scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

Authoritarian Liberalism in Europe: A Common Critique of Neoliberalism and Ordoliberalism:

Reads0
Chats0
TLDR
The differences between ordo-and neoliberalism are many and varied as mentioned in this paper, and they represent a single movement: a conjunction of political authoritarianism and economic liberalism in opposition to democracy and especially to democratic constituent power This dynamic becomes evident with the Eurocrisis response, but it represents the deeper logic of postwar reconstruction.
Abstract
The differences between ordo- and neoliberalism are many and varied This article suggests, however, that in directing the constitutional dynamic of European integration and postwar reconstruction, ordo- and neoliberalism represent a single movement: a conjunction of political authoritarianism and economic liberalism in opposition to democracy and especially in opposition to democratic constituent power This dynamic becomes more evident with the Euro-crisis response, but it represents the deeper logic of postwar reconstruction With a longer historical arc in view, authoritarian liberalism can be traced as a reaction to the interwar breakdown of liberal democracy, based on a narrow diagnosis of democratic collapse Postwar Europe is thus reconstituted on the basis of a substitution of economic for political freedom as a legitimating device for the new constitutional imagination

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

Authoritarian Liberalism in Europe:
A Common Critique of Neoliberalism and
Ordoliberalism
Michael A Wilkinson
London School of Economics Law Department
Abstract
The differences between ordo and neoliberalism are many and varied. They
include significant temporal and spatial differences, ascending in distinct places
and periods of state transformation and capitalist development. They also include
institutional and ideational differences: ordoliberalism is associated with rigid
anti-majoritarian and pro-competitive rule-based institutions, in a primarily
domestic context, neoliberalism with a looser set of political interventions
directing class and geopolitical conflicts, domestically and imperially. This paper
suggests, however, that within the constitutional dynamic of European integration
and postwar reconstruction, ordo- and neo-liberalism represent a single
movement: a conflation of political authoritarianism and economic liberalism in
opposition to democracy and especially in opposition to democratic constituent
power.
Keywords
Authoritarian Liberalism; Ordoliberalism; Neoliberalism; European Integration;
Constitutional Imagination
Introduction
The differences between ordo- and neo-liberalism are many and varied. They
include significant temporal and spatial differences, ascending in distinct periods
of state transformation and capitalist development. They also include
institutional and ideational differences: ordoliberalism is associated with rigid
anti-majoritarian and pro-competitive rule-based institutions, in a primarily
domestic context, neoliberalism with a looser, discretionary set of political
interventions directing class and geopolitical struggles, domestically and
imperially. I would like to suggest, however, that within the constitutional
dynamic of European integration and postwar reconstruction, ordo- and neo-
liberalism represent a single movement: a conflation of political authoritarianism
and economic liberalism in opposition to democracy and especially in opposition
to democratic constituent power.
The dynamic of authoritarian liberalism is evident throughout the recent Euro-
crisis, with politically authoritarian forms of governing emerging at national and
supranational level in defense of programmes of economic liberalism, especially
within the Eurozone (Wilkinson, 2013). Similar phenomena have been labelled

