scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessBook ChapterDOI

Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention

TLDR
In this article, the determination of optimal resource allocation for invention will depend on the technological characteristics of the invention process and the nature of the market for knowledge, which is interpreted broadly as the production of knowledge.
Abstract
Invention is here interpreted broadly as the production of knowledge. From the viewpoint of welfare economics, the determination of optimal resource allocation for invention will depend on the technological characteristics of the invention process and the nature of the market for knowledge.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National
Bureau of Economic Research
Volume Title: The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic
and Social Factors
Volume Author/Editor: Universities-National Bureau Committee for
Economic Research, Committee on Economic Growth of the Social
Science Research Council
Volume Publisher: Princeton University Press
Volume ISBN: 0-87014-304-2
Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/univ62-1
Publication Date: 1962
Chapter Title: Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources
for Invention
Chapter Author: Kenneth Arrow
Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c2144
Chapter pages in book: (p. 609 - 626)

Economic Welfare and the Allocation of
Resources for Invention
KENNETH J. ARROW
THE RAND CORPORATION
INVENTION is here interpreted broadly as the production of know-
ledge. From the viewpoint of welfare economics, the determination
of optimal resource allocation for invention will depend on the tech-
nological characteristics of the invention process and the nature of
the market for knowledge.
The classic question of welfare economics will be asked here: to
what extent does perfect competition lead to an optimal allocation of
resources? We know from years of patient refinement that competition
insures the achievement of a Pareto optimum under certain hypotheses.
The model usually assumes among other things, that (1) the utility
functions of consumers and the transformation functions of pro-
ducers are well-defined functions of the commodities in the economic
system, and (2) the transformation functions do not display indivisibi-
lities (more strictly, the transformation sets are convex). The second
condition needs no comment. The first seems to be innocuous but
in fact conceals two basic assumptions of the usual models. It pro-
hibits uncertainty in the production relations and in the utility func-
tions, and it requires that all the commodities relevant either to pro-
duction or to the welfare of individuals be traded on the market. This
will not be the case when a commodity for one reason or another
cannot be made into private property.
We have then three of the classical reasons for the possible failure
of perfect competition to achieve optimality in resource allocation:
indivisibilities, inappropriability, and uncertainty. The first problem
has been much studied in the literature under the heading of marginal-
cost pricing and the second under that of divergence between social
and private benefit (or cost), but the theory of optimal allocation of
resources under uncertainty has had much less attention. I will sum-
marize what formal theory exists and then point to the critical notion
of information, which arises only in the context of uncertainty. The
NOTE: I have benefited greatly from the comments of my colleague, William Capron.
I am also indebted to Richard R. Nelson, Edward Phelps, and Sidney Winter of The
RAND Corporation for their helpful discussion.
609

WELFARE ECONOMICS AND INVENTiVE ACTIVITY
economic characteristics of information as a commodity and, in
particular, of invention as a process for the production of information
are next examined. It is shown that all three of the reasons given above
for a failure of the competitive system to achieve an optimal resource
allocation hold in the case of invention. On theoretical grounds a
number of considerations are adduced as to the likely biases in the
misallocation and the implications for economic organization.'
Resource Allocation under Uncertainty
The role of the competitive system in allocating uncertainty seems to
have received little systematic attention.2 I will first sketch an ideal
economy in which the allocation problem can be solved by competition
and then indicate some of the devices in the real world which approxi-
mate this solution.
Suppose for simplicity that uncertainty occurs only in production
relations. Producers have to make a decision on inputs at the present
moment, but the outputs are not completely predictable from the in-
puts. We may formally describe the outputs as determined by the in-
puts and a "state of nature" which is unknown to the producers. Let
us define a "commodity-option" as a commodity in the ordinary sense
labeled with a state of nature. This definition is analogous to the differ-
entiation of a given physical commodity according to date in capital
theory or according to place in location theory. The production of a
given commodity under uncertainty can then be described as the
production of a vector of commodity-options.
This description can be most easily exemplified by reference to
agricultural production. The state of nature may be identified with the
weather. Then, to any given set of inputs there corresponds a number
of bushels of wheat if the rainfall is good and a different number if
rainfall is bad. We can introduce intermediate conditi.ons of rainfall
1
For other analyses with
similar points of view, see R. R. Nelson, "The Simple
Economics of Basic Scientific Research," Journal of Political Economy, 1959, pp. 297—306;
and C. J. Hitch, "The Character of Research and Development in a Competitive
Economy," The RAND Corporation, p. 1297, May 1958.
2
The
first studies lam aware of are the papers of M. Allais and myself, both presented
in 1952 to the Colloque International sur le Risque in Paris; see M. Allais, "Généralisation
des theories de l'équilibre économique général et du rendement social au cas du risque,"
and K. J. Arrow, "Role des valeurs bousières pour Ia repartition Ia meilleure des risques,"
both in Economèirie,
Colloques Internationaux du Centre National de Ia Reclierche
Scientifique, Vol. XL, Paris, Centre National de Ia Recherche Scientifique, 1953.
Allais'
paper has also appeared in Econometrica, 1953, pp. 269—290. The theory has received a
very elegant generalization by G. Debreu in Theory of Values, New York, Wiley, 1959,
Chap. VII.
610

ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES FOR INVENTION
in any number as alternative states of nature; we can increase the
number of relevant variables which enter into the description of the
state of nature, for example by adding temperature. By extension of
this procedure, we can give a formal description of any kind of uncer-
tainty in production.
Suppose—and this is the critical idealization of the economy—we
have a market for all commodity-options. What is traded on each
market are contracts in which the buyers pay an agreed sum and the
sellers agree to deliver prescribed quantities of a given commodity
if
a certain state of nature prevails and nothing if that state of
nature does not occur. For any given set of inputs, the firm knows
its output under each state of nature and sells a corresponding quantity
of commodity-options; its revenue is then completely determined. It
may choose its inputs so as to maximize profits.
The income of consumers is derived from their sale of supplies,
including labor, to firms and their receipt of profits, which are assumed
completely distributed. They purchase commodity-options so as to
maximize their expected utility given the budget restraint imposed by
their incomes. An equilibrium is reached on all commodity-option
markets, and this equilibrium has precisely the same Pareto-optimality
properties as competitive equilibrium under certainty.
In particular, the markets for commodity-options in this ideal
model serve the function of achieving an optimal allocation of risk
bearing among the members of the economy. This allocation takes
account of differences in both resources and tastes for risk bearing.
Among other implications, risk bearing and production are separated
economic functions. The use of inputs, including human talents, in
their most productive mode is not inhibited by unwillingness or
inability to bear risks by either firms or productive agents.
But the real economic system does not possess markets for com-
modity-options. To see what substitutes exist, let us first consider a
model economy at the other extreme, in that no provisions for reallo-
cating risk bearing exist. Each firm makes its input decisions; then
outputs are produced as determined by the inputs and the state of
nature. Prices are then set to clear the market. The prices that finally
prevail will be a function of the state of nature.
The firm and its owners cannot relieve themselves of risk bearing in
this model. Hence any unwillingness or inability to bear risks will
give rise to a non optimal allocation of resources, in that there will be
611

WELFARE ECONOMICS AND INVENTIVE ACTIVITY
discrimination against risky enterprises as compared with the opti-
mum. A preference for risk might give rise to misallocation in the
opposite direction, but the limitations of financial resources are likely
to make underinvestment in risky enterprises more likely than the
opposite. The inability of individuals to buy protection against un-
certainty similarly gives rise to a loss of welfare.
In fact, a number of institutional arrangements have arisen to miti-
gate the problem of assumption of risk. Suppose that each firm and
individual in the economy could forecast perfectly what prices would
be under each state of nature. Suppose further there were a lottery
on the states of nature, so that before the state of nature is known any
individual or firm may place bets. Then it can be seen that the effect
from the viewpoint of any given individual or firm is the same as if
there were markets for commodity-options of all types, since any
commodity-option can be achieved by a combination of a bet on the
appropriate state of nature and an intention to purchase or sell the
commodity in question if the state of nature occurs.
References to lotteries and bets may smack of frivolity, but we need
only think of insurance to appreciate that the shifting of risks through
what are in effect bets on the state of nature is a highly significant
phenomenon. If insurance were available against any conceivable
event, it follows from the preceding discussion that optimal allocation
would be achieved. Of course, insurance as customarily defined covers
only a small range of events relevant to the economic world; much
more important in shifting risks are securities, particularly common
stocks and money. By shifting freely their proprietary interests among
different firms, individuals can to a large extent bet on the different
states of nature which favor firms differentially. This freedom to in-
sure against many contingencies is enhanced by the alternatives of
holding cash and going short.
Unfortunately, it is only too clear that the shifting of risks in the
real world is incomplete. The great predominance of internal over
external equity financing in industry is one illustration of the fact that
securities do not completely fulfill their allocative role with respect
to risks. There are a number of reasons why this should be so, but I
will confine myself to one, of special significance with regard to inven-
tion. In insurance practice, reference is made to the moral factor as a
limit to the possibilities of insurance. For example, a fire insurance
policy cannot exceed in amount the value of the goods insured. From
the purely actuarial standpoint, there is no reason for this limitation;
612

