scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Gross Capital Flows: Dynamics and Crises

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
The authors analyzes the joint behavior of international capital flows by foreign and domestic agents - gross capital flows - over the business cycle and during financial crises and finds that gross capital flow is very large and volatile, especially relative to net capital flow.
Abstract
This paper analyzes the joint behavior of international capital flows by foreign and domestic agents - gross capital flows - over the business cycle and during financial crises. We show that gross capital flows are very large and volatile, especially relative to net capital flows. When foreigners invest in a country, domestic agents tend to invest abroad, and vice versa. Gross capital flows are also pro-cyclical, with foreigners investing more in the country and domestic agents investing more abroad during expansions. During crises, especially during severe ones, there is retrenchment, that is, a reduction in both capital inflows by foreigners and capital outflows by domestic agents. This evidence sheds light on the nature of shocks driving capital flows and helps discriminate among existing theories. Our findings seem consistent with shocks that affect foreign and domestic agents asymmetrically, such as sovereign risk and asymmetric information.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

FINANCIAL CRISES AND INTERNATIONAL PORTFOLIO DYNAMICS
Fernando Broner
Tatiana Didier
Aitor Erce
Sergio L. Schmukler
*
June 28, 2010
Abstract
This paper analyzes the behavior of international capital flows by foreigners and
domestic agents, especially during financial crises. We show that gross capital flows by
foreigners and domestic agents are very large and volatile, especially relative to net
capital flows. This is because when foreigners invest in a country domestic agents tend to
invest abroad and vice versa. Gross capital flows are also pro-cyclical. During
expansions, foreigners tend to bring in more capital and domestic agents tend to invest
more abroad. During crises, there is retrenchment, i.e. a reduction in capital inflows by
foreigners and an increase in capital inflows by domestic agents. This is especially true
during severe crises and during systemic crises. The evidence can shed light on the nature
of shocks driving international capital flows. It seems to favor shocks that affect
foreigners and domestic agents asymmetrically –e.g. sovereign risk and asymmetric
information– over productivity shocks.
JEL Classification Codes: F21, F32
Keywords: capital flows, domestic investors, foreign investors, crises
*
We received very valuable comments from Eduardo Fernandez-Arias, Carmen Reinhart, Frank Warnock,
and participants at presentations held at the AEA Annual Meetings (Atlanta), CREI, the LACEA Annual
Meetings (Buenos Aires), and the SED Annual Meetings (Istanbul). For excellent research assistance, we
especially thank Leandro Brufman, and also Francisco Ceballos, Ana Maria Gazmuri, Laura Fernandez,
and Virginia Poggio. Schmukler acknowledges financial support from the World Bank, Development
Economics. Broner is with the CREI and Universitat Pompeu Fabra. Erce is with the Bank of Spain. Didier
and Schmukler are with the World Bank. The views expressed here do not necessarily represent those of
the Bank of Spain or the World Bank.

1. Introduction
During the last decades, international capital flows have played an increasingly
important role in the business cycles of developed and developing countries,
particularly during episodes of financial crises. Many studies have analyzed the
behavior of net capital flows, or capital inflows by foreigners (CIF) plus capital inflows
by domestic agents (CID). It is known that net capital flows are highly pro-cyclical in
developing countries and, to a lesser extent, in developed countries. It is also known that
crises are associated with a large reduction in, or even a reversal of, net capital inflows.
1
This paper focuses on the behavior of gross capital flows, i.e. capital flows by
foreign and domestic agents (CIF and CID). In part, we are motivated by the behavior
of capital flows prior and during the global financial crisis of 2008. During the years
before the crisis, gross capital flows had been very large. They reflected, among other
things, portfolio diversification among developed countries, foreign direct investment
and portfolio flows to developing countries, and accumulation of safe foreign assets by
developing countries. The crisis, however, was accompanied by a larger reduction in
inflows by foreigners and outflows by domestic agents, prompting a debate on the
possibility of entering into a phase of de-globalization.
In this paper, we analyze systematically the cyclical behavior of gross capital
flows.
2,3
To do so, we construct measures of CIF and CID using Balance of Payments
data from the International Financial Statistics from the International Monetary Fund
(IMF). CIF equals net purchases of domestic assets by non-residents and is thus equal to
1
See for example Kaminsky, Lizondo and Reinhart (1998), Calvo, Izquierdo and Mejia (2002), and
Broner and Rigobon (2006).
2
Perhaps surprisingly, there are few analyses of the behavior of gross capital flows at business-cycle
frequencies. Three exceptions are Faucette, Rothenberg, and Warnock (2005), Rothenberg and Warnock
(2006), and Cowan, De Gregorio, Micco, and Neilson (2008), who use information on gross capital flows
to determine whether in each particular crisis reductions in net capital inflows is driven by foreigners or
domestic agents. A few papers also look at the distinction between domestic and foreign investors during
specific events or specific markets. See, for example, Frankel and Schmukler (1996).
3
For evidence on long-run trends in gross capital flows, see Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2001, 2007),
Kraay, Loayza, Servén, and Ventura (2005), Devereux (2007), and Gourinchas and Rey (2007a, 2007b).
2