‘authoritarian neo-liberalism’, grouping together recent critical conjunctures in
Latin America and Southeast Asia, often under the auspices of the so-called
‘Washington consensus’ in international affairs (Bruff, 2014). In each of these
contexts, principles associated with democracy and social rights are subsumed by
a mode of governing that operates in accordance with capital accumulation,
marketization and economic rationality.
The constitutional background to the Euro-crisis response is a mix of ordoliberal
principles entrenched at the Treaty of Maastricht (price stability, fiscal discipline,
avoidance of moral hazard), neoliberal political economic strategy pushed
through conditionality programmes (austerity, privatization, deregulation) and
ideological commitment to the European project (‘if the Euro fails, Europe fails’).
As a matter of legal and political form, ordoliberalism and neoliberalism are often
in tension with each other, as ordoliberalism’s rule-based commitments come up
against neoliberal discretionary politics. But they are not in basic opposition, at
least from the perspective of a constitutional theory that takes democracy
seriously. On the contrary, a common denominator is the elision or repression of
any democratic alternative to economic liberalism in general and austerity in
particular. This is maintained in practice by a third factor: the material and
ideological pressure to remain within the Euro-regime itself and the lack of any
alternative political vision.
The Maastricht settlement is now coming to a head as the pressure placed on
elected domestic governments (often self-imposed or imposed by other branches
of the state or regional state-system) to remain within the single currency is
increasingly matched by counter-pressure to leave in order to regain monetary
authority. Italy is the latest Member State in which this stress is provoking
constitutional crisis, with no apparent way out. And the basic dynamic affects
creditor as well as debtor states, with anti-systemic parties and movements on the
rise in Germany and France. The underlying tension, however, is not, as some
argue, merely a temporary one linked to a period of economic emergency; on the
contrary, it is hard-wired into the postwar constitutional settlement in Europe.
The aim of the Euro-crisis measures is not to enable a future return to normal
democratic politics, but to restore the pressure of the financial markets and the
constraints imposed by them, reinstating by different means the same constraints
(conditionality) now imposed through political coercion and institutional devices
such as the European Stability Mechanism and the Outright Monetary
Transactions of the ECB. The last decade of crisis response can be viewed as
having effected, in practice, a conservative revolution: bypassing and
circumventing normal parliamentary, democratic and legal accountability in
order to conserve a liberal economic regime.
The deep constitution of this conjuncture can be explored by considering the
longer pedigree of the confluence of political authoritarianism and economic
liberalism (Wilkinson, 2017). German Social Democrat and constitutional theorist
Hermann Heller coined the term ‘authoritarian liberalism’ in the interwar period
(Heller, 2015), targeting with the label not only the centrist and conservative
Cabinets of Chancellor Brüning that governed Germany before the Nazi party took
power, but also the constitutional theorist who had advised them, Carl Schmitt

(Bonefeld, 2017). Schmitt had recommended a strong state in order to defend the
free market economy against the threat of democratic socialism and associated
experiments of economic democracy, encapsulated in his address to the
Langnamverein in 1932, ‘strong state, free economy’ (Cristi, 1998). This motto
would be taken up and reformulated by the ordoliberals, who stressed not only
the dangers of unfettered democracy but of unfettered capitalism and its tendency
to self-destruct by leading to monopolies and cartels. The state needed to be
strong to secure the legal and institutional conditions (the ordo) of the free market
and disarm both democratic and capitalist threats to it.
The polemic between Heller and Schmitt took place in the crucible of late Weimar,
as it was teetering on the brink of collapse. But with a longer historical arc in view,
the combination of political authoritarianism and economic liberalism comes to
appear less exceptional than normal. As Karl Polanyi argued, the pattern of
authoritarian liberal response and reaction to economic crisis was far from unique
to Weimar right across the globe, states tried to maintain the political-economic
demands of the Gold Standard, fiercely resisting social democratic movements
through exceptional measures, until, eventually but unevenly, they abandoned
Gold, and market liberalism, leading, for example, to Welfarism in Britain and the
New Deal in the US (Polanyi, 2001 [1944]). According to Polanyi, the more fiercely
countries resisted social democracy through authoritarian government in the
name of economic liberalism and sound finances, the stronger and fiercer the
eventual backlash (the ‘double movement’). Authoritarian government hollowed
out democracy, ultimately weakening its ability to respond to the Fascist threat
when it arrived. It was, in other words, authoritarian liberalism that directly
prepared the ground for Fascism.
1
Polanyi’s account opens up a broader point about the backdrop to the interwar
conjuncture. The authoritarian state on which the defence of the interests and
ideas of economic liberalism depended made its mark not only in the crisis
response of the 1920’s and 30’s but in the initial forging of the market society
across the nineteenth century. The market society was not spontaneous but
planned and often coercively implemented using a strong, authoritarian state
apparatus.
Taking a similar tack, the argument here is that authoritarian liberalism signifies
not only the exception, the crisis response, but also the norm, the postwar
European constitutional state and regional order. This is reconstituted from the
beginning in an authoritarian vein in order to restore and maintain economic
liberalism after its interwar collapse. The project of European integration plays a
significant role in this restoration, beginning with the supranational institutions
of the Paris and Rome Treaties. But it is a domestic as much as a regional
reconfiguration.
This new brand of authoritarianism reflects the reaction of political elites (as well
as large sections of the people themselves) to the fear of a democratic- and class-
consciousness that was unleashed in the interwar period and that remained a
threat to the stability of a liberal order. Although this postwar settlement has been
captured by the label of restrained democracy’, or even the inappositely named

