent competition with any person who either
grants or knowingly receives the benets of such discrimination, or with customers of
either of them. (15 U.S.C. sec. 13a)
6
us, the Robinson-Patman Act protects competitors of the discriminating
seller from what is known as primary-line injury. In addition, the act extends
protection to disfavored customers from what is known as secondary-line injury.
ere are two armative defenses to charges of unlawful price dierences. First,
in section 2a, there is a cost justication defense. If the seller can show that any
price dierence is equal to the dierence in the cost of making the sales, then the
price dierence is lawful. Second, there is a meeting competition defense in sec-
tion 2b. If the lower price is oered to meet (but not beat) an equally low price of
a competitor, the resulting price dierence is lawful.
3. Bork’s Central Concern
e theme of e Antitrust Paradox is that antitrust policy should promote
competition in order to promote consumer welfare, but its implementation has
oen been at odds with that goal. e Robinson-Patman Act, however, is dier-
ent. It was intended to protect competitors instead of competition. Rather than
enhance consumer welfare, therefore, the act harms consumers. is deliberate
inconsistency with the broader goals of antitrust policy cannot be rationalized.
Although the Robinson-Patman Act speaks of price discrimination, it actually
challenges price dierences. Actual price discrimination occurs when there are
diering price-to-marginal-cost ratios across customers (Stigler 1987, p. 210), but
this is not what constitutes price discrimination under the Robinson-Patman Act.
e act requires only dierent prices. Bork argues that price discrimination will
seldom if ever be anticompetitive. Consequently, antitrust challenges to price dis-
crimination are misguided. He also points out that price dierences are not nec-
essarily discriminatory but that the cost justication defense is not up to the task
of identifying the instances of price discrimination. Persistent price dierentials
are apt to reect cost dierences across customers. ese dierences may be due
to service costs, selling costs, purchase volumes, wholesale functions performed
by the buyer, and the like (Bork 1978).
7
To the extent that the Robinson-Patman
Act inhibits such price dierentials, more ecient rms will be denied a lower
price, which in turn harms consumers. Contemporary antitrust scholars are in
6
Bork (1978, p. 383), observes that although the statute speaks of price discrimination, it is settled
that the act merely means price dierence.
7
Bork notes that if the cost justication defense actually worked, these price dierentials would
be lawful.
This content downloaded from
128.227.143.74 on Mon, 30 Mar 2020 17:01:47 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

S204 The Journal of LAW & ECONOMICS
general agreement with Bork’s assessment (Sokol 2014).
8
For example, Hoven-
kamp (2011) observes that a necessary result of the act’s protection of less e-
cient rms is higher consumer prices. Similarly, Carlton and Perlo (2005) ex-
plain that the Robinson-Patman Act has denied the benets of scale economies to
buyers and thereby leads to higher consumer prices.
Volume discounts provide an excellent example of this unfortunate outcome.
Bork explained that volume discounts tend to be procompetitive: “Some discount
schedules can be oered with reasonable condence that certain identiable large
buyers will take advantage of [them] and this enables the seller to plan the vol-
ume of his output giving him the possibility of most ecient production for that
volume” (Bork 1978, p. 393).
is, of course, allows the seller to oer lower prices that ultimately benet
consumers. As the Antitrust Modernization Commission (2007) pointed out,
however, a principal objective of the Robinson-Patman Act was to impede vol-
ume discounts.
Volume discounts are not the only victims of the act. In many business envi-
ronments, bargaining over price is routine. List prices are not transaction prices.
Instead, list prices provide a starting point for negotiations. e bargaining in-
volves discounts, rebates, credit terms, incentives, and other inducements. As
Dewey (1959) observes, the Robinson-Patman Act outlaws bargaining, since the
resulting transaction prices will inevitably vary across customers.
e act also fails to recognize that price discrimination can serve as a market-
adjustment mechanism and as a way of competing in oligopolistic markets. Bork,
of course, did recognize this and pointed out that price discriminations that are
“characteristic of active markets are favorable to consumer welfare because they
are part of the mechanism by which markets are enabled more rapidly to respond
to and balance the forces of supply and demand” (Bork 1978, p. 394). In oligop-
olistic markets, price discrimination may be a way of pursuing marginal sales.
To the extent that either overt or tacit collusion is present in the market, price
discrimination can undermine the collusive price structure (Kaysen and Turner
1959; Hovenkamp 2011). e results are lower prices and enhanced consumer
welfare.
9
Because of these concerns, Bork recommended outright repeal, rather than re-
vision, of the Robinson-Patman Act. So far, Congress has not seen t to repeal
the act, but recent decisions of the Supreme Court have done much to under-
mine its original intent. It is doubtful that Bork would have applauded this quasi-
legislative action by the judiciary.
8
Sokol (2014) provides an analysis of Bork and vertical restraints, including Robinson- Patman.
9
In truth, the welfare eects of price discrimination are ambiguous. See, for example, Schmalen-
see (1981), Varian (1985), Katz (1987), and Schwartz (1990). To the extent that scarce resources are
consumed in eorts to engage in price discrimination, social welfare is reduced because such invest-
ments are not socially productive. e Robinson-Patman Act, however, was never concerned with
consumer welfare. Instead, its aim in the rst instance was to protect competitors from predatory
pricing. Subsequently, it also aimed at the cost advantages enjoyed by large chain retailers.
This content downloaded from
128.227.143.74 on Mon, 30 Mar 2020 17:01:47 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Report and Recommendations

