scispace - formally typeset
Journal ArticleDOI

The Transition from an Agricultural to an Industrial Economy in East Asia

Harry T. Oshima
- 01 Jul 1986 - 
- Vol. 34, Iss: 4, pp 783-809
Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
The transition to an industrial economy is completed when the industrial labor force (in mining, construction, manufacturing, public utilities, transport, communication, and storage) rises to exceed the declining agricultural labor force as discussed by the authors.
Abstract
In my framework, the transition to an industrial economy is completed when the industrial labor force (in mining, construction, manufacturing, public utilities, transport, communication, and storage) rises to exceed the declining agricultural labor force. Though an approximate concept, it is a useful one because in the case of postwar Japan, Taiwan, and South Korea (Hong Kong and Singapore have no significant agricultural sector) it was accompanied by the completion of the demographic transition (whereby high plateaus of birth rates declined to much lower levels) and by the completion of the distributive transition (whereby high plateaus of income disparity fell to lower levels).' The industrial transition is more difficult in monsoon Asia than in the West because of the nature of monsoon paddy agriculture, which happens to be the main livelihood of about one-half of the world. No Asian nation, not even Japan, was able to complete the transition before World War II (although some Latin American nations did). Despite high growth rates, the Philippines, Thailand, and Indonesia are still a decade or so away from the completion, with Malaysia near completion. Hong Kong and Singapore moved easily into an industrial economy from a traditional service economy because of the absence of a large agricultural sector, whereas India and China, with enormous agricultural sectors, are several decades from completion.

read more

Citations
More filters
Posted ContentDOI

Strategies for stimulating poverty-alleviating growth in the rural nonfarm economy in developing countries

Abstract: "The rural nonfarm economy (RNFE) accounts for roughly 25 percent of full-time rural employment and 35-40 percent of rural incomes across the developing world. This diverse collection of seasonal trading, household-based and large-scale agroprocessing, manufacturing and service activities plays a crucial role in sustaining rural populations, in servicing a growing and modern agriculture, and in supplying local consumer goods and services. In areas where landlessness prevails, rural nonfarm activity offers important economic alternatives for the rural poor....Three key groups currently intervene in the rural nonfarm economy: large private enterprises, non-profit promotional agencies and governments. Large modern corporations take investment, procurement and marketing decisions that powerfully shape opportunities in the rural nonfarm economy throughout much of the Third World...." The authors put forth three basic principles for policy makers who want to ensure equitable growth of the RNFE : (1) Identify key engines of regional growth; (2) Focus on subsector-specific supply chains; and (3) Build flexible institutional coalitions. They conclude that "a prosperous rural nonfarm economy can contribute to both aggregate economic growth and improved welfare of the rural poor." from Executive Summary.
Journal ArticleDOI

Women and food chains: the gendered politics of food.

TL;DR: In this article, the authors identify three domains that define women's relationship to food: material, socio-cultural, and corporeal, and highlight some of the ways in which women are working to reconfigure social and economic conditions through food work.
Journal ArticleDOI

Agricultural technology and farm-nonfarm growth linkages

TL;DR: In this paper, an array of cross-section and time-series evidence bearing on the dynamics of the rural non-farm economy is reviewed and a simple model is introduced to isolate the effects of different technologies on nonfarm growth linkages.
Journal ArticleDOI

China's urban transition.

TL;DR: This article describes recent changes in urban patterns in Shanghai-Nanjing, Beijing-Tianjin-Tangshan, Canton-Hong Kong, and Dalian-Shenyang as part of an urban transition that is responding to population growth, a structural shift in employment, relaxed rules on migration and household registration, and foreign investment and trade.
Journal ArticleDOI

Beyond the East-West Binary: Resituating Development Paths in the Eighteenth-Century World

TL;DR: Huang's 1990 book, The Peasant Family and Rural Development in the Yangzi Delta, 1350-1988, remains the best framework for understanding the delta's economy over that entire period as discussed by the authors.
References
More filters
Book

Korea: Policy Issues for Long-Term Development

TL;DR: In this article, the authors focus on the social and economic consequences of Korea's rapid economic growth and highlight the need for greater attention to equity, for structural changes to maintain the comparative advantage of Korean exports, and for the roles government is to undertake in response to the changing domestic and external conditions expected in the 1980s.
Book

Economic Development, Population Policy, and Demographic Transition in the Republic of Korea

TL;DR: The Korean case represents close to an extreme in 2 dimensions: rapid open export led labor intensive growth combined with markedly egalitarian initial social and economic structures as mentioned in this paper, and the authors of this volume explore the channels of influence through which the economic development of Korea affected the fertility transition.
Journal ArticleDOI

Trade and Economic Development in Taiwan

Y. C. Jao
- 01 Jun 1976 - 
TL;DR: In this paper, the authors analyzed the country's economic development and appraised its future prospects, concluding that Taiwan's remarkable growth record has been the result of an outward-looking, export propelled development strategy.