‘militant democracy’, these labels conceal a de-democratisation of the political
process, with matters taken out of the hands of ordinary democratic politics in
order to promote political and economic stability (Müller, 2011). Indeed, the West
German case represents a de-politicisation (qua de-democratisation) not only of
ordinary politics but also of constitutional politics with its entrenched Basic Law
and conservative constitutional culture, closely guarded by a Constitutional Court.
It is from this perspective that we can see the neoliberal state of the 1970’s and
the recent austerity state of the financial crisis to represent a deepening rather
than a departure from the authoritarian liberal trajectory of postwar state
transformation.
2
The purpose of this contribution is thus to suggest that despite important
differences between ordoliberalism and neoliberalism, regarding, for example,
their temporal arcs, ideological-institutional supports and geopolitical
orientations, there is a constitutionally significant common denominator. In short,
what may appear a conjunctural turn to political authoritarianism in the
exceptional moment of economic emergency is rather a reflection of a deeper
systemic feature of the prevailing postwar liberal order in Europe. This order is
now in crisis, struggling to maintain the extreme centrism’ it depends on for
political support.
As yet, there has been no rupture from this postwar order but there is increasingly
an inflection, where authoritarian liberalism is mixed with aspects of
authoritarian illiberalism, particularly with regard to issues of identity and
immigration as right-wing nationalism returns. This is occurring within the
European Union, most evidently in Central and Eastern Europe but also in the
core, such as in Italy. Brexit may follow this inflection. But if it were to signify a
rupture with the postwar order of authoritarian liberalism, it would be through a
reclaiming of democratic sovereignty over the economy. It is, however, too early
to tell where Brexit will lead.
Militant Democracy, Restrained Democracy or Authoritarian Liberalism?
The crisis of the constitutional state in late Weimar Germany was a feature not
only of the political and economic turbulence associated with reparations, war
guilt and the Versailles Treaty. It was also a feature of domestic class struggle,
predominantly between a class-conscious and politically emancipated working
class and an anti-democratic and embittered ruling class. This threatened the
political economic order guaranteed in the 1919 Constitution, which promised to
protect economic liberalism as well as the social state, posing a dilemma well
understood by its architect, Hugo Preuss (2000). Above all, it was the anti-
democratic stance of political and economic elites that seriously hindered the
long-term prospects of the Weimar Republic (Kershaw, 1990). The reaction of the
governing elites and industrialists of the early 1930’s to the political and economic
instability, rendered more acute by the depression, was a combination of
authoritarianism and economic liberalism. This configuration was identified by
Heller and Polanyi as crucial to the collapse of Weimar (Heller, 2015 [1932];
Polanyi, 2001 [1944]). In their analysis, it was the capitalist market system and its