the sum of all “liability” inflows. CID equals net sales of foreign assets by domestic
agents and is thus equal to the sum of all “asset” inflows, including international
reserves.
4
We explore the behavior of these capital flows from 1970 to 2009 in 103
developed and developing countries.
Figures 1 and 2 show the behavior of CIF and CID as a fraction of GDP for a
number of developed and developing countries. Positive values of CIF indicate that
foreigners are increasing their holdings of domestic assets, while positive values of CID
indicate that domestic agents are reducing their holdings of foreign assets. The figures
illustrate the long-run process of financial globalization, as CIF has been consistently
positive and CID consistently negative and they have both been large and growing
fractions of GDP. The figures also suggest that the process of globalization has not been
smooth, as there have been large variations in CIF and CID from year to year.
Particularly during periods of financial turbulence, such as during the global financial
crisis of 2008, there seems to have been retrenchment in capital flows, reflected in
reductions in CIF and increases in CID.
In this paper, we formally document these patterns by analyzing the dynamics of
CIF and CID at business-cycle frequencies, as well as around periods of financial
distress. Our main findings are as follows.
(i) Over the last four decades, there has been a larger increase in the volatility
of CIF and CID than that of net flows, especially in developed countries.
Moreover, the larger volatility of CIF and CID has not been accompanied
by more volatile net flows, perhaps because of the high correlation
between CIF and CID.
4
Note that although we refer to CIF and CID as gross capital flows, they reflect net transactions in
domestic and foreign assets, respectively, between foreign and domestic agents. Also note that CIF and
CID are not equal to changes in foreign liability and foreign asset positions as these flow measures do not
take into account valuation effects.
3

(ii) Gross capital flows are pro-cyclical, as CIF is pro-cyclical and CID is
counter-cyclical. In other words, during expansions foreigners increase
their investment in domestic assets and domestic agents increase their
investment in foreign assets. This is true regardless of whether expansions
are measured in terms of real GDP growth or deviations in GDP from
trend.
(iii) During crises, especially during severe ones, there is a reduction of total
gross capital flows (CIF-CID), with significant reductions in CIF and
increases in CID. Systemic crises are associated with more retrenchment
than crises that occur in a smaller set of countries.
(iv) A decomposition of CIF and CID reveals interesting heterogeneity in the
behavior of their components during crises. The reduction in CIF is due to
reductions in liabilities in equity portfolio investment and other
investments in developed countries and in debt portfolio investment and
other investments in developing countries. The increase in CID is due to
reductions in assets in equity portfolio investment, debt portfolio
investment, and other investments in developed countries and in reserves
and debt portfolio investment in developing countries.
The behavior of capital inflows by foreigners and domestic agents can shed light
on the sources of fluctuations and international capital flows. First, we find no evidence
that, on average, gross capital flows are driven by fire sales of domestic assets to
foreigners and/or domestic capital flight, as we find retrenchment during crises, with
foreigners leaving and domestic agents coming back home. Also, the evidence runs
contrary to the view that capital flows are driven mostly by productivity shocks, since
such shocks would imply a similar behavior by foreigners and domestic agents towards
4

domestic assets. For instance, if crises were only due to negative productivity shocks,
we would expect both foreign and domestic investors to reduce their investments in
domestic assets, resulting in a decrease in both CIF and CIR.
5
Similar implications
would be obtained if crises were associated with a worsening of investor property rights
that affected equally domestic and foreign creditors.
The evidence suggests that crises affect foreigners and domestic agents
asymmetrically. If, for example, crises were associated with a worsening of investor
property rights that affected foreign creditors more than domestic creditors, we would
expect the type of retrenchment observed in the data. We would also expect
retrenchment, if crises increased the informational asymmetry between foreigners and
domestic agents.
6
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data.
Section 3 analyzes the comovement of capital flows by foreigners and domestic agents
and their behavior over the business cycle. Section 4 analyzes the behavior of gross
capital flows during crises. Section 5 concludes.
2. Data
To document worldwide patterns of capital flows by domestic and foreign
agents, we assemble a comprehensive dataset on both aggregate flows and the
subcomponents. The data come from the “analytic” presentation of the IMF’s Balance
5
We are not aware of papers that explicitly model the effects of productivity shocks on gross capital
flows over the business cycle. Some related models include Kraay and Ventura (2000), Kraay, Loayza,
Servén, and Ventura (2005), Devereux (2007), Coeurdacier, Kollmann, and Martin (2010), and Devereux
and Sutherland (forthcoming).
6
The large literature on sovereign risk and “sudden stops” has, for the most part, only concerned itself
with net capital flows. See, for example, Mendoza (forthcoming). Broner, Martin, and Ventura
(forthcoming) show that during periods of financial distress in which the probability of default on
foreigners increases domestic agents have an incentive to repurchase domestic assets in the hands of
foreigners, thereby reducing sovereign risk ex-ante. Brenan and Cao (1997) present a model based on
asymmetric information. Tille and van Wincoop (2010) suggest an alternative mechanism based on time
variation in asset risk.
5