Assane Seck, +1 more
TL;DR: In 2014, the United States Nuclear Regulatory Commission (NRC) issued a final rule on continued at-reactor storage of spent nuclear fuel and terminated a two-year suspension of final licensing actions for new nuclear power plants and license renewals of existing plants as discussed by the authors.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself

TL;DR: In this paper, Bork shows how antitrust suits adversely affect the consumer by encouraging a costly form of protection for inefficient and uncompetitive small businesses, and how this can be seen as a microcosm which reflects the larger movements of our society.
Journal ArticleDOI

Ethical and legal considerations of artificial intelligence and algorithmic decision-making in personalized pricing

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors build a conceptual model from an analysis of literature describing how companies couple organizational and technology factors into the price-setting process, and test the validity of the conceptual model.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Transformation Of Vertical Restraints: Per Se Illegality, The Rule Of Reason, And Per Se Legality

TL;DR: In practice, the shift in legal rules has not been one of per se illegality to the rule of reason, but a more dramatic shift from per se illegalality to one of presumptive legality under the rule-of-reason to close to per se legality.
Book

Net neutrality reloaded: zero rating, specialised service, ad blocking and traffic management

Luca Belli
TL;DR: The 2016 outcome of the IGF Dynamic Coalition on Network Neutrality (DCNN) as mentioned in this paper gathers a series of case studies on a variety of net neutrality issues from the perspective of different stakeholders.
References
More filters
Book

Industrial market structure and economic performance

TL;DR: In this article, the authors have reviewed theoretical, empirical, and policy developments of the past decade and provided new insights into strategic behaviour from game theory, and integrated them with the related theoretical materials.
Journal ArticleDOI

Durability and Monopoly

TL;DR: In this article, the authors consider the problem of determining the price at which a monopolistic land owner will sell a unit of land in the United States to a large number of owners, assuming that all the land is of uniform quality.
Book

Modern industrial organization

TL;DR: In this article, the authors present an overview of the literature in pricing and its application in the context of market structure and performance, including advertising, advertising and disclosure, and how to make decisions over time.
Book

The Theory of Price

Frequently Asked Questions (10)
Q1. What contributions have the authors mentioned in the paper "“antitrust's least glorious hour”: the robinson-patman act" ?

” In this paper, the authors explore Bork ’ s criticism of the Robinson-Patman Act along with those of other legal scholars and economists. The authors analyze the central prohibitions of the act and explore their competitive implications. The authors also show that the act ’ s unfortunate prohibitions have been muted by the antitrust agencies ’ benign neglect and three recent Supreme Court decisions. 

The future prospects for the Robinson-Patman 21 Third, private actions appear to be less promising than they once were for plaintiffs. If the lower courts adhere to this admonition, private plaintiffs in secondary-line cases will have to prove an actual diminution in competition. To the extent that efforts at repeal would encounter political obstacles, this suggests that there are beneficiaries of the Robinson-Patman Act. 

until the act’s language is corrected, the injury-to-competition requirement for price discrimination to be held illegal will likely remain ineffective for secondary-line cases. 

To the extent that either overt or tacit collusion is present in the market, price discrimination can undermine the collusive price structure (Kaysen and Turner 1959; Hovenkamp 2011). 

This content downloaded from 128.227.143.74 on Mon, 30 Mar 2020 17:01:47 UTCAll use subject to https://about.jstor.org/termspredatory pricing scheme that was likely to have the proscribed effect of reducing competition. 

This content downloaded from 128.227.143.74 on Mon, 30 Mar 2020 17:01:47 UTCAll use subject to https://about.jstor.org/termsThe legal theory of primary-line injury cases depends on the assumption that a multimarket firm can reduce its price in one geographic market to inflict harm on a localized rival (Hovenkamp 2011). 

Instances of secondary-line price discrimination raise the obvious question of why the seller would want to disadvantage any of its customers. 

Contemporary antitrust scholars are in6 Bork (1978, p. 383), observes that although the statute speaks of price discrimination, it is settled that the act merely means price difference. 

Salt argued that table salt was not a big revenue factor for any grocery store and that its discounts were not shown to have caused injury to competition. 

This would change the relative prices of generics and standard brands, which would result in a shift of the industry demand back to the more profitable standard brands.