scispace - formally typeset
Open AccessJournal ArticleDOI

CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Investment

TLDR
In this article, the authors argue that managerial overconfidence can account for corporate investment distortions and find that investment of overconfident CEOs is significantly more responsive to cash flow, particularly in equity-dependent firms.
Abstract
We argue that managerial overconfidence can account for corporate investment distortions. Overconfident managers overestimate the returns to their investment projects and view external funds as unduly costly. Thus, they overinvest when they have abundant internal funds, but curtail investment when they require external financing. We test the overconfidence hypothesis, using panel data on personal portfolio and corporate investment decisions of Forbes 500 CEOs. We classify CEOs as overconfident if they persistently fail to reduce their personal exposure to company-specific risk. We find that investment of overconfident CEOs is significantly more responsive to cash flow, particularly in equity-dependent firms.

read more

Content maybe subject to copyright    Report

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
CEO OVERCONFIDENCE AND CORPORATE INVESTMENT
Ulrike Malmendier
Geoffrey Tate
Working Paper 10807
http://www.nber.org/papers/w10807
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
September 2004
We are indebted to Brian Hall and David Yermack for providing us with the data. We are very grateful to
Jeremy Stein for his invaluable support and comments. We also would like to thank Philippe Aghion, George
Baker, Stefano DellaVigna, Edward Glaeser, Rick Green, Brian Hall, Oliver Hart, Caroline Hoxby, Dirk
Jenter, Larry Katz, Tom Knox, David Laibson, Andrei Shleifer and various participants in seminars at
Harvard University, MIT, University of Chicago, Northwestern University, UC Berkeley, Stanford
University, UCLA, CalTech, Yale University, Univeristy of Michigan, Duke University, NYU, Columbia
University, Wharton, LSE, CREST, CEMFI, LMU Munich, and at the EER, the Russell Sage Summer
Institute for Behavioral Economics and at the SITE for helpful comments. Mike Cho provided excellent
research assistance. Malmendier acknowledges financial support from Harvard University (Dively
Foundation) and the German Academic Exchange Service (DAAD). The views expressed herein are those
of the author(s) and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
©2004 by Ulrike Malmendier and Geoffrey Tate. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed
two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is
given to the source.

CEO Overconfidence and Corporate Investment
Ulrike Malmendier and Geoffrey Tate
NBER Working Paper No. 10807
September 2004
JEL No. G31, G32, D21, D23, D82
ABSTRACT
We argue that managerial overconfidence can account for corporate investment distortions.
Overconfident managers overestimate the returns to their investment projects and view external
funds as unduly costly. Thus, they overinvest when they have abundant internal funds, but curtail
investment when they require external financing. We test the overconfidence hypothesis, using panel
data on personal portfolio and corporate investment decisions of Forbes 500 CEOs. We classify
CEOs as overconfident if they persistently fail to reduce their personal exposure to company-specific
risk. We find that investment of overconfident CEOs is significantly more responsive to cash flow,
particularly in equity-dependent firms.
Ulrike Malmendier
Graduate School of Business
518 Memorial Way
Stanford University
Stanford, CA 94305-5015
and NBER
ulrikem@stanford.edu
Geoffrey Tate
Wharton School
University of Pennsylvania
tate@wharton.upenn.edu

In this paper, we argue that personal charact eristics of CEOs in large corporations lead to
distortions in corporate investmen t policies. In particular, we study the investment deci-
sions of CEOs who overestimate th e future returns of their companies, measured by failure
to divest company-specic risk on their personal accounts. We nd that overcondent CEOs
have a heightened sensitivity of corporate investment to cash ow, particularly among equity-
dependent rms.
The two traditional explanations for investment distortions are the misalignment of managerial
and shareholders int erests (Jensen and Meckling (1976), Jensen (1986)) and asymmetric infor-
mation between corporate insiders and the capital market (Myers and Majluf (1984)). Both
cause investment to be sensitive to the amount of cash in the rm. Under the agency view,
managers overinvest to reap private benets such as “perks,” large empires, and en trenchment.
Since the ex ternal capital market limits the extent to which managers can pursue self-interested
investment, an inux of cash ow enables the manager to invest more and increases investment
distortions. Under asymmetric information, the managers themselves (who act in the interest
of shareholders) restrict external nancing in order to avoid diluting the (undervalued) shares
of their company. In this case, cash ow increases investment, but reduces the distortion.
The empirical literature, starting with Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen (1988), conrms the
existence and robustness of investment-cash ow sensitivity after controlling for investment
opportunities. While most of the literature relates investment-cash ow sensitivity to imper-
fections in the capital market, this interpretation remains controversial (Kaplan and Zingales,
(1997), (2000); Fazzari, Hubbard and Petersen, (2000)).
We propose an alternative explanation for investment-cash ow sensitivity and suboptimal
1

