scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Quantity Controls, License Transferability, and the Level of Investment

TLDR
In this paper, the authors model investment/entry decisions in a competitive industry that is subject to a quantity control, either on output or on a production input, and show that liberalizing the quantity control could reduce investment in the industry under certain circumstances.
Abstract
This paper models investment/entry decisions in a competitive industry that is subject to a quantity control, either on output or on a production input. The quantity control is implemented via the sale of licenses for the restricted output/input. We show that liberalizing the quantity control could reduce investment in the industry under certain circumstances. Furthermore, the level of investment in the industry is different depending on whether the licenses are tradable or not. Key factors to consider are the elasticity of demand for the final good and the degree of input substitutability. Two examples are presented to illustrate the results.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
QUANTITY CONTROLS, LICENSE TRANSFERABILITY,
AND THE LEVEL OF INVESTMENT
Kala Krishna
Ling Hui Tan
Ram Ranjan
Working Paper 8796
http://www.nber.org/papers/w8796
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
February 2002
This paper was written while Kala Krishna was a visiting scholar at the IMF Institute. We are grateful to
Andrew Feltenstein for helpful comments. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not
necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
© 2002 by Kala Krishna, Ling Hui Tan and Ram Ranjan. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to
exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including ©
notice, is given to the source.

Quantity Controls, License Transferability, and the Level of Investment
Kala Krishna, Ling Hui Tan and Ram Ranjan
NBER Working Paper No. 8796
February 2002
JEL No. F3
ABSTRACT
This paper models investment/entry decisions in a competitive industry that is subject to a
quantity control on an input for production. The quantity control is implemented by auctioning licenses
for the restricted input. The paper shows that liberalizing the quantity control could reduce investment
in the industry under certain circumstances. Furthermore, the level of investment is quite different when
licenses are tradable than when they are not. Key factors in the comparison include the elasticity of
demand for the final good and the degree of input substitutability. Two examples are computed to
illustrate the results.
Kala Krishna Ling Hui Tan
The Pennsylvania State University IMF Institute
Department of Economics European Division, IS3-1612
608 Kern Graduate Building International Monetary Fund
University Park, PA 16802 700 19th Street, NW
and NBER Washington, DC 20431
kmk4@psu.edu
Ram Ranjan
The Pennsylvania State University
Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology
106 Armsby Building
University Park, PA 16802

- 3 -
I. INTRODUCTION
Quantity controls on production inputs are commonly used throughout the world. In
transition countries, input rationing is still prevalent in many industries. In some developing
countries, import licensing and foreign exchange controls may restrict the quantity of inputs
available to domestic firms. In industrial countries, input quantity controls are often used to
regulate natural resource industries such as timber and fishing; they have also been imposed
in response to supply shocks such as those experienced with petroleum or electricity, and for
environmental reasons such as pollution reduction.
Input rationing is usually implemented by issuing licenses or permits for the restricted
factor. In this regard, for analytical purposes, there is a close similarity between input quotas
and output quotas: in the latter case, a license is required in order to produce a certain amount
of output, so the license can be thought of as a restricted input that is necessary for
production.
The initial allocation of licenses may be based upon certain criteria, such as firms’
historical performance, or by auction. In some cases, these licenses are tradable; in other
cases, they are not. This is a particularly important issue in agricultural and natural resource
economics, where production controls are most likely to be implemented. For example, in
fisheries management, some countriesnotably Iceland and New Zealandhave introduced
a system of individual transferable quotas (ITQ) whereby an annual quota for a particular
species (the total allowable catch) is distributed among individual firms by means of licenses
that are tradable; other countriessuch as the United States and the United Kingdomare
still weighing the merits of this system vis-à-vis alternative measures such as nontransferable

- 4 -
individual fishing quotas. Similarly, in the dairy and poultry industry, there is an ongoing
discussion within the United States and the European Union on the advantages of a supply
management system like Canada’s, where farmers have to purchase a tradable permit to
produce a specified amount of output.
Although they are widely used, quantity controls and input rationing have not been
widely studied. Squires (1994) estimates the effect of an input quantity control on factor
demand, output supply, and capacity utilization by a competitive multiproduct firm in a
certain environment, using data on wet rice production in Indonesia. However, there has been
little work on the effect of input rationing on entry and investment in the affected industries
under production uncertainty. This paper considers the investment/entry decision in a
competitive industry with no fixed costs which is subject to input rationing such that licenses
or permits are required for production. The objective is to compare the level of investment in
the industry under two scenarios: when the licenses are transferable and when the licenses are
nontransferable. A similar problem is analyzed in Spencer (1997), which considers the
effects of a licensing requirement on imported capital equipment, comparing the outcome
under an exogenous bureaucratic allocation (nontransferable quota licenses) with that under a
market allocation (transferable licenses). Unlike Spencer (1997), however, the analysis used
in this paper draws on the model(s) developed in Krishna and Tan (1999), which compares
the endogenous outcomes from transferable and nontransferable regimes of quota licenses.
They show thatcontrary to the common belief that transferable licenses are always worth
more than nontransferable licenses and always yield more efficient outcomesthe price of
transferable licenses can fall below the price of nontransferable licenses if the quota is
sufficiently large and that nontransferability could result in higher welfare if license revenue

