scispace - formally typeset
Journal ArticleDOI

The Effect of Market Share Distribution on Industry Performance: Reply

John E. Kwoka.
- 01 Feb 1979 - 
- Vol. 61, Iss: 1, pp 101-109
Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
In this article, the authors identify two fundamental and opposing forces within industries-the advantages of greater output control by leading firms, and the difficulty of agreement among more numerous firms, as well as demonstrate basic deficiencies of the conventional concentration ratio, complex roles for multiple shares in industry performance, and a greater overall importance for large-share firms than heretofore recognized.
Abstract
A central proposition of industrial organization is that the size distribution of sellers is an important determinant of an industry's profitability. Numerous studies have explored -and generally confirmed-such a relationship, but virtually all have been subject to a serious and binding constraint. The lack of individual market share data has forced use of the simple sum of the four (or eight) largest shares, i.e., the concentration ratio, as the variable representing firm size distribution. Nothing in theory, however, predicts that exactly four firms are crucial to industry performance, and nothing implies that they are equally important, as is implicit in their simple summation. The availability of market share data for 19721 avoids the necessity of any such assumptions in this research. Instead, we begin by recognizing two fundamental and opposing forces within industries-the advantages of greater output control by leading firms, and the difficulty of agreement among more numerous firms. At least potentially, output control confers the power to set and enforce above-competitive prices for the benefit of the industry. Much depends, however, on who controls output, since the number of "core'" firms influences the strength of collusive or cooperative agreements (Scherer, 1970, pp. 183-186). Large numbers reduce the likelihood of agreement but, ceteris paribus, provide control over greater industry output. These factors are suggested in both theory and previous empirical work. Thus, the Cournot, Chamberlin (1933), and Stigler (1964) theories of oligopoly imply that fewness of firms, size disparity, and threshold levels of output control are crucial. Empirical testing has been limited by published concentration ratios but nonetheless has produced some relevant insights. The fourfirm concentration ratio proves to be more closely correlated with industry performance than the eight-firm or more inclusive versions (e.g.. Kilpatrick, 1967), suggesting the importance of quite small numbers. Various efforts to capture size inequality have demonstrated close associations with above-competitive profitability and can also be interpreted as emphasizing the role of the top few firms (Stigler, 1964; Miller, 1967; Mann, 1970; Kwoka, 1977). And a critical level of outpuit control often, but not always, seems to emerge in the vicinity of 50% for four firms (e.g., Rhoades and Cleaver, 1973; White, 1976). But much of interest about firm size distribution is inevitably obscured by the concentration ratio aggregate. In contrast, the present data permit detailed examination of the market share correlates of industry performance, casting light on the questions of what number of firms is "too large" for collusion and what amount of output control is '"sufficient" for price-setting power. We shall demonstrate basic deficiencies of the conventional concentration ratio, complex roles for muiltiple shares in industry performance, and a greater overall importance for large-share firms than heretofore recognized.

read more

Citations
More filters
Posted Content

Inter-industry studies of structure and performance

TL;DR: The authors discusses inter-industry studies of the relations among various measures of market structure, conduct, and performance, and discusses that tradition has indeed uncovered many stable, robust, and empirical regularities.
Journal ArticleDOI

Cooperation and competition in relationships between competitors in business networks

TL;DR: In this article, empirical findings from two in-depth studies, the rack and pinion industry and the lining industry, show that a firm can be involved in four different types of horizontal relationships at the same time.
Journal ArticleDOI

“Austrian” and Industrial Organization Perspectives on Firm-level Competitive Activity and Performance

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors present and test a dynamic model of competitive activity and performance, drawing on the Austrian school of economics and the structure-conduct-performance paradigm of industrial organization.
Journal ArticleDOI

Rivalry, Strategic Groups and Firm Profitability

TL;DR: In this paper, an analysis of the U.S. pharmaceutical industry during the period 1963-82 finds that a substantial decline in industry profitability is not explained by changes in the number and size distribution of firms, in segment interdependence and in strategic distance.
Journal ArticleDOI

Comparing the resource‐based and market‐based views of the firm: empirical evidence from Czech privatization

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors compare the predictive ability of the resource-based view (RBV) against the market-based approach (MBV) under conditions of great change, showing that the RBV-driven variables are remarkably better at explaining share values of Czech firms in the period of privatization than MBV-based variables.
References
Trending Questions (1)
However, limited market access and changes in productivity are also important factors to consider

The text does not provide information about limited market access and changes in productivity as important factors to consider.