investment behavior. Rather than focusing on rm-level characteristics, w e relate corporate
investment decisions to personal characteristics of the top decision-maker inside the rm. Build-
ing on Roll (1986) and Heaton (2002), we argue that one important link between investment
levels and cash ow is the tension between the beliefs of the CEO and the market about the
value of the rm. Overcondent CEOs systematically overestimate the return to their invest-
ment projects. If they have sucient internal funds for investment and are not disciplined by
the capital market or corporate governance mechanisms, they overinvest relative to the rst
best. If they do not ha ve sucient internal funds, however, they are reluctant to issue new
equity because they perceive the stock of their company to be undervalued by the market. As
a result, they curb their investment. Additional cash ow provides an opportunity to invest
closer to their desired level.
Our overcondence story builds upon a prominent stylized fact from the social psychology
literature, the “better than average” eect. When individuals assess their relative skill, they
tend to overstate their acumen relative to the average (Larwood and Whittaker, (1977); Sven-
son, (1981); Alic ke, (1985)). This eect extends to economic decision-making in experiments
(Camerer and Lovallo (1999)). It also aects the attribution of causality. Because individuals
expect their behavior to produce success, they are more likely to attribute good outcomes to
their actions, but bad outcomes to (bad) luck (Miller and Ross (1975)). Executives appear to be
particularly prone to display overcondence, both in terms of the “better-than-average eect”
and in terms of “narrow condence intervals” (Larwood and Whittak er, (1977); Kidd, (1970);
Moore, (1977)).
1
This nding is attributed to three main factors, which trigger overcondence:
the illusion of control, a high degree of commitment to good outcomes, and abstract reference
2

poin ts that make it hard to compare performance across individuals (Weinstein (1980); Alicke
et al. (1995)). All three factors are pertinent in the context of corporate investment. A CEO
who hand-picks an investment project is likely to believe he can control its outcome and to
underestimate the likelihood of failure (March and Shapira (1987); Langer, (1975)). The typi-
cal CEO is also highly committed to good company performance since his personal wealth and
the value of his human capital uctuate with the company’s stock price. And nally, assessing
relative managerial skill or, specically, the abilit y to pick protable investment projects is
dicult ev en ex post due to other factors that inuence overall rm performance.
Heaton (2002) rst showed that common distortions in corporate in vestment may be the result
of managers overestimating the returns to their investment. We expand on Heaton’s insight in
two ways. First, we model how the pre-existing capital structure aects the role of overcon-
dence. Second, we empirically test the predictions of the model.
To construct measures of overcondence, we exploit the over-exposure of typical CEOs to their
rms’ idiosyncratic risk. CEOs receive large grants of stock and options as compensation. They
cannot trade their options or hedge the risk by short-selling company stock, and the value of
their human capital is intimately linked to the rm’s performance. Because of this under-
diversication, risk-averse CEOs should exercise their options early given a suciently high
stock price (Lambert, Larcker and Verrechia (1991); Meulbroek, (2001); Hall and Murphy,
(2000), (2002)). We take two main approaches to translate this logic into overcondence
measures. First, we identify a benchmark for the minimum percentage in the money at which
CEOs should exercise their options for a given y ear immediately following the vesting period.
If a CEO persisten tly exercises options later than suggested by the benc hmark, we infer that he
3

Citations
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Managing with Style: The Effect of Managers on Firm Policies

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigate whether and how individual managers affect corporate behavior and performance and show that managers with higher performance effects receive higher compensation and are more likely to be found in better governed environments.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Cash Flow Sensitivity of Cash