- 5 -
is heavily weighted in the overall welfare function. To the extent that license possession
enables a firm to produce the final product, the license market will be closely linked to the
market for the final product. This paper thus extends the analysis in Krishna and Tan (1999)
by explicitly modeling the product market as well. In this paper, the demand for licenses
(i.e., the restricted input) is modeled as a derived demand arising from production in a final
output market. It is assumed that each firm has to utilize a certain number of licenses in order
to produce a unit of output.
It is necessary to introduce an element of uncertainty into the model in order to make
a meaningful comparison between transferable and nontransferable licenses. After all, as
explained in Krishna and Tan (1999), if every economic agent knows with full certainty his
or her valuation of a license at all times, and if the initial allocation of licenses is determined
endogenously (reflecting the voluntary choice of each agent), then there will be no scope for
resale and transferability will confer no benefit (or equivalently, nontransferability will imply
no cost).
1
Furthermore, this uncertainty has to be at the individual rather than the aggregate
level: if all agents faced a common shock then, again, there will be no scope for resale and no
benefit from transferability. In this paper, uncertainty is modeled as a firm-specific
productivity shock which affects the efficiency of final good production. Firms have to
purchase licenses for production before this productivity shock is realized; in the transferable
1
In many practical applications, the initial allocation of licenses is not endogenous. For
example, the initial allocation of tradable fishing quotas in New Zealand and Iceland were
not effected by auction but by free distribution to existing firms based primarily on historical
catch (see OECD (1999)). However, such schemes are generally considered inferior to
market-based mechanisms such as allocation by auction, on efficiency and equity grounds
(see Morgan (1997), for example.)

References
More filters
Posted Content

On the Sign of the Investment-Uncertainty Relationship

TL;DR: In this paper, Bertola et al. showed that the effect of changes in uncertainty on investment due to risk aversion and incomplete markets is not explained by the asymmetric nature of adjustment costs in the irreversible investment case.
Journal ArticleDOI

The law of large numbers with a continuum of IID random variables

TL;DR: The Law of Large Numbers may not hold even when there is no measure of a non-measurable set as discussed by the authors, but there is a probability measure, consistent with the finite-dimensional distributions, which assigns zero measure to the set of realizations having that difficulty.
Journal ArticleDOI

Competitive Firm and the Theory of Input Demand under Price Uncertainty

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors examine the behavior of a competitive firm faced with making input-hiring decisions under conditions of price uncertainty and show that a marginal increase in uncertainty stimulates a decline in the firm's output, provided the absolute risk aversion is decreasing.
Posted Content

Factor Demand with Output Price Uncertainty

TL;DR: In this article, the effect of price uncertainty on factor demand and supply has been investigated under the assumption that all decisions are made before the price is observed, and it is shown that if the firm is risk neutral, the uncertainty has no effect on supply and factor demands.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (13)
Q1. What are the contributions in this paper?

This paper models investment/entry decisions in a competitive industry that is subject to a quantity control on an input for production. The paper shows that liberalizing the quantity control could reduce investment in the industry under certain circumstances. Furthermore, the level of investment is quite different when licenses are tradable than when they are not. 

T TZ K Z Kε < − − Since / TZ K is bounded away from unity inthis region, the right hand side of the inequality is bounded away from zero.10 

The intensive form for the firm’s production function can be written as:1( )q f z z αβ β −= = (17)Assume that β is uniformly distributed between 0 and 2, so h(β) = ½ and E(β) = 1.Assume that the demand for the final product is isoelastic, with elasticity ε:D P ε−= (18)Consider first the case of transferable licenses. 

Both ηg and ηK are related to the degree of substitutability between Z and K: the greater the substitutability between Z and K, the smaller is ηg (as fz is elastic so that fz–1 is inelastic) and the larger is ηK (as output is very responsive to changes in K). 

Equating total supply with total demand yields:1/1/if( ; ) 2 ifTK K ZP K Z Z Z K ZKεε−− ≤ = − ≥ (65)Using (65), the equilibrium license price may be written as:1/ 0 if( ; ) 2 1 2 ifTK Zv K Z Z Z Z K ZK Kε− ≤ = − − ≥ (66)In Period 1, the equilibrium level of investment, K, is determined by the zero profitcondition. 

Total industry supply of the final good is 2max[0, / ] ( ) v P K h dβ β β∫ , or:if( ; ) 2 ifT K K Z Q K Z ZZ K Z K ≤ = − ≥ (64)Note that total supply can exceed K since the licenses are used only by the most efficient firms. 

The second line, ( ; )Tv K Z Z rK+ is a continuous line that has a slope of r forK Z≤ ; has a slope less than r for K Z> ; and takes the value of rZ at . 

ηP is the reciprocal of the price elasticity of demand for the final product: the higher the price elasticity of demand, the lower is ηP. 

The equilibrium nontransferable license price is the same as the equilibrium transferable license price (vNT = vT = 0) when the quantity constraint is not binding (i.e., when Z r ε−≥ ). 

although it is often assumed that liberalizing the input restriction wouldincrease investment in the affected industry, it is shown here that under certain conditions— notably, if the demand for the final good is very inelastic and/or the inputs are very close substitutes—liberalizing the input restriction may actually shrink the industry rather than boost its growth. 

Equating this with the totalsupply of licenses yields: ( , ; ) 2 (1 / )Tv P K Z P Z K= − if K ≥ Z and 0 if K < Z (since thelicense price cannot be negative). 

Krishna and Tan (1998) show that when the quota is very restrictive relative to K, i.e., when K is large enough, then v is higher under transferability than undernontransferability, and when /Z K is very large then v is lower under transferability than under nontransferability. 

With a Cobb Douglas production function, the equilibrium license price and level of investment under transferability are higher than under nontransferability if demand elasticity is high, and lower than under nontransferability if demand elasticity is low.