material inequalities that ultimately undermined democracy and laid the path to
the Fascist takeover.
Yet the message taken by mainstream constitutional theory in response to the
extraordinary double movement and breakdown of liberal democracy it entailed
in Germany (and elsewhere) would be quite different from the one Heller and
Polanyi had conveyed. It was not the threat that capitalist inequality posed to
democracy that resonated in the liberal constitutional imagination, but the threat
that democracy posed to liberalism. The underlying concern was that democracy
in general and the democratic constituent power in particular would erode or
overturn liberalism and the constitutional order that undergirded it. This concern
came to prominence through the work of another constitutional theorist of the
period, who had emigrated to the US, but became closely involved in post-war
German reconstruction, Karl Loewenstein. Loewenstein, writing in 1935, thought
that liberal democracy needed to be more ‘militant’ in the fight against Fascism
(and, if to a lesser extent, also against Communism) (Loewenstein 1935, 1937).
The structures of the Weimar republic should have been more flexible in order for
it to defend itself, by suspending constitutional rights, banning political parties,
and preventing the rise of extremist groups and associations. Lowenstein,
describing the opportunism of the Fascist opponents of the constitution, urged
liberal democracy to pre-empt them, to take the fight to its enemies, to ‘fight fire
with fire’ (Loewenstein, 1937: 432). This echoed Carl Schmitt’s own earlier call for
robust defence of the Weimar constitution, by dictat and decree if necessary.
In the aftermath of World War II, mainstream political and constitutional theory
thus became preoccupied with liberal constitutional defence, Loewenstein’s
warning apparently heeded. This narrow attention to constitutional form,
however, elided the sociological examination of the power structures and social
inequalities that undermined democracy in a capitalist state and state-system. The
West German practice of entrenching strong constitutional guarantees to protect
individual rights became increasingly influential and widespread (however
misleading the conventional narrative of the dignified reaction to Nazism
(Hailbronner, 2015). Constitutional lawyers, and those tasked with designing
legal and political institutions, were dedicated to the justification of various
institutional arrangements whether domestic, international or supranational
that would constrain majoritarianism, with the rationale (or pretext) of
preventing democratic backsliding or avoiding democratic irrationality.
Independent technocratic institutions such as constitutional courts, expert
commissions, and central banks, became the norm, and were gradually engrained
in the liberal constitutional imagination. European integration was an intrinsic
part of this post-war settlement, representing the construction of a ‘militant
democracy writ large’, a project generated by administrative and bureaucratic
processes rather than democratic energies. The role of the European Court of
Justice in conjunction with domestic courts in pushing forward integration-
through-law would be central to the success of the project (Wilkinson, 2017).
Jan-Werner Müller, with the label of ‘restrained democracy’, offers a more
accurate assessment of this set of phenomena than suggested by the inappositely
named ‘militant democracy’ (Müller, 2011). Müller shows how it was liberalism

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Does COVID-19 as a Long Wave Turning Point Mean the End of Neoliberalism?

TL;DR: This article claimed that the COVID-19 pandemic could cause neoliberalism to break, based on four arguments addressed in four sections, and demonstrated that such a break is possible wit...
Journal ArticleDOI

Behemoth: The Structure and Practice of National Socialism.

TL;DR: The authors published a new paperback edition of Behemoth with an introduction by the distinguished historian Peter Hayes, who argued that the Nazi organization of society involved the collapse of traditional ideas of the state, of ideology, of law, and even of any underlying rationality.
Journal ArticleDOI

Doing Away with the Sovereign: Neoliberalism and the Promotion of Market Discipline in European Economic Governance

TL;DR: In this article, a critical reading of market discipline and its limitations as a mechanism in European economic governance is proposed, consistent with neoliberal beliefs about market-based governance, and the authors propose a critical analysis of the market discipline.
References
More filters
Book

The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time

TL;DR: In this paper, the key to the institutional system of the 19 century lay in the laws governing market economy, which was the fount and matrix of the system was the self-regulating market, and it was this innovation which gave rise to a specific civilization.
Journal ArticleDOI

A Postfunctionalist Theory of European Integration: From Permissive Consensus to Constraining Dissensus

TL;DR: In this article, the authors claim that European integration has become politicized in elections and referendums, and as a result, the preferences of the general public and of national political parties have become decisive for jurisdictional outcomes.
Posted Content

Capital in the 21st Century

TL;DR: A discussion forum based around Thomas Piketty's book, Capital in the twenty-first century, with a number of economists from academia, public sector bodies and private sector institutions was held at the Centre for Economic Policy Research and the Bank of England.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (18)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Authoritarian liberalism in europe: a common critique of neoliberalism and ordoliberalism" ?