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors empirically estimate the sensitivity of cash using a large sample of manufacturing firms over the 1971 to 2000 period and find robust support for their theory, and hypothesize that constrained firms should have a positive cash flow sensitivity, while unconstrained firms' cash savings should not be systematically related to cash flows.
Journal ArticleDOI

Corporate Governance and Firm Value: The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility

TL;DR: In this paper, the authors investigated the effect of internal and external corporate governance and monitoring mechanisms on the choice of CSR engagement and the value of firms engaging in CSR activities.
Journal ArticleDOI

Quantifying Managerial Ability: A New Measure and Validity Tests

TL;DR: The authors proposed a measure of managerial ability, based on managers' efficiency in generating revenues, which is available for a large sample of firms and outperforms existing ability measures and finds that the measure is strongly associated with manager fixed effects, and that stock price reactions to CEO turnover are positive (negative) when assessing the outgoing CEO as low (high) ability.
References
More filters
Journal ArticleDOI

Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure

TL;DR: In this article, the authors draw on recent progress in the theory of property rights, agency, and finance to develop a theory of ownership structure for the firm, which casts new light on and has implications for a variety of issues in the professional and popular literature.
Journal ArticleDOI

The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities

TL;DR: In this paper, a theoretical valuation formula for options is derived, based on the assumption that options are correctly priced in the market and it should not be possible to make sure profits by creating portfolios of long and short positions in options and their underlying stocks.
Journal Article

The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment

TL;DR: In this article, the effect of financial structure on market valuations has been investigated and a theory of investment of the firm under conditions of uncertainty has been developed for the cost-of-capital problem.
Journal ArticleDOI

Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have

TL;DR: In this paper, a firm that must issue common stock to raise cash to undertake a valuable investment opportunity is considered, and an equilibrium model of the issue-invest decision is developed under these assumptions.
Posted Content

A Survey of Corporate Governance

TL;DR: The authors surveys research on corporate governance, with special attention to the importance of legal protection of investors and of ownership concentration in corporate governance systems around the world, and presents a survey of the literature.
Related Papers (5)
Frequently Asked Questions (9)
Q1. What have the authors contributed in "Nber working paper series ceo overconfidence and corporate investment" ?

The views expressed herein are those of the author ( s ) and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. 

Net Buyer requires that the factor leading the CEO to purchase additional company stock still affects investment decisions in a disjoint future time period. Overall, the results suggest that the number of times a CEO has held a 67 percent-in-the-money option in the past is considerably more important in determining the CEO ’ s future exercise behavior than any information about current or future stock price performance — an indication of a personal fixed effect on option exercise decisions. Financial services firms and the financial press, while following stock purchases and sales of insiders closely, generally discount option exercises as signals of future stock prices. Still, Holder 67 places no restriction on how long the CEO must hold the option beyond the fifth year and, thus, could potentially capture short term delays in option exercise. 

In addition, CEOs who have accumulated additional titles (President and Chairman of the Board) display heightened sensitivity of investment to cash flow. 

The coefficient on the interaction of the holder indicator with cash flow is positive (0.2339 in the OLS specification with controls) and highly significant. 

One alternative to controlling for industry effects on investment-cash flow sensitivity would be to remove all cross-sectional variation by including firm fixed effects interacted with cash flow24in the analysis. 

The first two regressions confirm the stylized facts of the25investment-cash flow sensitivity literature — namely that cash flow has a large amount of explanatory power beyond Q for investment. 

The authors repeat this exercise starting at 50 percent in the money and incrementing by five up to 150 percent in the money to verify the robustness of their results to variations in the parameters (e.g., 100 percent corresponds to ρ = 3; 50 percent of wealth in stock). 

I∗)−c∗−d∗ − ∆R(I ∗)(I∗−c∗−d∗)(A+C+R(I∗)−c∗−d∗)2 − 1− µ− ν = 0 (A6) λ(c∗ −C) = 0, µ(d∗ −D) = 0, ν(c∗ + d∗ − I∗) = 0 (A7) λ ≥ 0, µ ≥ 0, ν ≥ 0(i) Suppose ∆ = 0. Then conditions (A4)-(A6) simplify to:R0(I∗)− 

The authors also find that Q has more impact on investment for higher levels of cash flow (although this effect is not consistently significant).