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Sudden Stops, Financial Crises, and Leverage

TL;DR: In this article, a business cycle model with an endogenous collateral constraint that induces amplification and asymmetry in the responses of macro-aggregates to shocks is presented, and the evidence from Sudden Stops in emerging economies shows that financial crashes are generally followed by major economic crises.
Posted Content

The Russian Federation

TL;DR: The year 2001 was the best year yet for legal reform in Russia as mentioned in this paper, with significant developments in Russian laws covering land reform, joint stock companies, taxes and labor, and Part III of the Civil Code has become effective creating more certainty with respect to inheritances.
Journal ArticleDOI

On the international transmission of shocks : micro-evidence from mutual fund portfolios

TL;DR: In this article, the volatility of mutual fund investments is quantitatively driven by both the underlying investors and fund managers through injections into/redemptions out of each fund and managerial changes in country weights and cash.
Journal ArticleDOI

Financial frictions, financial integration and the international propagation of shocks

TL;DR: In this article, Dedola and Lombardo argue that under financial integration, the fact that leveraged investors face the same returns across internationally traded assets, would tend to equalize their borrowing cost across countries.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Share of Systematic Variation in Bilateral Exchange Rates

TL;DR: In this paper, a slope factor (long in high beta currencies and short in low beta currencies) accounts for this cross-section of currency risk premia, which is orthogonal to the high-minus-low carry trade factor built from portfolios of countries sorted by their interest rates.
References
More filters
Journal Article

Financial globalization and emerging market portfolios

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors focus on the degree to which Asian economies have experienced financial globalization, meaning that their gross external asset and liability positions have grown significantly, and they show that a simple dynamic general equilibrium model of portfolio choice in an emerging market economy can account for this trend remarkably well.
Journal ArticleDOI

International Gross Capital Flows: A New Measure and Application to a Global Panel

TL;DR: This article presented a new measure of international gross capital flows and applied it to a global panel from 1970 to 2004 and explained why paying attention to the gross flows underlying net capital flows may be important and how their gross flow measure differs from the standard measure in the literature.
Posted Content

The Next (but not new) Frontier for Sovereign Default

TL;DR: In this new world, debt crises in emerging markets will be a thing of the past, and the IMF is plainly out of business as discussed by the authors, and this change in government debt management patterns is taken as evidence of graduation from serial default.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (12)
Q1. What are the contributions in this paper?

This paper analyzes the behavior of international capital flows by foreigners and domestic agents, especially during financial crises. The authors show that gross capital flows by foreigners and domestic agents are very large and volatile, especially relative to net capital flows. 

for example, crises were associated with a worsening of investor property rights that affected foreign creditors more than domestic creditors, the authors would expect the type of retrenchment observed in the data. 

Some small countries are a concern due to their possible role as offshore financial centers or tax havens; many small economies often display an artificially high volume of financial transactions. 

a negative CID should be interpreted as capital outflows by domestic agents whereas a positive CID means capital inflows. 

All countries faced at least one crisis within their sample period and a total of 78 crises episodes (24 severe ones) have been observed in these countries. 

capital inflows by foreigners remained at depressed levels (or declined even more for middle-income countries) during the two-year period after the onset of the crisis. 

During the last decades, international capital flows have played an increasinglyimportant role in the business cycles of developed and developing countries, particularly during episodes of financial crises. 

The evidence in Table 1 and Figure 3 suggests that capital inflows by domesticand foreign agents have become very large in recent years, surpassing the size of net international capital inflows. 

The authors do so by estimating the following regressions:,,,, tctctc ControlsXY εβα +++= (3)where Y stands for CIF, CID, or a measure of aggregate flows, CIF-CID; X represents either net capital flows, the trade balance in goods and services, or measures of the GDP fluctuations; and Controls stand for additional controls the authors include in the regressions such as country-trends or year dummies. 

The milder reaction of capital flows in low-income countries might be related to the relative size of official funding in comparison to total flows for these economies as these flows are unlikely to decline during crises. 

capital inflows by foreigners have grown considerably less, going from about 4 percent of trend GDP in the 1980s to only 4.2 percent in the 2000s. 

the boundaries of the ellipses capture two standard deviations, which should encompass 86% of the total probability mass.