This paper suggests, however, that within the constitutional dynamic of European integration and postwar reconstruction, ordoand neo-liberalism represent a single movement: a conflation of political authoritarianism and economic liberalism in opposition to democracy and especially in opposition to democratic constituent 

Once politics is reduced to a single political-economic logic, and the possibility of genuine renewal comes down to the possibility of exercising the constituent power, the autonomy of the political is reduced to a bare formality or the prospect of a revolutionary rupture. The differentiation of the political and the economic is cemented at Maastricht, continued into a further stage, with neoliberal financialisation representing a deepening rather than overturning of the post-war logic of integration. If the ultimate capitulation of Greece suggests authoritarian liberalism in Europe may survive, developments elsewhere, as right-wing Eurosceptic parties surge in popularity ( in Hungary, Poland, as well as in the core of Europe, in France, Germany and Italy ) suggests that the authoritarian liberal suppression of the democratic voice may, as in the interwar period, tend not only to the victory of capitalism, but also to the resurgence of reactionary forms of authoritarian illiberalism. Whether any reprisal of the inter-war breakdown of liberal democracy will more closely resemble tragedy or farce remains to be seen ( Wilkinson, 2015b ). 

The reaction of the governing elites and industrialists of the early 1930’s to the political and economic instability, rendered more acute by the depression, was a combination of authoritarianism and economic liberalism. 

In their analysis, it was the capitalist market system and itsmaterial inequalities that ultimately undermined democracy and laid the path to the Fascist takeover. 

Once politics is reduced to a single political-economic logic, and the possibility of genuine renewal comes down to the possibility of exercising the constituent power, the autonomy of the political is reduced to a bare formality or the prospect of a revolutionary rupture. 

rather than presented as an emancipatory opportunity, or a material struggle for political equality, is disarmed as ‘liberal democracy’, or dismissed as likely to entail a ‘tyranny of the majority’. 

European integration was an intrinsic part of this post-war settlement, representing the construction of a ‘militant democracy writ large’, a project generated by administrative and bureaucratic processes rather than democratic energies. 

The creation of an internal market is seen tamely and benignly as designed only to ensure peace and prosperity after half of century of war and destruction. 

Fiscal indiscipline is avoided in theory, because states have to pursue the austerity programmes (the ‘strict conditionality’) that, it is claimed, would be demanded were they still subject to the discipline of the financial markets. 

The dominance of Christian Democratic parties and a widespread ethos of social Catholicism played a strong part in this resettlement. 

It was also a feature of domestic class struggle, predominantly between a class-conscious and politically emancipated working class and an anti-democratic and embittered ruling class. 

The market was meant to ensure that interdependent states would retain sound finances, backed up institutionally by a Stability and Growth pact that was, however, seriously under-enforced, notably against France and Germany in its early phase, before the financial crisis (Menendez, 2013). 

It is, properly understood, authoritarian in character; but it is an authoritarianism based on a fear of freedom that has a class character as well as a socio-psychological dimension: it is not only that elites fear and distrust the people, but also that the people fear and distrust themselves (Fromm, 2001 [1941]). 

European integration itself is initially given relatively little attention by constitutional scholars, neglected as a further stage of democratic capitalist development and state transformation. 

All of this suggests that the constitutional crises are not fundamentally about a formal conflict between emergency politics and the normal rules of the game. 

There was, however, a school of thought which did take – and had since the 1930’s taken - seriously political economy as a constitutional question, placing economic freedom at the centre of its constitutional analysis. 

The differentiation of the political and the economic is cemented at Maastricht, continued into a further stage, with neoliberal financialisation representing a deepening rather than overturning of the post-war logic of integration. 

The Maastricht project flows from the same premises of market-building, economic rationality and de-politicisation (qua de-democratisation) that characterised the deep reconstitution of postwar Europe.