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors argue that the ability of a firm to recognize the value of new, external information, assimilate it, and apply it to commercial ends is critical to its innovative capabilities.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Promise of Entrepreneurship as a Field of Research

TL;DR: In this article, the authors draw upon previous research conducted in the different social science disciplines and applied fields of business to create a conceptual framework for the field of entrepreneurship, and predict a set of outcomes not explained or predicted by conceptual frameworks already in existence in other fields.
Posted Content

Endogenous Technological Change

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors show that the stock of human capital determines the rate of growth, that too little human capital is devoted to research in equilibrium, that integration into world markets will increase growth rates, and that having a large population is not sufficient to generate growth.
Journal ArticleDOI

Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R & D

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors assume that firms invest in R&D not only to generate innovations, but also to learn from competitors and extraindustry knowledge sources (e.g., university and government labs).
Journal ArticleDOI

Sectoral patterns of technical change: Towards a taxonomy and a theory

TL;DR: In this article, the authors describe and explain sectoral patterns of technical change as revealed by data on about 2000 significant innovations in Britain since 1945, which can be explained by sources of technology, requirements of users, and possibilities for appropriation.
Frequently Asked Questions (11)
Q1. What is the way to determine the monopolist's incentive?

Since the inventor's incentive under competition is the cost reduction on the competitive output, it will again always exceed the monopolist's incentive. 

In a free enterprise economy, inventive activity is supported by using the invention to create property rights; precisely to the extent that it is successful, there is an underutilization of the information. 

The only ground for arguing that monopoly may create superior incentives to invent is that appropriability may be greater under monopoly than under competition. 

Two exemplifications of the moral factor are of special relevance in regard to highly risky business activities, including invention. 

The importance of parallel research developments in the case of uncertainty has been especially stressed by Burton H. Klein; see his, "A Radical Proposal for R. and D.," Fortune, May 1958, p. 112 if.; and Klein and W. H. Meckling, "Application of Operations Research to Development Decisions," Operations Research, 1958, pp. 352—363.tion among different projects which is incompatible with the complete decentralization of an ideal free enterprise system. 

To up, the authors expect a free enterprise economy to underinvest in invention and research (as compared with an ideal) because it is risky, because the product can be appropriated only to a limited extent, and because of increasing returns in use. 

The company may put its best team on the development for the sake of patriotism or its own long term reputation, but the powerful incentive of competition i.s lacking. 

in any number as alternative states of nature; the authors can increase the number of relevant variables which enter into the description of the state of nature, for example by adding temperature. 

From the purely actuarial standpoint, there is no reason for this limitation;ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES FOR iNVENT/ONthe reason for the limit is that the insurance policy changes the incentives of the insured, in this case, creating an incentive for arson or at the very least for carelessness. 

For c' very close to c (i.e., very minor inventions), the ratio of the two incentives is approximately Xc/Xm, i.e., the ratio of monopoly to competitive output. 

If the cost reduction is sufficiently drastic that P'm <c, then his most profitable policy is to set r so that the competitive price isp'm, i.e. let,r P'm — C'In this case, the inventor's royalties are equal to the profits a monopolist would make under the same conditions, i.e. his incentive to invent will be F'.